Next Article in Journal
The Maximum Entropy Production Principle: Its Theoretical Foundations and Applications to the Earth System
Next Article in Special Issue
Air Conditioning Systems from a 2nd Law Perspective
Previous Article in Journal
Thermodynamic and Differential Entropy under a Change of Variables
Previous Article in Special Issue
Combined Effects of Pipe Diameter, Reynolds Number and Wall Heat Flux and on Flow, Heat Transfer and Second-Law Characteristics of Laminar-Transitional Micro-Pipe Flows
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Application of Thermoeconomics to Industrial Ecology

CIRCE, Center of Research for Energy Resources and Consumption, Universidad de Zaragoza, Spain
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Entropy 2010, 12(3), 591-612; https://doi.org/10.3390/e12030591
Submission received: 19 January 2010 / Revised: 13 March 2010 / Accepted: 15 March 2010 / Published: 22 March 2010
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Exergy: Analysis and Applications)

Abstract

:
Industrial Ecology involves the transformation of industrial processes from linear to closed loop systems: matter and energy flows which were initially considered as wastes become now resources for existing or new processes. In this paper, Thermoeconomics, commonly used for the optimization and diagnosis of energy systems, is proposed as a tool for the characterization of Industrial Ecology. Thermoeconomics is based on the exergy analysis (Thermodynamics) but goes further by introducing the concepts of purpose and cost (Economics). It is presented in this study as a systematic and general approach for the analysis of waste flow integration. The formulation is based on extending the thermoeconomic process of the cost formation of wastes in order to consider their use as input for other processes. Consequently, it can be applied to important Industrial Ecology issues such as identification of integration possibilities and efficiency improvement, quantification of benefits obtained by integration, or determination of fair prices based on physical roots. The capability of the methodology is demonstrated by means of a case study based on the integration of a power plant, a cement kiln and a gas-fired boiler.

1. Introduction

Industrial Ecology (IE) offers promising opportunities for attaining sustainable industrial development. IE essentially aims at achieving a more rational and balanced industrial organization, trying to imitate the structure and operation of natural ecosystems. Like natural organisms, industrial ecosystems consume material, energy and water flows, transforming them into products and wastes. However there is one important difference among the two: the wastes produced by natural organisms are used as feedstock for other natural systems. As a result of this cyclic process, the net production of wastes produced in nature is zero. Wastes are always a consequence of lack of knowledge. The challenge of industrial systems is thus to identify opportunities for waste reduction by imitating nature (industrial biocenosis). Instead of the Zoo paradigm in which any industry must be fed and cleaned up separately, the Savannah paradigm must prevail. In the latter, every facility feeds products/wastes from someone else and ultimately the natural surroundings act as another active member of the industrial community. In Industrial Ecology, the conventional linear productivity chain approach is shifted into a materials cycle approach [1]. Unfortunately, the dominant industrial conception has been so far that of the Zoo paradigm, constituting a fundamental factor in the current environmental crisis.
Industrial Ecology principles are materialized through the establishment of eco-industrial parks. These are defined as “a community of businesses that cooperate with each other and with the local community to efficiently share resources (information, materials, water, energy, infrastructure and natural habitat), leading to economic gains, gains in environmental quality, and equitable enhancement of human resources for the Business and local community” [2]
Frosch and Gallopoulos [3], Dunn and Steinmann [4], Chertow [5,6] or Gibbs et al. [7] analyze in detail the strengths and barriers of IE. Particularly, the latter two authors make a critical evaluation of eco-industrial parks in development. Some of the economic, environmental and social advantages listed in the literature are the following:
  • The input costs of raw materials are reduced as waste products from one industry are provided as inputs for another.
  • Wastes are converted into products with an associated economic value.
  • The waste streams are reduced and hence the disposal costs.
  • Enhancement of long-term resource security by increasing the availability of critical resources such as water, energy or particular raw materials through contracts.
  • Creation of a larger and more varied economic base.
  • Potential for job creation from the formation of niche species firms.
Although theoretically IE represents a win-win situation, the associated benefits are difficult to evaluate and have seldom been carefully measured. A critical barrier commonly encountered when promoting eco-industrial parks is in encouraging companies for pursuing industrial symbiosis. The most obvious motivations are conventional business reasons; for example, resource sharing can reduce costs and/or increase revenues [5]. But companies will unlikely act with mere qualitative statements no matter how promising they are. Companies need numbers and these numbers should be as objective and accurate as possible.
The integration of industrial systems with mutual exchanges of resources, products and wastes implies energy savings. And the most objective way to analyze the magnitude of those savings is through the laws of Thermodynamics. As stated before, in all industrial processes, energy resources are consumed and non energetic raw materials are transformed. In this context, exergy rather than energy is the unit of measure to be used. In every material and energy transformation, neither matter, nor energy disappear, it is always exergy what is lost. Each step in the manufacturing process involves the generation of irreversibilities and hence of exergy losses (often misinterpreted as energy losses). The most important contribution of the exergy concept is in its ability to objectify all the physical manifestations in energy units, independently of their economic value. Any product, natural or artificial resource, productive process or polluting emission can be valued from an exergy point of view with a single unit of measure.
A number of authors such as Ayres and Ayres [8] have long been stating that the exergy analysis can help to quantify the benefits of Industrial Ecology. In particular, Connelly and Koshland [9] discussed the ties between exergy and industrial ecology and proposed exergy-based definitions and methods for addressing resource depletion. Finnveden and Östlund [10], Cornelissen and Hirs [11] and Dewulf and Langenhove [12,13] applied the exergy analysis to the Life Cycle Assessment (LCA) methodology, which should account for the depletion of natural resources and the associated environmental impacts.
Unfortunately, exergy analysis is necessary but not sufficient to determine the origin of losses and the potential for energy saving. Conventional Thermodynamics states that the exergy balance accounts for the degradation of the exergy. The incoming exergy will be always greater than the outgoing one:
Exergy Input – Exergy Output = Irreversibilities > 0
This expression only points out the existence of irreversibilities within the process. However Thermoeconomics (TE), term coined by Tribus and Evans [14], takes a step further, including in this equation the concept of purpose by means of the definition of efficiency. This is to say that there is an implicit classification of the flows crossing the boundary of the system: the production objective, P, the resources required to carry out the production, F, and those that are residuals or wastes, R. We cannot just associate the resources with input flows, nor the products with output flows. We need to have a clear idea of what we want to produce before defining the efficiency. This information is not implicit in the Second Law and is the most important conceptual leap separating and at the same time unifying Physics with Economics. This way, the exergy balance now becomes:
F P R = I > 0
where I represents the irreversibilities of the process. All resources have an “economic” cost: the more irreversible a process is the more resources and energy are consumed (higher exergy cost). The concept of exergy cost is still within Thermodynamics, but it already shares many of the cost accounting methodologies borrowed from Economics. It is clearly a conceptual link between these two disciplines. Thus the isomorphism between exergy cost and economic cost lets us straightforwardly convert thermodynamic costs into thermoeconomic costs, by simply adding the prices of resources, installation and maintenance costs. In fact, this methodology is isomorphous with the Input-Output analysis [15], with the difference that Thermoeconomics uses Second Law to cost assessment. This is the only way that we can provide physical roots to the accounting techniques. The cost formation process sheds light on new paths for economic, scientific, technological and, perhaps, philosophical research. Thermoeconomics becomes a crystal clear and unique way to connect the universal measure of physical loss, i.e., irreversibility with the loss of resources at the overall system level and then to Economics. The “exergy cost” concept was proposed by Valero et al. [16]. Almost simultaneously Szargut and Morris [17] proposed the “cumulative exergy consumption” theory. Both concepts represent in fact embodied exergy.
Thermoeconomics has been largely used for the diagnosis of single production plants, allowing the identification of inefficiencies and the potential for energy savings [18]. Now, it is the time to open the approach to industrial networks under the industrial ecology paradigm. The versatility of TE allows its application to complex systems, providing a systematic and general approach for the analysis of waste flow integration.
On the other side, Input-Output analysis (IO) has been used to address environmental issues related to Industrial Ecology [19] and Environmental Life Cycle Assessment [20]. However, it IO has been traditionally used with different quantity units for accounting for all energy and material fluxes coming into play, what complicates extremely the analysis. Similarly, if monetary units are used to assign costs, it may introduce arbitrariness to the analysis. As it has been argued before, exergy is a suitable physical unit to which costs should be allocated. To this same conclusion have come Hau and Bakshi [21], who applied exergy and cumulative exergy consumption, to Input-Output analysis in a sample of industrial and ecological systems.
In short, the application of exergy to IO analysis based on Thermoeconomics can help to rationalize the general problem of energy saving achieved through waste integration. Moreover, it is able to objectively assess the final costs of the products interchanged in eco-industrial parks, providing a decision tool for companies.
In the following sections, a description of the fundamentals of Thermoeconomics applied to an Industrial Ecology is developed, and an example is carried out.

2. The Thermoeconomic Model

For the thermoeconomic characterization of any energy system, a thermoeconomic model is firstly required. In the following sections, the basic ingredients of the thermoeconomic model are briefly described.

2.1. Physical Structure

Energy systems represent complex networks of mass and energy flows. The level of aggregation of the system depends on the type of analysis carried out. The total system is composed of a collection of subsystems. Each subsystem can be a part of a physical device, the device itself or a group of devices, representing the thermodynamic process.
A suitable data structure representation of an energy system for a specific level of aggregation is made by means of a directed graph, consisting of a set of graph nodes representing the system components, and a set of graph edges, where each element connects two components of the system and shows the interchanged mass or energy flows. Figure 1 shows an example of the physical structure of an eco-industrial park which integrates a power plant, a steam generator and a cement factory. In the figure, the boxes represent the components and the arrows the flows of the system.
Figure 1. Physical structure of an eco-industrial park, integrating a power plant, a steam generator and a cement factory.
Figure 1. Physical structure of an eco-industrial park, integrating a power plant, a steam generator and a cement factory.
Entropy 12 00591 g001

2.2. Thermodynamic Model

The thermodynamic model (TDM) of the plant is described through a set of equations, (including the mass, energy and entropy balances). They allow every mass flow stream and every heat and work interactions involved in the physical structure of the plant to be determined from a set of input variables, defining a thermodynamic state of the plant. Exergy is used as the measure of the usefulness of the energy carried by each flow defined in the physical structure.

2.3. Fuel and Product

Each component or process of the system has a productive purpose. It is established by means of the definition of its efficiency:
Efficiency of productive processes = Product / Resources
Efficiency measures the quality of a process. This is to say, there is an implicit classification of the flows crossing the boundary of the system, the flows that are the production objective, and those that are the resources required to carry out the production. Since the exergy of resources is greater than that of the products, this efficiency is always positive and less than one.
For each process or component of the system, it is necessary to identify the flow streams that constitute its product streams, and the flow streams used to obtain them, called fuel streams. Accordingly, it can be said that the fuel is the amount of exergy provided by the resources streams, and the product is the exergy provided by the product streams. Table 2, shows the fuel–product definition for the components of the system depicted in Figure 1.

2.4. Waste and By-Products

In any productive process, along with the primary products, there are unintended remaining output flows of matter or energy called residuals or wastes. Waste refers to those outputs which are disposed of. They could also be partially used in further processes, i.e., recycled. Therefore, besides the productive components, there are components whose objective is to dissipate residual flows. Our technical limitations make these components to be a need, since we are not able to recover all the exergy of outputs and they become wastes. The combustion process is an example of this fact. It has a low efficiency conversion, and furthermore it produces low thermal exergy residual gases which cannot be recovered and must be disposed of into the environment. Moreover, if we want to eliminate them, additional resources are required, using processes to cooling, expanding, dispersing or capturing them. The efficiency of a dissipative unit measures the amount of resources required per unit of exergy reduced in the waste flow:
Efficiency of dissipative processes = Exergy reduction of waste / Resources required
Since the resources required have no relationship with the decreased exergy of waste, this efficiency is always positive and does not have an upper limit of one.
Thermoeconomics has been mainly focused on production and dissipative processes, but there is also another type of system outputs which belongs neither to primary products nor to waste, and they are called by-products.
According to Nakamura and Kondo [22] we incorporate the following definitions of by-products:
  • An output from a given production process is a competitive by-product, when it is not a primary product of the process, but technically related to its production, and happens to be the primary product of another production process.
  • An output from a given production process is a non-competitive by-product, when it is not a primary product, but related to its production and there is not another production process where it is primary produced.
Competitive by-products are part of the output of productive or dissipative units that could be used total or partially as alternative products in other processes. An example of this kind of by-product is the steam produced in a power plant and further used as process steam in a chemical plant, which also produces steam in a natural gas boiler.
Non-competitive by-products are closely related to waste recycling. Ash generated by an incinerating process or coal burned in power plants is a typical example of this type of by-product associated with waste treatment processes. Ash can be used as a raw-material for cement production within a limited range as a substitute for clinker.
The output flows that belong neither to products nor to waste are emissions, examples of which are CO2, NOx and SOx in the exhaust gases of combustion processes.

2.5. Productive Structure

The productive structure [23] is the representation of the production process of an energy system. The inputs of each process are the resources or fuels and the outputs are their products. The utility of the obtained products can be of different nature: as fuels for other components, as part of the primary product, as by-products or as wastes that must be eliminated in dissipative or waste treatment components. Reciprocally the fuel of a component comes from external resources or from the products of another component. The definition of the productive structure depends on the definition of the efficiency of the individual components of the system for a given aggregation level. The fuel and product of a component do not necessarily correspond with the input and output of the physical components. For example in a power plant turbine, the product is the mechanical energy produced, meanwhile the fuel is the difference between the exergy of the input and output steam flows. Furthermore, the components of the productive structure could be different from those of the physical structure. This way, some physical components could be disaggregated for a better analysis of its products and wastes and vice versa, they could be aggregated to simplify the model without loss of information.
For the description of the productive structure we must identify, for every component, one or several fuel and product streams. From the fuel-product definition it is possible to build a productive diagram, as the one shown in Figure 2.
The productive structure is the key point to understand the cost formation process of products, by-products and wastes.

2.6. External Resources Assessment

The definition of the thermoeconomic model requires also every external resource inputs to the system to be valued. The ways these external resources are valued will determine the type of cost obtained. If the resources are accounted in terms of exergy, the results obtained are expressed as exergy costs (kW). Alternatively, if the cumulative exergy for the complete life cycle of the resources is used, then exergy life costs (kW) will be obtained.
Figure 2. Productive Structure of the integrated plant.
Figure 2. Productive Structure of the integrated plant.
Entropy 12 00591 g002
Thermoeconomics can also use economic valuation of the external resources costs. In this case the resulting cost is evaluated in monetary units per unit of time (€/h) and is called exergoeconomic cost. The latter includes:
  • The investment and operational cost of the equipment (€/h), defined as a function of a list of parameters, including size, materials, operating range, working hours per year, inflation rates, installation and maintenance cost, as well as other factors, see [24].
  • The market prices of the fuels (€/kWh), natural gas, coal and other external resources.
  • The cost (€/h) of the resources required for the disposal of the wastes, or abatement costs.

3. The Fuel-Product-Residuals Model

The first step for the identification of the cost formation process of products and wastes consists of building a productive scheme that explains the resources distribution throughout the plant. This approach, which is closely related to Input-Output analysis, is essential in order to analyze the potential improving of recycling. An equivalent micro-economic model based on the Second Law of Thermodynamics, can be applied to energy systems. This model can be represented by means of an input-output table (see Table 1). The rows represent the destination of the production of each component: as fuel of other components, as disposable waste, or as a primary product of the system. The first row represents the external resources entering the system. Meanwhile, the columns represent the source of the fuel of each component: either coming from the production of other components or as resources coming from outside the boundaries of the system. An algorithm to obtain the fuel-product table from the physical and productive structure is described in [25]. Table 4 shows the Fuel-Product tables of the integrated system used in our case study.
Table 1. Generic FP Table.
Table 1. Generic FP Table.
F 1 F j F n ω R ω S
υ 0 E 01 E 0 j E 0 n
P 1 E 11 E 1 j E 1 n R 10 E 10
P i E i 1 E i j E i n R i 0 E i 0
P n E n 1 E n j E n n R n 0 E n 0
According to this representation, the production of a productive component is used as fuel of other components or as a primary product of the system. Mathematically, this could be expressed as the sum of the element of each fuel-product table row:
P i = R i 0 + E i 0 + j = 1 n E i j
In the above expression, if the component 0 is considered to be the system environment, then E i 0 represents the production of the i-th component that leaves the system as a primary product. In case of waste treatment units R i 0 represents the disposable, or not recycled, waste.
On the other hand, the resources consumed by each component are the sum of the elements of each fuel-product table column:
F i = E 0 i + j = 1 n E j i
where E 0 i represents the external resources used in the i-th component.
The exergy balance, Equation (1), is the point in understanding the difference between the Input-Output quantity model and the Thermoeconomic approach. The only numeraire (kg, m 3 , kJ,…) defining F, P and R that satisfies the Second Law Analysis is exergy. The right hand side of this equation is the measure of the process irreversibility. Since all elements in the fuel-product table are measured in the same quantity exergy, it is possible to add not only the rows (products) but also columns (fuels) for each component and compare them. The comparison between fuels and products provides a universal measure of the quality of a process.
Equations (2) and (3) can be compactly summarized in matrix notation as:
F = υ 0 + t u FP P = FP u + ω R + ω S
where FP is a square matrix ( n × n ) which represents the internal elements of the Fuel-Product table. F and P are column vectors ( n × 1 ) that represent the fuel and product of each component. ω S and ω R are column vectors ( n × 1 ) that represent the exergy of primary output and the waste generated for each component. υ 0 is a ( n × 1 ) column vector that contains the exergy of the external resources entering each component. We use u to represent a column vector of 1’s (with the appropriate dimension–here n is the number of components). An important observation is that post-multiplication of a matrix by u creates a column vector whose elements are the row sums of the matrix. Similarly t u is a row vector of 1’s and premultiplication of a matrix by t u creates a row vector whose elements are the column sums of the matrix. We will use these “summation” vectors along the paper.
Let define the exergy distribution ratios as y i j = E i j / P i as the part of the production of the i t h component becoming fuel of the j t h component. If we denote by FP the square matrix ( n × n ) which contains the exergy distribution ratios of the system, then it verifies:
FP = P ^ 1 FP
we use x ^ to represent a diagonal matrix, whose elements are a vector x .

4. The Cost Model

The exergy cost theory (ECT) is established as a rational procedure that uses the second law analysis through property exergy, for the allocation of cost in energy systems. We will obtain the exergy cost equations, according to the proposed Fuel-Product-Residual model that incorporated waste recycling and by-product assessment.
Once the Fuel-Product-Residual model has been defined, we will determine now the exergy cost of the flows in the productive structure E i j * , and the corresponding Fuel-Product cost table FP * . In accordance with the proposed model, the cost of the resources used in each component is given by:
C F = υ 0 * + t FP * u
where υ 0 * is a ( n × 1 ) vector that represents the known cost of the external resources entering the components, both productive and waste treatment units. Likewise, the cost of the productive units is:
C P = FP * u + ω S * + ω R *
where ω S * represents the cost of the final products and ω R * the cost of the disposed wastes.

4.1. Waste Cost Assessment

According to ECT, all costs yielded by the productive process must be included in the cost of the final or primary products. Torres et al. [26] proposed a general methodology for cost allocation of wastes. The exergy cost contained in the waste that is disposed of and the cost of the resources required in its treatment, must be allocated to the productive units that have generated them. Each waste flow has a cost formation process, as well as the production flows that must be identified to calculate the cost of all functional products correctly.
The cost of each waste flow could be decomposed as:
ω R , i * = j = 1 n R i j *
where R i j * is assumed to be the cost of the dissipated residue by the i–th component that has been produced by the j–th component. We denote as RP * the square matrix ( n × n ) which contains the residue cost R i j * , therefore Equation (8) is written in matrix notation as:
ω R * = RP * u
The cost of the residues charged to each component, denoted as C R , is written as:
C R = t RP * u
In order to determine the values of R i j * , the waste cost distribution ratio ψ i j is defined as:
R i j * = ω R , i * ψ i j and j ψ i j = 1
If we denote as RP the ( n × n ) matrix which contains the waste cost distribution ratios, Equation (10) is written as follows:
C R = t RP ω R *

4.2. Exergy Cost Equations

Accordingly, from the application of the ECT rules, we have:
  • The costs of the external resources υ 0 * are known values.
  • The production cost of a component equals the cost of the resources needed to obtain it, as well as all costs generated by the waste disposal:
    C P = C F + C P
  • The cost of each one of the flows making up the product of a component is proportional to its exergy:
    FP * = C ^ P FP
Combining Equations (6) and (10) into Equation (13), we get:
C P = υ 0 * + t FP * u + t RP * u
The cost of the residuals generated by a component could be related with its production cost, by introducing the disposal waste ratio, γ i = ω R , i / P i , as the quotient between the waste disposed of and the production of the component. Wastes can be either emitted to the environment or recovered to some extend through making it available for other processes. The degree of recycling could be expressed by means of the exergy disposal waste ratio γ i . This ratio has a value between 0 and 1. In case of emissions its value is 1, and in case all wastes could be recovered as by-product the value is 0.
Therefore, equation (12) is rewritten as:
C R = t RP G ^ R C P
where G ^ R is a ( n × n ) diagonal matrix whose elements are the disposal waste ratios of each component.
Now, applying Equations (14) and (16), into Equation (15) it could be written as:
C P = υ 0 * + t FP C P + t RP G ^ R C P
This relationship allows the determination of the production cost as a function of the external resources cost, the distribution cost ratios for products and waste and the recycling ratios.
C P = P * υ 0 *
where P * U ^ t FP t RP G ^ R 1 is called production cost matrix. The elements of this matrix are interpreted as a measure of the production cost that comes about in process j–th per unit of primary input in process i–th.
The total system fuel cost of the system defined as the sum of cost of all external resources:
F T = t u υ 0 *
From Equation (18) previous expression of the total fuel cost could be expressed as a function of the production cost:
F T = t y 0 C P
where t y 0 is a ( 1 × n ) vector which contains the ratio of the production of each component that becomes final product (including waste recycling) and satisfy P * y 0 = u .

4.3. Recycling Fuel Impact

The previous model can be applied to the analysis of process integration and recycling. For that purpose, some aspects must be considered in the evaluation of by-product costs.
  • Competitive by-product: Their cost must be compared with the cost of the primary output of the other system. A straight forward way to incorporate the by-product, for example the process steam generated in a power plant, is to account it as an exergy credit whose value is the corresponding exergy cost if it had been produced in an independent natural gas boiler. Therefore, if E i 0 is the exergy entry in the fuel-product table of a by-product, this value is suppressed and substituted with an entry C 0 i , where C 0 i is the cost value in the primary process. The total fuel saving is given by:
    Δ F T = t u Δ υ 0
    where Δ υ 0 contains the external cost assessment of the by-products.
  • Noncompetitive by-product: The cost of the by-product cannot be compared with other costs of an alternative product. Therefore the cost of the by-product used as an input for another system is equal to its formation cost. The cost of the recycled by-product E i 0 * , for example ash generated in a combustion process, is subtracted from the waste disposal cost ω R , i * , which is redistributed to the productive components that generated it. If recycling increases, then the dispose waste ratio γ i decreases and according to equation (18) the production cost is reduced. The total fuel saving is now given by:
    Δ F T = t u Δ C R
    where Δ C R is the variation of the waste cost of each process, that could be computed as a function of Δ G ^ R as follows:
    Δ C R = t RP Δ G ^ R U ^ P * t RP Δ G ^ R C P

5. Application to a Plant Integration Analysis

The aim of this section is the application of the methodology previously developed in a case study. Three installations have been considered: a coal-fired power plant, a cement plant and a gas-fired boiler producing steam. Besides, two integrations are analyzed: use of steam bleeding instead of steam produced by the gas-fired boiler, and use of part of fly ashes for substituting clinker within the cement industry.
A simplified physical structure of the system has been depicted in Figure 1. The main facility is a power plant producing 350 MW at design conditions. In addition to superheated and reheated steam, the coal-fired boiler produces ash and a flow of flue gases. The steam cycle is composed of high pressure, medium pressure and low pressure steam turbines. Steam leaving the last turbine is condensed and then compressed and heated by both low pressure and high pressure heaters and a deaerator (consuming bleeding steam) prior to enter the boiler to close the cycle. Part of the steam leaving the medium pressure steam turbine can be diverted from the steam cycle and used in industrial processes.
The cement plant considered has a capacity of 650,000 ton/year operating 8,000 hours/year. The cement manufacturing process can be divided into two parts: clinker production taking place in a kiln and grinding and mixing of this clinker with other constituents. The clinker production process begins with the calcination of limestone (mainly CaCO3) at about 900 C to form calcium oxide (CaO, lime). This is followed by the clinkering process in which the calcium oxide reacts at high temperature (typically 1400–1500 C) with silica, alumina, and ferrous oxide to form clinker. The clinker is then milled with gypsum and other additives to produce cement. It should be noted that it is possible to replace part of the clinker by fly ash.
Finally, the gas-fired boiler produces a flow of 10 kg/s of steam at 8.5 bar and 310 C. These intensive properties have been fixed to coincide with those of steam leaving the medium pressure turbine of the power plant.
In order to perform the thermoeconomic analysis, a productive structure comprising power plant, cement kiln and gas-fired boiler has been defined and represented in Figure 2. Since this structure focuses on the purpose of the sub-systems, it contains not only actual devices appearing in the physical structure but mainly groups of them as well as fictitious components for joining and diverting flows. Components of the productive structure as well as their efficiency definition are shown in Table 2.
The coal boiler is disaggregated into three components: Component #1 is a fictitious device which removes the ashes from the coal, and part of the ashes are recycled and used in the cement plant. Component #2 is the combustion chamber that transforms the exergy of coal without ashes into a flow of heat at adiabatic flame temperature, whose exergy is denoted by E Q . It also produces a flow of flue gases going to stack (#4). Component #3 represents the boiler heat exchange and uses the heat flow E Q to produce steam that is used in further processes as well as heat released in the condenser (#7).
Component #5 aggregates the three stages of the turbine and transforms steam into electricity. Component #6 aggregates the feedwater heaters. It uses part of bleeding steam E H = E 5 + E 6 + E 9 + E 10 to produce hot water returning to the boiler.
Component #9 is a junction connecting steam produced by the natural-gas boiler (#8) with steam bleed from the steam cycle in order to produce a flow to be used in an external process. Besides, component #11 is another junction which connects clinker from the kiln (#10) with ash imported from the power plant.
Table 2. Productive Structure Definition.
Table 2. Productive Structure Definition.
NrComponentFuelProduct
1Ash separator E 1 E 1 ( E 17 + E 18 )
2Burner E 1 ( E 17 + E 18 ) E Q + E 19
3Boiler E Q ( E 2 E 4 ) + ( E 3 E 13 )
4Stack E 19 E 19
5Steam turbines ( E 2 + E 3 ) ( E 4 + E H + E 11 ) E 14 + E 15 + E 16
6Feedwater heaters E H E 13 E 12
7Condenser E 11 E 12 E 20
8Natural-gas boiler E 21 E 22
9Steam mixer E 7 + E 22 E 23
10Cement kiln E 24 + E 25 E 26
11Clinker mixer E 18 + E 26 E 27
Exergy flows of the power plant have been adapted from [27] and correspond to an actual operation point of the plant. An exception is the ash flow which has been obtained by considering a coal heating value of 16,912 kJ/kg, a coal ash content of 23.16% and an ash composition of 49% SiO2, 26% Al2O3, 15% CaO and 10% Fe2O3, which results in an exergy value of 454.0 kJ/kg). Values of exergy related to gas-fired boiler have been calculated by considering an energy efficiency of 0.9 (exergy efficiency is lower). In the case of the cement kiln, it has been considered that each kg of clinker needs 1.54 kg of raw material (mainly limestone) and 4,195 kJ of fuel, including a small part of electricity [28]. Specific exergies of the raw material and clinker are 220 kJ/kg and 1,240 kJ/kg respectively, see reference [29].
In the integrated plant, steam flow produced by the natural-gas boiler is completely substituted by a similar flow bleed from the steam cycle, while the power plant electricity production is kept constant. Accordingly, the amount of coal burned in the power plant increases. Besides, 10% of the mass flow rate of clinker produced in the kiln is substituted by fly ashes imported from the power plant, which has two effects. First, the amount of resources consumed by the kiln is reduced, and, second, exergy flow of the cement also varies because each kg of ash replaces one kg of clinker while the specific exergy of the former is smaller than the specific exergy of the latter.
Table 3. Waste cost distribution ratios matrix.
Table 3. Waste cost distribution ratios matrix.
1234567891011
11.00000000000
41.00000000000
7000.5800.110.3100000
The last point to be considered is to define the distribution of costs associated with wastes. It is done by means of the waste cost cost distribution ratios matrix RP . Their values for the case study system are shown in table 3. There are three components producing wastes: ash separator (#1) producing ash, stack (#4) producing flue gases and condenser (#7) producing waste heat. Both costs associated to ash and flue gases are charged to the ash separator. The cost of waste heat from the condenser is shared proportionally to the entropy generation in the different elements of the steam cycle. Abatement costs for ashes landfilling, combustion gases and cooling system are not considered, but it could be included here, is a more detailed analysis.

6. Results Analysis

Prior to present the results obtained with the application of the methodology to the case study, it is useful to consider what is needed in the evaluation of the integration of several subsystems. Obviously, the main question is which are the savings achieved. However it is interesting to go beyond in order to understand where these savings come from and how they are formed. This can be done by applying thermoeconomic analysis.
The fuel-product tables for the non integrated and integrated system are shown in Table 4. In the first case (a), the power plant, cement plant and natural gas boiler work independently, producing respectively electricity, clinker and steam. In the second case (b) the plants are integrated. Each row of the tables represents how the product of a component is distributed among the other components, how it forms a final product or how it becomes a waste. For example, in Table 4(a), burner (#2) produces 740.8 MW of hot flue gases for the steam boiler (#3) and 37.7 MW are dissipated in the stack (#4). Besides, in each column, the origin of fuel of each component can be seen, for example, the fuel of the turbines (#5) comes from the boiler (#3) and from the feedwater heaters (#6).
Figure 3 resumes the exergy savings achieved by the integration. In the original situation, the total fuel consumption is 1167.2 MW, meanwhile with the integration it decreases down to 1143.7 MW. Therefore, the total fuel saving is equal to 23.5 MW (2%), which may seem small compared to the global consumption, but corresponds to more than €3.5 million/year. The exergy saving for process steam is 12.08 MW (34%), and the exergy saving in clinker production is 11.84 MW (9%).
Table 4. Fuel–Product Table in MW for isolated (a) and integrated (b) system.
Table 4. Fuel–Product Table in MW for isolated (a) and integrated (b) system.
(a) Isolated system
F 1 F 2 F 3 F 4 F 5 F 6 F 7 F 8 F 9 F 10 F 11 ω R ω S Total
υ 0 1014.800000034.510117.90001167.2
P 1 01008.50000000006.3101014.8
P 2 00740.837.7000000000778.5
P 3 0000347.897.9252.92000000498.6
P 4 0000000000037.73037.73
P 5 000000000000351.6351.6
P 6 000062.2817.549.4800000089.29
P 7 0000000000049.01049.01
P 8 000000009.2200009.22
P 9 0000000000009.229.22
P 10 000000000027.990027.99
P 11 00000000000027.9927.99
Total1014.81008.5740.837.73410.0115.562.4034.519.22117.927.9993.05388.21
(b) Integrated System
F 1 F 2 F 3 F 4 F 5 F 6 F 7 F 8 F 9 F 10 F 11 ω R ω S Total
υ 0 1037.600000000106.10001143.8
P 1 01031.2000000001.035.4301037.6
P 2 00757.538.58000000000796.0
P 3 0000347.897.9252.927.8200000506.4
P 4 0000000000038.58038.58
P 5 000000000000351.6351.6
P 6 000062.2817.549.481.400000090.69
P 7 0000000000049.01049.01
P 8 000000009.2200009.22
P 9 0000000000009.229.22
P 10 000000000025.190025.19
P 11 00000000000026.2126.21
Total1037.61031.2757.538.58410.0115.562.409.229.22106.126.2193.01387.0
Figure 3. Resources consumption comparison, between isolated (a) and integrated system (b).
Figure 3. Resources consumption comparison, between isolated (a) and integrated system (b).
Entropy 12 00591 g003
The Fuel–Product tables allow understanding the origin of these numbers. Although the fuel consumed by the power plant increases, the fuel consumed by clinker decreases, because part of the clinker is substituted by ash. Similarly, the fuel consumed by the natural gas boiler disappears, because all process steam is now imported from the power plant. It should be noted that the Fuel-Product table provides interesting results with clear interpretation because flows appearing in this table are not related to detailed flows of the physical structure but with productive flows related to the purpose of the components.
To understand better the origin of the savings caused by the integration, unit costs of the different products are needed. These costs have been calculated by applying the formulation presented in Section 4, and are listed in Table 5.
Table 5. Comparison of unit cost for plant integration.
Table 5. Comparison of unit cost for plant integration.
Isolated SystemIntegrated System
NrProcess C P (MW) c p (MW/MW) C P (MW) c p (MW/MW)
1Ash Separator1073.181.0581096.171.056
2Burner1066.511.3701089.351.368
3Boiler1103.602.2131125.272.222
4Stack51.681.37052.791.368
5Turbines1014.832.8871014.132.885
6Feedwater Heater327.793.671327.573.612
7Condenser151.923.100151.823.098
8Natural Gas Boiler34.513.743N/AN/A
9Steam Mixer34.513.74322.432.433
10Cement Kiln117.904.213106.114.213
11Clinker Mixer117.904.213107.194.090
The unit cost of the product of the ash separator is slightly higher than 1, because it includes the cost of ash and flue gases which are charged to this component. The costs of the burner’s and stack’s product increase up to around 1.37 because of the irreversibility generated in the combustion. Due to heat transfer irreversibility, the cost of steam produced by the boiler increases up to 2.2. The cost of electricity (product of the turbines) increases up to more than 2.8 and the costs of the feedwater heaters and condenser products are greater than 3. It can be seen that as the productive process goes forward, cost increases because of irreversibilities appearing in the different components.
The production cost of the steam decreases significantly with the integration. This reduction shows clearly the interest of the integration and how thermoeconomic analysis can help to detect integration opportunities: a key point is to substitute a given product by another with a lower cost.
The substitution of part of the clinker (which has a cost of about 4) by ash (which costs around 1) causes a reduction of the cost of the clinker mixer. Besides, the amount of ashes which were disposed of decreases, causing also a slight reduction of the cost of its product “clean coal” (1.058 to 1.056) and consequently, a reduction of the production costs of the following components, in particular a reduction of 0.7 MW in the electricity cost.
Finally, it should be noted that this example of application corresponds to a steady-state situation close to design conditions. Important issues such as transient conditions, variable demands of electricity, steam and/or cement, or materials/energy storage have not been considered. To take them into account, the same methodology should be applied several times for a set of representative situations, thus obtaining a set of solutions. Anyway, the systematic analysis of Thermoeconomics provides a rational basis (because it follows the physical process of cost formation) to establish a fair price of the interchanged flows.

7. Conclusions

Thermoeconomic analysis is proposed as a systemic methodology based on physical roots for the analysis of integrations that characterize Industrial Ecology. The main concepts and tools of Thermoeconomics have been summarized and new ideas related to Industrial Ecology (such as the recycling ratio) have been introduced. This formulation has been applied to a case study comprising a coal-fired power plant, a cement kiln and a gas-fired boiler producing steam. Comparison of the Fuel Product tables with and without integration shows clearly how the total resources savings are formed (i.e. how the fuel and products of all components vary). Besides, the analysis of the unit costs not only shows how they are reduced due to the integration but also justifies clearly its interest. For example, it is better to bleed steam from the power plant than to produce it separately because the cost of the former is higher than that of the latter. The case of ashes is even more interesting because it is a win-win situation: reduction of cost of clinker produced (benefits for the cement plant) and reduction of cost of ashes charged to the power plant.
Input-Output analysis is shown as a common tool used in Industrial Ecology, whereas Thermoeconomics and Symbolic Exergoeconomics [30] in particular, combines the exergy and IO analysis to study the process of cost formation of products and wastes. Therefore IO appears as the common mathematical framework for both disciplines.
This paper is a first and promising step in the application of Thermoeconomics to Industrial Ecology, which can help to solve several important problems such as the identification of possibilities of integration and efficiency improvement, quantification of benefits obtained by integration or determination of prices based on physical roots. Furthermore, all Thermoeconomic techniques developed during years for the analysis, optimization, and diagnosis of energy systems can now be applied to Industrial Ecology.

Nomenclature

n 
Number of processes
E 
Exergy of a flow (kW)
F 
Fuel exergy of a component (kW)
P 
Product exergy of a component (kW)
I 
Irreversibility of a component (kW)
C 
Exergy cost (kW)
c 
Unit exergy cost (kW/kW)
y 
Exergy distribution ratios

 Greek letters

Δ
Increment
ψ
Residue cost distribution ratio
ω 
Exergy of system output (kW)
ν 
Exergy of system external resources (kW)
γ 
Waste exergy disposal ratio

 Matrix and Vectors

[FP]
Input–Output matrix for productive processes (n × n)
FP
Matrix of exergy distribution ratios (n × n)
RP
Matrix of waste distribution ratios (n × n)
P*|
Production cost matrix operator (n × n)
CF
Fuel cost of each process (n × 1)
CP
Product cost of each process (n × 1)
CR
Waste cost of each process (n × 1)
ĜR
Waste disposal ratio matrix (n × 1)
μ
Unity vector (n × 1)
Û
Identity matrix (n × 1)

 Subscripts

0
Environment or system outlet
S
Related to final products
T
Total system
F
Related to Fuel
P
Related to Product
R
Related to Residual or Waste

 Superscripts

ˆ
Diagonal matrix of a vector
t
Transpose matrix
−1
Inverse matrix
*
Exergy cost

Glossary

Abatement Cost: 
Amount of resources required to eliminate an undesired output or waste.
Embodied energy: 
The amount of energy required to produce a given product.
Embodied exergy: 
The amount of exergy required to produce a given product.
Energy system: 
A system that transforms various energy forms to other energy forms, of which at least one is useful.
Exergy (unit) cost: 
Amount of resources, expressed in terms of exergy, to obtain (a unit of) a given product.
Exergy: 
The maximum theoretical useful work that can be obtained if a thermodynamic system is brought into thermodynamic equilibrium with the environment, while the system interacts with the environment only.
Industrial Ecology (IE): 
A systems-based, multidisciplinary methodology that seeks to understand the behavior of complex integrated systems. The field approaches issues of sustainability by examining problems from multiple perspectives, usually involving aspects of sociology, the environment, economy and technology.
Irreversibility: 
Is a synonymous of exergy destruction, which represents the energy quality degradation occurring in whatever physical process.
Life Cycle Assessment(LCA): 
The analysis and evaluation of the environmental impacts of a given product or service required by its existence.
Productive structure: 
Scheme of the function of the different process units and their interactions in a system. It represents how the resources consumed by the system are distributed among the different pieces of equipment and converted into the final plant product.
Thermoeconomics: 
A contraction of the terms “thermodynamics” and “economics”, implying the combined application of these two disciplines for the analysis, improvement, and optimization of energy systems.

References

  1. Graedel, T.; Allenby, B. Industrial Ecology; Prentice Hall: Englewood Cliffs, NJ, USA, 1995. [Google Scholar]
  2. USPCSD (US President’s Council on Sustainable Development). Eco-industrial Park Workshop Proceedings, Cape Charles, Virginia, 17th–18th October, 1996.
  3. Frosch, R.; Gallopoulos, N. Strategies for manufacturing. Sci. Am. 1989, 261, 144–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Dunn, B.; Steinmann, A. Industrial ecology for sustainable communities. J. Environ. Plann. Manage. 1998, 41, 661–672. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Chertow, M. Industrial symbiosis: Literature and taxonomy. Annu. Rev. Energy Environ. 2000, 25, 313–337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Chertow, M. Uncovering industrial symbiosis. J. Ind. Ecol. 2007, 11, 11–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Gibbs, D.; Deutz, P.; Proctor, A. Industrial ecology and eco-industrial development: A potential paradigm for local and regional development? Reg. Stud. 2005, 39, 171–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Ayres, R.; Ayres, L. Industrial Ecology. Towards Closing the Material Cycle; Edward Elgar Publishing: Northampton, MA, USA, 1996. [Google Scholar]
  9. Connelly, L.; Coshland, C. Exergy and industrial ecology. Part 2: A non-dimensional analysis of means to reduce resource depletion. Exergy Int. J. 2001, 1, 234–255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Finnveden, G.; Ostland, P. Exergies of natural resources in life-cycle assessment and other applications. Energy 1997, 22, 923–931. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Cornelissen, R.; Hirs, G. The value of the exergetic life cycle assessment besides the LCA. Energy Convers. Manage. 2002, 43, 1417–1424. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Dewulf, J.; Langenhove, H.V. Assessment of the sustainability of technology by means of a thermodynamically based Life Cycle Analysis ESPR. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. Int. 2002, 9, 267–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  13. Dewulf, J.; Langenhove, H.V. Integrating industrial ecology principles into a set of environmental sustainability indicators for technology assessment. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2005, 43, 419–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Tribus, M.; Evans, R.B. A contribution to the theory of thermoeconomics. Technical report, Report No. 62–63; Department of Engineering, UCLA: Los Angeles, CA, USA, 1962. [Google Scholar]
  15. Miller, R.; Blair, P. Input-Output Analysis. Foundations and Extensions, 2nd ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  16. Valero, A.; Lozano, M.; Muñoz, M. A general theory of exergy saving. Part I: On the exergetic cost. In Computer Aided Engineering and Energy Systems, Volume 3: Second Law Analysis and Modeling; Gaggooli, R., Ed.; ASME: New York, NY, USA, 1986; Volume 2–3, pp. 1–8. [Google Scholar]
  17. Szargut, J.; Morris, D. Cumulative exergy consumption and cumulative degree of perfection of chemical processes. Int. J. Energy Res. 1987, 11, 245–261. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Valero, A.; Correas, L.; Zaleta, A.; Lazzaretto, A.; Reini, M.; Verda, V.; Rangel, V. On the Thermoeconomic approach to the diagnosis of energy system malfunctions. Energy 2004, 29, 1875–1907. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Suh, S. (Ed.) Handbook of Input-Output Economics in Industrial Ecology; Spinger Science: NY, New York, USA, 2009.
  20. Hendrickson, C.T.; Lave, L.B.; Matthews, H.S. Environmental Live Cycle Assessment of Goods and Services. An Input-Output Approach; Resources for the Future: Washington, DC, USA, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  21. Hau, J.; Bakshi, B. Expanding exergy analysis to account for ecosystem products and services. Environ. Sci. Technol. 2004, 38, 3768–3777. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  22. Nakamura, S.; Kondo, Y. Waste Input-Output Analysis Concepts and Application to Industrial Ecology (Eco-Efficiency in Industry and Science); Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2009; Volume 26. [Google Scholar]
  23. Torres, C.; Serra, L.; Valero, A. The productive structure and thermoeconomic theories of system optimization. In Thermodynamics and The Design, Analysis and Improviment of Energy Systems; Duncan, A., Fiszdon, J., O’Neal, D., Braven, K., Eds.; ASME: New York, NY, USA, 1996; Volume 36, pp. 429–436. [Google Scholar]
  24. El-Sayed, Y. The Thermoeconomics of Energy Conversion; Pergamon: Oxford, UK, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  25. Perez, E.; Torres, C. TAESS. Thermoeconomic Analysis of Energy System Software. CIRCE. Centro de Investigación de Recursos y Consumos Energéticos, 2007. Available online: http://www.exergoecology.com (accessed March 15, 2010).
  26. Torres, C.; Valero, A.; Rangel, V.; Zaleta, A. On the cost formation process of the residues. Energy 2008, 33, 144–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Usón, S. Comparative analysis of causal diagnosis methods of malfunctions in power cycles . PhD thesis, Deparment of Mechanical Engineering, University of Zaragoza, Spain, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  28. Integrated Pollution Prevention and Control Bureau, Institute for Prospective and Technological Studies, Joint Research Centre, European Commission. Best Available Techniques Reference Document on Lime and Cement Industries; European Commission: Sevilla, Spain, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  29. Valero, A.; Valero, A. A thermodynamic aproach for acounting the earth’s mineral capital. he case of Bauxite–aluminium and Limestone–lime Chains. Energy 2010, 35, 229–238. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Torres, C. Symbolic thermoeconomic analysis of energy systems. In Exergy, Energy System Analysis and Optimization; Frangopoulos, C., Ed.; Eolss Publishers: Oxford, UK, 2009; Volume 2, pp. 61–82. [Google Scholar]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Valero, A.; Usón, S.; Torres, C.; Valero, A. Application of Thermoeconomics to Industrial Ecology. Entropy 2010, 12, 591-612. https://doi.org/10.3390/e12030591

AMA Style

Valero A, Usón S, Torres C, Valero A. Application of Thermoeconomics to Industrial Ecology. Entropy. 2010; 12(3):591-612. https://doi.org/10.3390/e12030591

Chicago/Turabian Style

Valero, Antonio, Sergio Usón, César Torres, and Alicia Valero. 2010. "Application of Thermoeconomics to Industrial Ecology" Entropy 12, no. 3: 591-612. https://doi.org/10.3390/e12030591

APA Style

Valero, A., Usón, S., Torres, C., & Valero, A. (2010). Application of Thermoeconomics to Industrial Ecology. Entropy, 12(3), 591-612. https://doi.org/10.3390/e12030591

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop