Next Article in Journal
Bullwhip Entropy Analysis and Chaos Control in the Supply Chain with Sales Game and Consumer Returns
Next Article in Special Issue
Entropy in the Tangled Nature Model of Evolution
Previous Article in Journal
Response Surface Methodology Control Rod Position Optimization of a Pressurized Water Reactor Core Considering Both High Safety and Low Energy Dissipation
Previous Article in Special Issue
Entropies of the Chinese Land Use/Cover Change from 1990 to 2010 at a County Level
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Concept Paper

Discussing Landscape Compositional Scenarios Generated with Maximization of Non-Expected Utility Decision Models Based on Weighted Entropies

by
José Pinto Casquilho
1,2,* and
Francisco Castro Rego
2,*
1
Graduate and Research Program, Universidade Nacional Timor Lorosa’e, R. Formosa, Díli, Timor-Leste
2
Centro de Ecologia Aplicada “Prof. Baeta Neves”, Instituto Superior de Agronomia, Universidade de Lisboa, InBio, Tapada da Ajuda, 1349-017 Lisboa, Portugal
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Entropy 2017, 19(2), 66; https://doi.org/10.3390/e19020066
Submission received: 27 September 2016 / Revised: 26 January 2017 / Accepted: 6 February 2017 / Published: 10 February 2017
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Entropy in Landscape Ecology)

Abstract

:
The search for hypothetical optimal solutions of landscape composition is a major issue in landscape planning and it can be outlined in a two-dimensional decision space involving economic value and landscape diversity, the latter being considered as a potential safeguard to the provision of services and externalities not accounted in the economic value. In this paper, we use decision models with different utility valuations combined with weighted entropies respectively incorporating rarity factors associated to Gini-Simpson and Shannon measures. A small example of this framework is provided and discussed for landscape compositional scenarios in the region of Nisa, Portugal. The optimal solutions relative to the different cases considered are assessed in the two-dimensional decision space using a benchmark indicator. The results indicate that the likely best combination is achieved by the solution using Shannon weighted entropy and a square root utility function, corresponding to a risk-averse behavior associated to the precautionary principle linked to safeguarding landscape diversity, anchoring for ecosystem services provision and other externalities. Further developments are suggested, mainly those relative to the hypothesis that the decision models here outlined could be used to revisit the stability-complexity debate in the field of ecological studies.

1. Introduction

There are two distinct uses for the word entropy in landscape ecology, either related to the scientific field of thermodynamics or to information theory, and though there is a formal analogy these concepts are claimed to represent scientific disciplines [1].
In this paper we will focus on the information theory perspective, recalling that Shannon [2] derived the entropy of the set of probabilities p 1 ,   ,   p n denoted H = K i = 1 n p i log p i (with K > 0 ) as a measure of uncertainty. Therefore, as Lindley [3] pointed out, Shannon introduced two fundamental ideas: that information is a statistical concept and that, on the basis of frequency distribution, there is an essentially unique function which measures the amount of information; function H is correlatively said to be a measure of the amount of uncertainty represented by a probability distribution [4] or the average randomness of a stochastic system [5]. Shannon based his deductive axiomatic procedure on previous work done by Hartley [6] aiming to compare capacities of several systems to transmit information, a concept there defined to be proportional to the number of selections, using a measure outlined as the logarithm of the number of possible sequences of symbols, following an analogy with the physical entropy in statistical mechanics first introduced by Boltzman. About a decade later, statistical entropy was introduced in ecological studies either as a measure of community stability by MacArthur [7] or as a diversity index of assemblages of species by Margalef [8], who used Shannon’s formula as equivalent to Brillouin’s expression [9] and interpreted it as the average number of bits per individual [10]. Pielou [11] reviewed the theme, stating that diversity in an ecological system is directly related to the amount of uncertainty regarding the identity of an individual selected at random from a community.
Shannon entropy was not the only source for diversity measures in ecology; the other main example was ascribed to Simpson’s concentration measure [12], published in 1949, here denoted C = i = 1 n p i 2 , also reformulated as D = 1 C , which is usually referred to as Gini-Simpson index of diversity (e.g., [13,14]). In 1961, Rènyi [15] outlined a generalization of Shannon entropy as a 1-parameter functional family, and Hill [16], about a decade later, used the exponential form of Rènyi’s generalized entropy to derive what he called diversity numbers, which were shown to be related with Shannon and Simpson diversity measures. In the 1980s, Rao introduced a generalization of Gini-Simpson index (see [13]), commonly mentioned as quadratic entropy and interpreted as the abundance-weighted mean distance between species [17], expressed as Q = i = 1 s j = 1 s d i j p i p j . A review of diversity measures relative to community assemblages with focus on semantic content and distinction between simplex and complex issues was made by Ricotta [18].
In a process that can be classified as transference of concepts from community studies in ecology to broader space scales concerning landscapes or regions, thus replacing relative abundance of species in a community for land cover types (or habitats) areal proportions, we get into diversity metrics in landscape characterization and research (see [19,20,21] for a review). Landscape composition can be defined as the variety and abundance of different land cover types within the landscape [22] and different diversity indices measure distinct aspects of the partition of abundance between landscape elements [23]. In this paper, we will not deal with landscape spatial entropy measures related with heterogeneity and fragmentation of the habitats (see [1]).
There is a considerable body of evidence indicating, in the absence of legal constraints, change in human-dominated landscapes is substantially driven by economic values (e.g., [24]). Such land-use decisions are usually considered to follow utility maximization strategies associated with land conversion [25], although it can be argued that public preferences, for instance relative to forest management, are not influenced solely by the particular attributes of competing management objectives [26].
Non-expected utility models were developed in environmental and natural resources economics as a consequence for the realization that models must accommodate preferences that are non-linear in the probabilities [27], thus becoming an alternative to traditional expected utility methodology. For instance, recently, researchers concluded that a non-expected utility model was needed to evaluate environmental risks and preferences related to forest wildfires in Poland [28].
In this paper, we present two original decision models that combine expected utility and weighted entropies, which is a novel example of the non-expected utility framework, and discuss how the optimal points of the models using different utility valuations generate solutions to the composition of the landscape mosaic that will be assessed relative to the trade-off between economic value and landscape diversity.

2. Methodology

2.1. Background

A review of non-expected utility theory was made by Starmer [29], in which individuals made decisions based on finite lotteries as a function of a vector of fixed consequences X = ( x 1 ,   x 2 ,   ,   x n ) mapped into real values named utilities, denoted u ( X ) = ( u ( x 1 ) ,   ,   u ( x n ) ) , which are associated with the correspondent vector of unknown probabilities p = ( p 1 ,   ,   p n ) . In this context, individuals are facing a decision problem of uncertainty and are assumed to maximize the functional W ( p ) = i = 1 n u ( x i ) π ( p i ) , where { π ( p i ) } i = 1 , , n are decision weights. The general explanation for this concept is that when individuals are choosing between two lotteries they tend to perceive the probabilities subjectively, and transfer to decision weights with some systematic deviation between the decision weights and the objective probabilities [30]. The weighting function of the probabilities π ( · ) : [ 0 ,   1 ] [ 0 ,   1 ] is assumed to be continuous and non-decreasing, verifying the boundary conditions π ( 0 ) = 0 and π ( 1 ) = 1 (e.g., [31,32]).
A non-expected utility framework involving the sum of expected utility and Shannon entropy defined as a measure of risk was discussed as a decision-making model, later reframed into a normalized expected utility-entropy measure of risk [33]. Also, there are other utility-based motivations for different entropy measures, anchoring decision theoretic models (e.g., [34,35]).
Weighted Shannon entropy was conceived as a quantitative-qualitative measure of information, denoted I = c i = 1 n u i p i log p i with c > 0 , introduced and axiomatized by Belis and Guiasu [36] incorporating objective probabilities { p i } i = 1 , , n and subjective utilities { u i } i = 1 , , n . About a decade later, Aggarwal and Picard [37], following a paper of Emptoz [38], generalized to the concept of entropy of degree β , defined as:
H β = i = 1 n u i p i ( 1 p i β 1 ) / ( 1 2 1 β )  with  β 1 .
Using l’Hôpital’s rule, we get the result lim β 1 H β = I (with c = 1 / log 2 ) thus allowing for an extension, using natural logarithms, to: H 1 × log 2 = H 1 = i = 1 n u i p i log p i . Also, a direct substitution shows that H 2 / 2 = H 2 = i = 1 n u i p i ( 1 p i ) , a formula named the weighted Gini-Simpson index (e.g., [39,40,41]) or weighted Simpson index [42]. Next, we shall consider that for β = 1 , 2 the term H β stands for two different weighted entropies related through Equation (1), except for a multiplicative constant.
In addition, there are other links between H 1 and H 2 that we can highlight. Near x = 1 we have the first order Taylor’s approximation log x x 1 , so it follows that log p i 1 p i and the weighted Gini-Simpson index becomes the weighted average of the first order approximation of information values ( log p i ) in Shannon entropy (when p i < 0.5 the approximation may be considered quite poor).

2.2. Decision Models

To be considered relevant the problem must embody dimension n 3 associated with a n 1 simplex of compositional proportions. In any case, we will be dealing with a functional denoted W β = i = 1 n u i p i + H β for β = 1 , 2 where the term i = 1 n u i p i stands for expected utility E [ U ] . It can be shown that the functional W β for each value of β = 1 , 2 and for a fixed set of positive utilities { u i } i = 1 , , n reduces to a real function which is smooth and concave, allowing determination of constrained maximum points with the method of Lagrange multipliers. In any case, there is only one optimal vector of proportions p * = ( p 1 * , , p n * ) such that i = 1 n p i * = 1 - a solution which is shown to be insensitive to a positive linear transformation of the utilities, or change in units, thus becoming irrelevant to assess the optimal proportions for an area.

2.2.1. The Case for β = 1

For β = 1 we get:
W 1 = i = 1 n u i p i i = 1 n u i p i log p i = i = 1 n u i p i ( 1 log p i ) .
We can rewrite W 1 = i = 1 n u i π 1 , i with the decision weights defined with the expression π 1 , i = p 1 , i ( 1 log p 1 , i ) for i = 1 , , n . It is clear that p 1 , i = 1 is equivalent to π 1 , i = 1 , and (using l’Hôpital’s rule) we have the result lim p 1 , i 0 + π 1 , i = 0 , allowing for the continuity statement defining the range 0 π 1 , i 1 . The real function W 1 was previously presented and discussed (see [43]); in summary, W 1 is a differentiable concave function in the interior of the simplex, attaining minimum and maximum values in the domain. The minimum value is min W 1 = min i = 1 , , n u i and it is possible to locate the maximum point with a Lagrange multiplier method, the coordinates of the maximum point thus being evaluated by computing p 1 , i * = exp ( α * / u i ) for i = 1 , , n , the optimal value of the Lagrange multiplier ( α * ) defined implicitly by the equation α * :   i = 1 n exp ( α / u i ) = 1 which can be solved with numerical methods providing a unique solution.

2.2.2. The Case for β = 2

For β = 2 we have:
W 2 = i = 1 n u i p i + i = 1 n u i p i ( 1 p i ) = i = 1 n u i p i ( 2 p i ) .
In parallel with what was shown in the previous section relative to Equation (2), now we get W 2 = i = 1 n u i π 2 , i with the decision weights here defined as π 2 , i = p 2 , i ( 2 p 2 , i ) for i = 1 , , n . Also, we see that p 2 , i = 0 implies π 2 , i = 0 and p 2 , i = 1 entails π 2 , i = 1 , so we get 0 π 2 , i 1 . The real function W 2 displayed in Equation (3) was also previously studied (see [44]), and, analogously to what was stated relative to function W 1 shown in Equation (2), it is also a smooth and concave real function with minimum value evaluated like min W 2 = min i = 1 , , n u i , while the maximum point is attainable with a Lagrange multiplier method checked for the feasibility of solutions verifying altogether the full set of inequalities u i > ( n 1 ) / i = 1 n 1 / u i , for i = 1 , , n . In general, the set of inequalities doesn’t hold and we have to proceed with an algorithm obtaining the maximum point coordinates defined with the expression p 2 , i * = 1 ( k 1 ) / ( u i i = 1 k 1 / u i ) and 2 k n . When k < n we have n k null coordinates in the optimal solution. Whether k = 2 we get the simple results p 2 , i * = u i / ( u i + u j ) and p 2 , j * = u j / ( u i + u j ) .

2.3. Decision Space

The decision space is conceived with two dimensions: economic value stricto sensu, meaning economic assessment relative to forest products with market valuation, and landscape diversity. Economic value will be computed with the standard weighted average formula V = i = 1 n v 1 p i * , where { v i } i = 1 , , n is a set of economic values and { p i * } i = 1 , , n is the set of optimal proportions which will be computed for the cases W 1 and W 2 and different utility valuations.
Landscape diversity shall be assessed with the Hill number N 1 = exp ( i = 1 n p i * log p i * ) defined in [15], which can be interpreted as the “number” of abundant habitats - making an analogy with the correspondent statement of Alatalo concerning species [45]. The option for this bi-dimensional decision space refers to the precautionary principle, as it is acknowledged that the resilience of a system can be lost because of optimal control strategies focused on a single variable [46], and it is believed that the trade-off between economic value and landscape diversity can be relevant to safeguard ecosystem services and other externalities. Also, a benchmark indicator represented by the formula B = V × N 1 will be used to help the discussion of results. Lastly, we consider that the decision models we compare here are tools for optimizing landscape composition, not prescriptive methods.

3. Results

We used data from another source (see Table 1 in [47]), which reports the average economic values of different forest habitats in the region of Nisa, Portugal, expressed in euros per hectare (€/ha). This simple example has dimensions n = 4 , corresponding to four forest habitats or land cover types: holm oak; blue gum; cork oak and umbrella pine. Since our aim is merely to illustrate the methodology, the characterization of such economic values will be ignored except for highlighting that they just reflect forest products with market valuation and do not account for externalities and ecosystem services as other approaches do (e.g., [48]).
In Table 1 we present the economic values ( v i ) as well as their utility valuation using the power function denoted u i = v i ω (e.g., [49]) with ω = ½   , 1   , 2 . Those three cases are relative to different geometries of utility function, since utility theory states that risk-averse behavior is typically related to concave utility transformations, thus utility transformations ( u i ) herein considered are: linear neutral with ω = 1 , square-root (concave) with ω = 0.5 and quadratic (convex) with ω = 2 .
Applying formulas previously mentioned in Section 2.2.1 and Section 2.2.2 to data in Table 1 we computed the results summarized in Table 2, relative to the optimal proportions in each case, respectively obtained with the maximization of W 1 and W 2 using the utilities specified by the exponent ω of the power value function.
In Table 3 we assess the results presented in Table 2, by evaluating the economic value ( V = i = 1 n v 1 p i * in €/ha) and landscape diversity associated with each solution, the last computed with the second Hill number N 1 . Each case is benchmarked by the indicator value B = V × N 1 . The values of the measures relative to the indifference solution, or maximum landscape diversity, where each forest habitat type occupies 25% of the area and thus the correspondent value of the second Hill number is N 1 = 4 and the benchmark indicator evaluates as the sum of economic values at stake.

4. Discussion

In the example analysis we would attain the minimum value of the benchmark indicator with the whole area occupied by holm oak forest (Qr), scoring B = 112 , as we have in that case V = 112 and N 1 = 1 . On the other hand, the maximum landscape diversity would provide B = 1360 with the average economic value of V = 340 and N 1 = 4 . A similar value for B is attained with the decision model W 1 and neutral utilities ( ω = 1 ), enhancing economic value to ca. V = 530 , which is about 86% of the maximum of 618, and a diversity number of ca. N 1 = 2.55 , meaning that the number of abundant habitats is over 63% of the maximum of 4. The highest value of the benchmark indicator is achieved with the decision model W 1 and square root utilities, ca. B = 1579 , leading to an economic value of V = 451 , about 73% of the maximum, and a diversity number of N 1 = 3.5 , over 87% of the maximum value, which seems to be the most suitable compromise within the decision space, if we consider that landscape diversity is a general potential safeguard relative to ecosystem services and other externalities not accounted in the economic value. In fact, the number of patch types may indicate the level of resource diversity while the proportions may determine the dominance of critical resources [49], and it is believed that more variation in a landscape generally leads to greater genetic and species diversity and this, in turn, stabilizes populations and strengthens the different ecosystem elements in the landscape which provides for more varied ecosystem services, which may enhance the resilience of the local economy [50]. Even so, the framework here discussed has two major limitations: it presupposes that the habitats are spatially interchangeable in the whole area considered, which would not be the case in most actual situations where there will be ecological constraints associated with heterogeneity and fragmentation in patches; and also, it does not account for the distinction between the ecological value of the habitats concerning differences between abundant or rare, even endangered, species. The last issue could be bypassed with a parallel assessment using ecological values for conservation of the habitats, or a broader version of economic values incorporating externalities such as ecosystem or landscape services.
In summary, comparing the optimal proportions of the decision models W 1 and W 2 relative to the same set of utilities in a small dimension example ( n = 4 ), the analysis shows that W 1 performs in a considerably more conservative way relative to differences in utilities enhancing landscape diversity, except for the quadratic risk-prone transformation where both models perform about the same. The link to this difference is rooted in the fact that each model incorporates a rarity valuation measure, which for W 1 , defined in Equation (2), is the nonlinear factor r 1 , i = log p 1 , i (e.g., [51]) and for W 2 is the linear function r 2 , i = 1 p 2 , i as we can check in Equation (3); when the habitat i vanishes we get respectively the results lim p 1 , i 0 + ( log p 1 , i ) = + and lim p 2 , i 0 + ( 1 p 2 , i ) = 1 , the infinite rarity value helping counteracting extinction.
Highlighting areas for future research, we point out that the trends of the results presented here should be tested relative to an analogous higher dimensional problem, and also using other utility valuation functions such as the logarithmic or negative exponential and a valuation procedure that incorporates an ecological assessment of singularities.
Also, the framework we describe in this paper could be helpful in revisiting the diversity-stability debate relative to dynamic equilibrium points in ecological studies. In general, when dealing with equilibrium points in dynamic systems we consider minima under potential formulation and, in probability formulation, we look for the opposite: we consider maxima, while minima are excluded [52]. Thus, we could think of optimal solutions of the models here discussed as minimum points of the symmetric forms W 1 and W 2 considered to be potential functions governing dynamic systems. The utilities { u i } i = 1 , , n then could better be replaced by some kind of time indexed characteristic positive values of the different habitats, say { w i ( t ) } i = 1 , , n , for example relative to a measure of their resilience. In fact, we can go back to 1937 and Volterra’s works [53] and find a symmetric form of weighted Shannon entropy, though conceived with whole numbers, not proportions, which is to be minimized concerning an entity called “vital action” of the community, when searching for an equilibrium. About six decades later, we find weighted Simpson index as a potential function characterizing an inverse measure for antigenic diversity of virus populations [54].
Concerning the object landscape, a recent review based on agent-based modeling of landscape dynamics shows a cornucopia of methods with emphasis on comparative approaches, pursuing the continuation of innovative modeling for understanding landscape change, its causes and consequences for sustainability in the Anthropocene [55].

Acknowledgments

We acknowledge an anonymous reviewer for several text corrections and comments, which were included in the final version of the text. This work is funded by FEDER funds through the Operational Program for Competitiveness Factors-COMPETE and by National Funds through FCT-Foundation for Science and Technology under the UID/BIA/50027/2013 and POCI-01-0145-FEDER-006821.

Author Contributions

José Pinto Casquilho conceived the initial draft and Francisco Castro Rego made suggestions and corrections, so that both authors wrote together the paper. All authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Vranken, I.; Baudry, J.; Aubinet, M.; Visser, M.; Bogaert, J. A review on the use of entropy in landscape ecology: Heterogeneity, unpredictability, scale dependence and their links with thermodynamics. Landsc. Ecol. 2015, 30, 51–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  2. Shannon, C.E. A mathematical theory of communication. Bell Syst. Tech. J. 1948, 27, 379–423. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Lindley, D.V. On a measure of the information provided by an experiment. Ann. Math. Stat. 1956, 27, 986–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Jaynes, E.T. Information theory and statistical mechanics. Phys. Rev. 1957, 106, 620–630. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Kornreich, P. Mathematical Models of Information and Stochastic Systems; CRC Press: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  6. Hartley, R.V.L. Transmission of information. Bell Syst. Tech. J. 1927, 7, 535–563. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. MacArthur, R. Fluctuations of animal populations and a measure of community stability. Ecology 1955, 36, 533–536. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Margalef, R. Information Theory in Ecology; Hall, W., Translator; Memorias de la Real Academia de Ciencias y Artes de Barcelona: Barcelona, Spain, 1957; Volume 23, pp. 373–449. [Google Scholar]
  9. Brillouin, L. Physical entropy and information. J. Appl. Phys. 1951, 22, 338–343. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Margalef, R. On certain unifying principles in ecology. Am. Nat. 1963, 97, 357–374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Pielou, E.C. Shannon’s formula as a measure of specific diversity: Its use and misuse. Am. Nat. 1966, 100, 463–465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Simpson, E.H. Measurement of diversity. Nature 1949, 163, 688. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Rao, C.R. Diversity and dissimilarity coefficients: A unified approach. Theor. Popul. Biol. 1982, 21, 24–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Zaller, J.G.; Kerschbaumer, G.; Rizzoli, R.; Tiefenbacher, A.; Gruber, E.; Schedl, H. Monitoring arthropods in protected grasslands: Comparing pitfall trapping, quadrat sampling and video monitoring. Web Ecol. 2015, 15, 15–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Rènyi, A. On measures of entropy and information. In Proceedings of the Fourth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability, Berkley, CA, USA, 20 June–30 July 1961; Volume 1, pp. 547–561.
  16. Hill, M.O. Diversity and evenness: A unifying notation and its consequences. Ecology 1973, 54, 427–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Chiu, C.-H.; Chao, A. Distance-based functional diversity measures and their decomposition: A framework based on Hill numbers. PLoS ONE 2014, 9, e100014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  18. Ricotta, C. A semantic taxonomy for diversity measures. Acta Biotheor. 2007, 55, 23–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  19. Frank, S.; Fürst, C.; Koschke, L.; Makeshin, F. A contribution towards a transfer of the ecosystem service concept to landscape planning using landscape metrics. Ecol. Indic. 2012, 21, 30–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Uuemaa, E.; Antrop, M.; Roosaare, J.; Marja, R.; Mander, U. Landscape metrics and indices: An overview of their use in landscape research. Living Rev. Landsc. Res. 2009, 3, 1–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Ramezani, H. A note on the normalized definition of Shannon’s diversity index in landscape pattern analysis. Environ. Nat. Resour. Res. 2012, 2, 54–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Diaz-Varela, E.; Roces-Diaz, J.V.; Álvarez-Álvarez, P. Detection of landscape heterogeneity at multiple scales: Use of the Quadratic Entropy index. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2016, 153, 149–159. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Carranza, M.L.; Acosta, A.; Ricotta, C. Analyzing landscape diversity in time: The use of Rènyi’s generalized entropy function. Ecol. Indic. 2007, 7, 505–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Verbič, M.; Slabe-Erker, R. An econometric analysis of willingness-to-pay for sustainable development: A case study of the Volčji Potok landscape area. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 68, 1316–1328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Satake, A.; Janssen, M.A.; Levin, S.A.; Iwasa, Y. Synchronized deforestation induced by social learning under uncertainty of forest-use value. Ecol. Econ. 2007, 63, 452–462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Smith, J.W.; Siderelis, C.; Moore, R.L.; Anderson, D.H. The effects of place meanings and social capital on desired forest management outcomes: A stated preference experiment. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2012, 196, 207–218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Shaw, W.D.; Woodward, R.T. Why environmental and resource economists should care about non-expected utility models. Resour. Energy Econ. 2008, 30, 66–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Bartzack, A.; Chilton, S.; Meyerhoff, J. Wildfires in Poland: The impact of risk preferences and loss aversion on environmental choices. Ecol. Econ. 2015, 116, 300–309. [Google Scholar]
  29. Starmer, C. Developments in non-expected utility theory: The hunt for a descriptive theory of choice under risk. J. Econ. Lit. 2000, 38, 332–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Levy, H. Stochastic Dominance, 3rd ed.; Springer: Cham, Switzerland, 2016. [Google Scholar]
  31. Wu, G.; Gonzalez, R. Nonlinear decision weights in choice under uncertainty. Manag. Sci. 1999, 45, 74–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Weber, E.U. From subjective probabilities to decision weights: The effect of asymmetric loss functions on the evaluation of uncertain outcomes and events. Psychol. Bull. 1994, 115, 228–242. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Yang, J.; Qiu, W. Normalized expected utility-entropy measure of risk. Entropy 2014, 16, 3590–3604. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Friedman, C.; Huang, J.; Sandow, S. A utility-based approach to some information measures. Entropy 2007, 9, 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Yu, J.-R.; Lee, W.-Y.; Chiou, W.-J.P. Diversified portfolios with different entropy measures. Appl. Math. Comput. 2014, 241, 47–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Belis, M.; Guiasu, S. A quantitative-qualitative measure of information in cybernetic systems. IEEE Trans. Inf. Theory 1968, 14, 593–594. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Aggarwal, N.L.; Picard, C.-F. Functional equations and information measures with preference. Kybernetika 1978, 14, 174–181. [Google Scholar]
  38. Emptoz, H. Information de Type β Intégrant un Concept d’Utilité. C. R. Acad. Sci. Paris 1976, 282, 911–914. (In French) [Google Scholar]
  39. Guiasu, R.C.; Guiasu, S. Conditional and weighted measures of ecological diversity. Int. J. Uncertain. Fuzz. Knowl. Based Syst. 2003, 11, 283–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Guiasu, R.C.; Guiasu, S. The weighted Gini-Simpson index: Revitalizing an old index of biodiversity. Int. J. Ecol. 2012. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Casquilho, J.P. A methodology to determine the maximum value of weighted Gini-Simpson index. SpringerPlus 2016, 5, 1143. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  42. Subburayalu, S.; Sydnor, T.D. Assessing street tree diversity in four Ohio communities using the Weighted Simpson index. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2012, 106, 44–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Casquilho, J.P. Discussing an expected utility and weighted entropy framework. Nat. Sci. 2014, 6, 545–551. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Casquilho, J.P. Combining expected utility and weighted Gini–Simpson index into a non-expected utility device. TEL 2015, 5, 185–195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Alatalo, R.V. Problems in the measurement of evenness in ecology. Oikos 1981, 37, 199–204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Allen, C.R.; Gunderson, L.H.; Holling, C.S. Commentary on part three articles. In Foundations of Ecological Resilience; Gunderson, L.H., Allen, C.R., Holling, C.S., Eds.; Island Press: Washington DC, USA, 2010; pp. 301–307. [Google Scholar]
  47. Casquilho, J.A.P. Ecomosaico Florestal: Composição, Índices de Informação e Abdução. Rev. Árvore 2012, 36, 321–329. (In Portuguese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Aretano, R.; Petrosillo, I.; Zacarelli, N.; Semeraro, T.; Zurlini, G. People perception of landscape change effects on ecosystem services in small Mediterranean islands: A combination of subjective and objective assessments. Landsc. Urban Plan. 2013, 112, 63–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Li, H.; Wu, J. Landscape pattern analysis: Key issues and challenges. In Key Topics in Landscape Ecology; Wu, J., Hobbs, R., Eds.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2007; pp. 39–61. [Google Scholar]
  50. Schippers, P.; van der Heide, C.M.; Koelewijn, H.P.; Schouten, M.A.H.; Smulders, R.M.J.M.; Cobben, M.M.P.; Sterk, M.; Vos, C.C.; Verboom, J. Landscape diversity enhances the resilience of populations, ecosystems and local economy in rural areas. Landsc. Ecol. 2015, 30, 193–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Duarte, I.; Rego, F.C.; Casquilho, J.P.; Arsénio, P. A Relevance Index for the habitat areas of Natura 2000 network based on their rarity and representativeness. Ecol. Ind. 2016, 61, 202–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Hansen, V.L. Geometry in Nature; A K Peters Ltd.: Wellesley, MA, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  53. Volterra, V. Principes de biologie mathématique. Acta Biotheor. 1937, 3, 1–36. (In French) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Nowak, M.A. The evolutionary dynamics of HIV infections. In Progress in Mathematics; Joseph, A., Mignot, F., Murat, F., Prum, B., Rentschler, R., Eds.; Birkhäuser Verlag: Basel, Switzerland, 1994; Volume 120, pp. 311–326. [Google Scholar]
  55. Millington, J.D.A.; Wainwright, J. Comparative approaches for innovation in agent-based modelling of landscape change. Land 2016, 5, 13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Soil occupation economic values v i ( / h a ) of four forest habitat types in the region of Nisa, Portugal and different utility valuations according to exponent ω . Codes: Qr-Quercus rotundifolia (holm oak); Eg-Eucalyptus globulus (blue gum); Qs-Quercus suber (cork oak); Pp-Pinus pinea (umbrella pine).
Table 1. Soil occupation economic values v i ( / h a ) of four forest habitat types in the region of Nisa, Portugal and different utility valuations according to exponent ω . Codes: Qr-Quercus rotundifolia (holm oak); Eg-Eucalyptus globulus (blue gum); Qs-Quercus suber (cork oak); Pp-Pinus pinea (umbrella pine).
Utilities u i ω Forest Habitat Type
QrEgPpQs
v i (€/ha) 1 112136494618
v i 0.5 10.58311.66222.22624.860
v i 2 2 12,544.018,496.02.4404×10⁵3.8192×10⁵
Table 2. Optimal proportions relative to the maximization of expected utility and weighted entropies models W 1 and W 2 with data specified in Table 1.
Table 2. Optimal proportions relative to the maximization of expected utility and weighted entropies models W 1 and W 2 with data specified in Table 1.
Decision Model ω Forest Habitat Type—Optimal Proportions
QrEgPpQs
W 1 1 p 1 , 1 *   = 0.02 p 1 , 2 *   = 0.05 p 1 , 3 *   = 0.43 p 1 , 4 *   = 0.50
W 2 1 p 2 , 1 *   = 0 p 2 , 2 *   = 0 p 2 , 3 *   = 0.44 p 2 , 4 *   = 0.56
W 1 0.5 p 1 , 1 *   = 0.11 p 1 , 2 *   = 0.14 p 1 , 3 *   = 0.35 p 1 , 4 *   = 0.40
W 2 0.5 p 2 , 1 *   = 0 p 2 , 2 *   = 0 p 2 , 3 *   = 0.47 p 2 , 4 *   = 0.53
W 1 2 p 1 , 1 *   0 p 1 , 2 *   0 p 1 , 3 *   = 0.42 p 1 , 4 *   = 0.58
W 2 2 p 2 , 1 *   = 0 p 2 , 2 *   = 0 p 2 , 3 *   = 0.39 p 2 , 4 *   = 0.61
5.3635 × 10⁻⁸; 1.1725 × 10⁻⁵.
Table 3. Results shown in the bi-dimensional decision space with the dimensions defined as economic value ( V ) and landscape diversity ( N 1 ); B = V × N 1 is a benchmark indicator.
Table 3. Results shown in the bi-dimensional decision space with the dimensions defined as economic value ( V ) and landscape diversity ( N 1 ); B = V × N 1 is a benchmark indicator.
Decision Model Measures
V N 1 B
W 1 ω = 1 530.462.55361354.6
W 2 563.441.98561118.8
W 1 ω = 0.5 451.463.49731578.9
W 2 559.721.99641117.4
W 1 ω = 2 565.921.97451117.4
W 2 569.641.95181111.8
p 0 340.004.00001360.0

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Casquilho, J.P.; Rego, F.C. Discussing Landscape Compositional Scenarios Generated with Maximization of Non-Expected Utility Decision Models Based on Weighted Entropies. Entropy 2017, 19, 66. https://doi.org/10.3390/e19020066

AMA Style

Casquilho JP, Rego FC. Discussing Landscape Compositional Scenarios Generated with Maximization of Non-Expected Utility Decision Models Based on Weighted Entropies. Entropy. 2017; 19(2):66. https://doi.org/10.3390/e19020066

Chicago/Turabian Style

Casquilho, José Pinto, and Francisco Castro Rego. 2017. "Discussing Landscape Compositional Scenarios Generated with Maximization of Non-Expected Utility Decision Models Based on Weighted Entropies" Entropy 19, no. 2: 66. https://doi.org/10.3390/e19020066

APA Style

Casquilho, J. P., & Rego, F. C. (2017). Discussing Landscape Compositional Scenarios Generated with Maximization of Non-Expected Utility Decision Models Based on Weighted Entropies. Entropy, 19(2), 66. https://doi.org/10.3390/e19020066

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop