Next Article in Journal
Kernel-Free Quadratic Surface Support Vector Regression with Non-Negative Constraints
Next Article in Special Issue
Kinetic Models of Wealth Distribution with Extreme Inequality: Numerical Study of Their Stability against Random Exchanges
Previous Article in Journal
A New Analysis of Real-Time Fatality Rate in the Initial Stage of COVID-19
Previous Article in Special Issue
Can the Sci-Tech Innovation Increase the China’s Green Brands Value?—Evidence from Threshold Effect and Spatial Dubin Model
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Productivity vs. Evenness in the U.S. Financial Market: A Business Ecosystem Perspective

Institute of Physics, Faculty of Science, Universidad de la República, Montevideo 11400, Uruguay
Entropy 2023, 25(7), 1029; https://doi.org/10.3390/e25071029
Submission received: 5 June 2023 / Revised: 30 June 2023 / Accepted: 5 July 2023 / Published: 7 July 2023

Abstract

:
This paper starts by presenting an empirical finding in the U.S. stock market: Between 2001 and 2021, high productivity was achieved when the Shannon evenness—measuring the inverse of concentration—dropped. Conversely, when the Shannon evenness soared, productivity plunged. The same inverse relationship between evenness and productivity has been observed in several ecosystems. This suggests explaining this result by adopting the business ecosystem perspective, i.e., regarding the tangle of interactions between companies as an ecological network, in which companies play the role of species. A useful strategy to model such ecological communities is through ensembles of synthetic communities of pairwise interacting species, whose dynamics is described by the Lotka–Volterra generalized equations. Each community is specified by a random interaction matrix whose elements are drawn from a uniform distribution centered around 0. It is shown that the inverse relationship between productivity and evenness can be generated by varying the strength of the interaction between companies. When the strength increases, productivity increases and simultaneously the market evenness decreases. Conversely, when the strength decreases, productivity decreases and evenness increases. This strength can be interpreted as reflecting the looseness of monetary policy, thus providing a link between interest rates and market structure.

1. Introduction

Neoclassical economics, which assumes investors behave with rational expectations in order to maintain an efficient market, is frequently at odds to explain the dynamics of markets. Instead, the agents in markets are not perfectly rational, but rather they are boundedly rational satisfiers [1]. The idiosyncrasies in human behavior make financial markets depart from the assumption of informational efficiency leading for example to excess volatility, i.e., financial markets change more than rational measures of value would suggest [2].
An alternative viewpoint is to regard financial markets as ecosystems with a tangle of interactions between companies, investors, clients, etc. Indeed, according to [3,4], companies are engaged in “competition for differential advantage” which gives firms a position in the marketplace known as an “ecological niche” [3]. Companies survive and grow in the marketplace depending on the actions and reactions of agents permanently adjusting their behavior to match environmental opportunities. Such an ongoing process is similar to the one that operates in ecological systems competing for scarce resources [5,6,7]. That is, a process of co-evolution, shared by markets and ecosystems, in which interdependent species or companies evolve in an endless reciprocal cycle—such that changes in species A set the stage for the natural selection of changes in species B—and vice versa [8]. Co-evolution occurs in different forms, antagonistic, e.g., predators and their prey, mutually competitive, e.g., different species sharing the same trophic level, or cooperative co-evolution, e.g., flowering plants and their pollinators [9].
Moore [10] introduced biological ecology as a metaphor for strategic thinking about business co-evolution and radically new cooperative/competitive relationships. In a similar vein, Farmer and Lo [11] regard markets as co-evolving ecologies of different strategies pursued by companies. These strategies are analogous to a biological species, and the amount of funds deployed by traders following a given strategy is analogous to the population of that species [11]. As the market evolves, the market shares of the inefficient companies decrease while the companies with greatest fitness capture market share. Therefore, companies often play the same role of selection units that species play in ecosystems.
The general goal in this paper is to use the above analogy between markets and ecosystems to better understand the forces that structure markets and determine their productivity. This includes the market responses to external shocks (analogous to environmental perturbations), such as expansive economic policies (analogous to nutrient enrichment), and the susceptibility of companies of being displaced by newcomer companies (species turnover in the case of ecosystems). Furthermore, the above analogy offers an opportunity to harness the potential of applying various powerful techniques from theoretical ecology to the fields of economics and finance. The specific primary objective of this study is to elucidate the inverse relationship detected between productivity and evenness within a set of firms encompassing the largest companies in the U.S. stock market. To accomplish this, we employ a combination of empirical evidence and theoretical modeling from ecology. Unraveling this relationship holds significant importance as it profoundly impacts the functioning of both markets and ecosystems. In fact, this ecological perspective allows us to use two central attributes which emerge from the co-evolution process of species in an ecological community, namely its productivity and its species diversity [12,13] to get insight into market dynamics. Both properties can be defined in several different ways in ecology. Productivity has been characterized by variables that range from direct estimates of energy flow to the ecosystem to accumulated biomass or biomass density (per area or volume) [14,15]. A common metric is the rate of generation of biomass in an ecosystem, usually expressed in units of mass per unit area per unit of time, such as grams per square meter per day [16]. In the case of agricultural crops, productivity is also commonly measured by the total weight per unit area [17], which is known as crop yield [18]. Diversity, in turn, involves concepts ranging from simplest concept of species richness, namely the number of species, to evenness, i.e., the measure of how similar species are in their abundance in an environment [19]. Indeed, species diversity is often intended as a combination of richness and evenness [20].
This study draws on and integrates elements of ecological science and economics, which is the scientific research program of ecological economics (EE), understood as “the relationship between ecosystems and economic systems in the broadest sense” [21]. In addition, it is transdisciplinary and uses methods and complex systems analysis [22].

2. The Business Ecosystem Perspective: Financial Markets as Ecosystems

The business ecosystem perspective refers to a framework or approach that views businesses and organizations as part of a larger interconnected system or ecosystem [10]. In the business ecosystem perspective, the focus is not solely on individual firms operating in isolation, but rather on understanding how they interact and mutually influence each other within the broader context of the ecosystem [23,24,25]. It recognizes that the success and sustainability of any given organization are influenced by the health and dynamics of the entire ecosystem in which it operates. Key features of the business ecosystem perspective include interconnectedness, collaborative relationships, and ecosystem dynamics. Interconnectedness recognizes that firms within the ecosystem are interconnected and depend on each other for resources, capabilities, and market opportunities. Actions and changes in one part of the ecosystem can have ripple effects on other entities within the system. Collaborative relationships refer for example to partnerships and alliances among different companies within the ecosystem. Through ecosystem dynamics, we understand that the perspective acknowledges that ecosystems are dynamic and subject to various forces and disruptions, rather than entities at equilibrium. New entrants, technological advancements, market shifts, or changes in regulatory environments can shape the competitive landscape and the overall dynamics of the ecosystem [10,24].
Using the analogy between ecosystems and markets, companies can be regarded as species and the market value (In this paper ‘market value’ is taken as synonym of market capitalization, i.e., the number of a company’s shares outstanding multiplied by the current price of a single share [26].) of a company as the abundance or biomass of a species [7,11,23,24,25]. Therefore, as in ecology, we consider as proxy for productivity a relative metric, corresponding to total returns—i.e., the rate of variation of the total market value. In addition, as it is carried out in agricultural sciences, we also consider an absolute metric, given by the total market value (analogous to crop yield). Likewise, as a measure of diversity, the Shannon evenness [27]—aka Shannon equitability index is used. This metric is widely used in ecology, for example, to measure the variation of the diversity of a community with a fixed number of species [28]. Notice that, in the same way as species evenness is highest when all species in a community have the same abundance, the market evenness is highest when all firms have the same market share. Market evenness is the opposite of concentration, which happens for example when a few disproportionately large firms dominate the returns of value weighted stock market indices such as the S&P500. The use of the concept of evenness and other diversity measures in economics was reviewed, for example, in [29]. Additionally, a comparison of ecological and economic measures of biodiversity was reviewed in [30]. Box 1 summarizes the correspondences between financial markets and community ecology.
Box 1. Correspondences between financial markets and community ecology.
Financial market Community ecologyDenoted by
  • company
 ↔  speciesi
  • market value of a company
 ↔  species biomassvi
  • total market value
 ↔  total biomass (all species)V
  • total market return
 ↔  rate of variation of the
total biomass
R
  • market share of a company
 ↔  frequency of such speciesxi
  • evenness (inverse of concentration)
 ↔  evenness (species diversity)E
Most natural ecological communities exist in a state of nonequilibrium where competitive equilibrium is prevented by several factors such as, for example, fluctuations in the physical and biotic environment [31]. The same happens in stock markets, where stock prices often do not settle down for long time but are driven by factors affecting supply and demand such as the economic environment, economic policies, market news, etc. In nonequilibrium ecological communities, although the number of coexisting competitors remains relatively stable, the level of diversity—measured by the evenness—varies. Indeed, a long-standing debate in ecology is that of how species diversity relates to the productivity of ecosystems (see for instance [32] or [33] and references therein).
Classical community ecology, developed by Lotka [34] and Volterra [35], has been the major descriptor of species interactions in the ecological literature for almost a century. The Lotka–Volterra generalized theory (LVGT) [36,37] rests on the assumption that species interactions play a major role in structuring an ecological community. The Lotka–Volterra generalized equations can be written in finite time as [37,38]:
v i ( t + 1 ) v i ( t ) = r i v i ( t ) ( 1 + j = 1 S α i j v j ( t ) ) ,     i = 1 , 2 , , S .
where i denotes the species number; vi(t) stands for its biomass at time t and ri is the intrinsic growth rate of the species (dimension of time−1). Thus, a central ingredient of LVGT is the pairwise interaction matrix, αij. whose element ij quantifies the effect of species j on the growth of species i. The resulting variation in pairwise species interactions determines biodiversity in a community [39], and thus it is able to yield species abundance distributions and biodiversity as a function of species-specific interaction parameters. By analogy, one way to approach the relationship between productivity as a function of evenness in financial markets is through LVGT. The problem is that estimating the interaction matrix αij between companies is far from trivial. We will come back to this problem in Section 4.

3. Empirical Analysis

3.1. Dataset

The used dataset is based on the Fortune 100 list, i.e., a list of the top 100 public and privately held companies by revenues in the United States published by Fortune magazine [40]. From these 100 U.S. companies we selected those 78 public firms such that reported annual revenue and market cap from 1 January 2000 (see Table 1). Thus, the resulting dataset consists of time series for daily closing market values for each company, vi(t) (i =1, 2, …, 78), with t measured in days spanning 5536 days, from 1 January 2000 to 31 December 2021 [41]. The market value is a good firm size proxy; indeed, over the 27-year period of 1989–2015, it demonstrated providing high value relevance in predicting future returns [42].
According to the Federal Reserve [43], there were three recessions in this period:
  • From the first to the third quarter of 2001, corresponding to the dot-com crash [44];
  • From the fourth quarter of 2007 to the second quarter of 2009, associated with the “Subprime Mortgage Crisis” or the “Mortgage crisis” [45];
  • Across the first and second quarters of 2020.
Hence, this sample covers two business cycles.

3.2. Variables

In this study, as mentioned, the three main global or aggregated variables considered are:
1. The total market value, V(t), which depends on time t (measured in days), i.e.,
V ( t )   i = 1 78 v i ( t ) .
2. The total market return, R(t), given by the annual variation of V, i.e.,
R ( t ) j = 1 S ( v i ( t + 1 ) v i ( t ) ) .
In fact, I mainly consider the two abovementioned quantities adjusted by the annual consumer price index (CPI), respectively, denoted as Va(t) and Ra(t), except as otherwise stated.
3. The Shannon evenness or Shannon equitability, E(t), defined as:
E ( t ) i = 1 78 x i ( t ) ln x i ( t ) ln 78 ,
where xi(t) is the market share of company i at day t, i.e.,
x i ( t ) = v i ( t ) V ( t ) .
This index is basically a normalized Shannon entropy, independent of the sample size (N = 78 in our particular study).
In addition, using daily data raises the problem of high-frequency variation of daily prices compared to the monthly, quarterly, or annual frequency which are much more relevant for the business ecosystem picture. To avoid this problem, the high frequency daily fluctuations were smoothed out by using moving averages over 252 stock trading days per year.
It is worth mentioning that the total (unadjusted) market value V of this set of companies at the end of the period was USD 18.9 trillion [40,41], and they represented at least 60% of the total New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) market cap in the period 2000–2021 [46]. Hence, as expected, V is strongly correlated with the S&P 500 index, as shown in Figure 1. This simply confirms that V for the selected set of companies serves as an aggregate measure of production to determine the business cycle chronology (working with the entire set of 2800 NYSE listed firms would be a daunting task).
As an additional check that that E(t), given by Equation (4), correctly reflects the market evenness of the whole U.S. stock market the Shannon evenness was computed through Equation (3) but taking subsets of the whole set of 78 firms, i.e., the top 20 companies, the top 30, etc. (and replacing in Equation (3) 78 by N = 20, 30, etc.). Figure 2 shows that the corresponding succession of curves of EN (t) converges towards the evenness E(t) for the whole set; for N ≥ 50 the curves are qualitatively very similar, while the curve E70 (t) only shows small departures from E(t). This is because adding companies with very low shares does not change much E since xi ln xi → 0 when xi → 0.
It was checked that other different metrics used to quantify the evenness, like inverse Simpson and the Gini–Simpson indices, provide qualitatively identical curves to the Shannon evenness. (See Appendix A)

3.3. Productivity vs. Evenness in the U.S. Stock Market

The relationship between Ra(t), the most widely used metric to measure market productivity, and E(t) provides clear evidence of the inverse relationship between productivity vs. evenness. In Figure 3, the 21-year period is divided into three portions according to the behavior of the evenness E (full thick green curve). That is:
  • A period of soaring E(t), from January 2001 to December 2007, (almost exactly coinciding with the first business cycle);
  • A period of relatively smooth oscillations of E(t) around a high value, from January 2008 to December 2017;
  • A period in which E plunged, from January 2018 to December 2021.
Figure 3. CPI adjusted total returns, Ra, and Shannon evenness, E, along the period 2001–2022 [41]. Right axis: Shannon evenness E (full tick green curve). Left axis: Ra plotted for three different periods depending on the behavior of E: 2001–2007 (dashed blue), characterized by soaring E and negative average Ra; 2008–2017 (dotted gray), of roughly constant E and low average Ra; January 2018 to December 2021, in which E plunged and the average Ra was high. The horizontal segments correspond to the mean of Ra along the respective period.
Figure 3. CPI adjusted total returns, Ra, and Shannon evenness, E, along the period 2001–2022 [41]. Right axis: Shannon evenness E (full tick green curve). Left axis: Ra plotted for three different periods depending on the behavior of E: 2001–2007 (dashed blue), characterized by soaring E and negative average Ra; 2008–2017 (dotted gray), of roughly constant E and low average Ra; January 2018 to December 2021, in which E plunged and the average Ra was high. The horizontal segments correspond to the mean of Ra along the respective period.
Entropy 25 01029 g003
Notice that the Ra averaged over these periods, indicated in Figure 3 by horizontal segments, was slightly negative (blue), slightly positive (gray), and high (red), respectively. In other words, during periods in which E(t) sharply decreased productivity was high, while in the other periods of soaring or high evenness, productivity was low.
The behavior of the absolute productivity metric, Va, is also enlightening. Figure 4 shows the trajectory of Va as a function of E from 2001 to 2021 together with some key financial events that occurred in this period. The three recessions divide the period in two business cycles, both characterized by E and Va moving in opposite directions:
  • From the beginning of 2001 until the end of 2007 (portion of the trajectory in blue in Figure 4), in which E steadily increased, while Va ended in a slightly lower value.
  • The 2009–2020 expansion (portion of the trajectory in red in Figure 4), which was the longest on record at 128 months—from July 2009 to February 2020—according to the Congressional Research Service (NBER 2022). This was a period in which, after some initial erratic movements, Va grew strongly and E considerable declined.
Figure 4. The trajectory of CPI adjusted total market value, Va, as a function of E from 2001 to 2021 [41]. The portion in blue corresponds to the period between the dot-com crash and the Mortgage crisis (2001–2008). The red portion corresponds to the 2009–2020 expansion. Full lines correspond to entire periods in which Va and E moved in opposite directions (see text). Dashed lines correspond to periods in which Va and E moved in the same direction. The dotted section corresponds to the erratic period whose start coincided with the Mortgage crisis. The dot-dashed section in the upper left corresponds to the last three quarters of 2021 in which the market entered in a phase of almost vertical growth of Va.
Figure 4. The trajectory of CPI adjusted total market value, Va, as a function of E from 2001 to 2021 [41]. The portion in blue corresponds to the period between the dot-com crash and the Mortgage crisis (2001–2008). The red portion corresponds to the 2009–2020 expansion. Full lines correspond to entire periods in which Va and E moved in opposite directions (see text). Dashed lines correspond to periods in which Va and E moved in the same direction. The dotted section corresponds to the erratic period whose start coincided with the Mortgage crisis. The dot-dashed section in the upper left corresponds to the last three quarters of 2021 in which the market entered in a phase of almost vertical growth of Va.
Entropy 25 01029 g004
It is possible to identify some landmark events. For instance, the dot-com crash in 2001 seems to have triggered a process until 2003 in which Va steadily decreased and E increased quickly. Conversely, from 2017 to 2021 Va increased and E decreased fast and steadily. The start of this second period coincided with the advent of “Trumponomics”. The term refers to the economic policies of U.S. President Donald Trump, who won the 8 November 2016 presidential election on the back of bold economic promises to cut personal and corporate taxes, restructure trade deals and introduce large fiscal stimulus measures [47]. The period 2008–2015 (dotted curve), whose start coincided with the “Subprime Mortgage Crisis” or the “Mortgage crisis”, was quite erratic from the point of view of Va vs. E.
In summary, after 21 years, the market evenness roughly returned to the value it had in 2001, but the total market value doubled in CPI-adjusted dollars. This growth occurred entirely in the second half of the period, characterized by a process of concentration in which the evenness lost everything it had gained in the first half.
The negative relationship between the two productivity metrics with the market evenness agrees to what is often observed in ecological communities across different taxa. For example, the analysis of data from a large multi-site grassland experiment revealed that for plots which started with the same and even species composition, but which diverged in evenness over time, those with lower evenness attained a significantly greater biomass [48]. Moreover, the relationship between evenness and biomass across all plots in these experiments was also negative. The same was observed in other grassland experiments involving many plots of perennial grass species [49]. There are also examples of mixtures of species that converge with time towards a state of higher biomass and lower evenness for protozoa [50] and algae [51].

4. Explaining the Relationship between Productivity and Evenness in Stock Markets from a Community Ecology Perspective

Species interactions involve a complex balance of competition and facilitation in which indirect interactions occur if a third species (or more species) modifies the interaction between two other species [52]. It was argued that the success of species in a community is affected not only by direct interactions between species, but also by indirect interactions among groups of species [53,54]. The Lotka–Volterra generalized equations can naturally implement these indirect interactions through combinations of several pairwise interaction coefficients. That is, species i affects directly species k through the coefficient αki, but also indirectly through the combination of αji and αkj (i.e., species i affects directly species j, which in turn affects directly species k).
Regarding markets as ecological communities enables us to use the general machinery of the theory of community ecology [9] to understand the observed negative relationship between productivity, measured by Va and Ra, and evenness, E. We will focus in particular to the Lotka–Volterra generalized equations and the interaction matrix, αij, quantifying the strength of the effects between pairs of species.
To estimate the interaction matrix αij of an ecological community a far from trivial task. A straightforward procedure is through pairwise competition trials by comparing the species yields in biculture relative to monoculture [50,55]. However, these experiments, which are common in community ecology and agricultural science are feasible for a small number of coexisting species S [17,37,49,50]. This is because the number of required experiments grows as S2. Furthermore, such experiments are not feasible in markets since one cannot isolate companies from the rest of the market to study their evolution under controlled conditions. Hence, we have to make use of theoretical analysis in terms of in silico synthetic communities.

4.1. Ensemble of Synthetic Communities

Therefore, let us use an approach based on Robert May’s theoretical work in community ecology in terms of randomly assembled communities [38]. The idea is to consider an ensemble of pairwise interaction matrices whose diagonal elements, corresponding to intraspecific interactions of each species i, are set to −1, as it is customarily performed in community ecology [38]. The off-diagonal matrix elements, corresponding to interspecific interactions between different species i and j, are drawn from a uniform random distribution centered around 0 and with radius δ, which can thus be interpreted as the intensity of interspecific interactions. That, is:
α i j = { 1 if   i = j random   in   [ δ , + δ ] if   i j
Notice that the mean of the interspecific interaction coefficients is μ = 0, i.e., negative and positive interaction coefficients are equally likely. In fact, complex combinations of negative and positive interactions have been identified in a number of different ecological communities, like plant communities [49,56], freshwater communities [57], etc. The heterogeneity of interspecific interactions is controlled by δ since the variance of the interspecific interaction coefficients is given by δ2 = δ2/3, i.e., the greater δ, the greater the variance of interspecific interactions. To analyze the effect of varying the heterogeneity of interspecific interactions, we took into account that systems in which interspecific interactions are stronger than intraspecific interactions are likely to be unstable [58], thus we kept δ < 1. Thus, the parameter δ was varied from 0 to 0.9 in steps of 0.1.
To set the intrinsic growth rates, ri, it was used that, by Equation (1), on average ri is equal to the mean relative returns (vi(t + 1) − vi(t))/vi(t). Therefore, let us take ri = 0.014 for all i which is the mean of the empirically observed relative returns (This mean implies a double average, over companies and over time.). Next, to solve the Lotka–Volterra Equation (1) for each value of δ, 1000 simulations were run, each one starting from a random initial condition:
v i ( 1 ) = random   in   [ 0 , 1 ] , i = 1 , 2 , , 78 .
The initial total market value, and the evenness are thus given, respectively, by: V(1) ≈ 78 × 0.5 = 39 (in arbitrary units) and E(1) ≈ 0.957 (see Appendix B). Notice that these initial values are close to the equilibrium values for δ = 0, V0* = 39 and E0* = 1(see Appendix C). From this initial arbitrary state, the transient dynamics towards equilibrium was studied. It is important to note that randomness only enters in the initial choice of the interspecific coefficients αij, which then define a particular community by Equation (6), and in the initial configuration (i.e., Equation (7)). For each simulation the subsequent dynamics is strictly deterministic, and the community specified by a random interaction matrix given by Equation (6), in general does not allow for the coexistence of all the 78 species. Instead, some species extinguish with time; the coexistence of the 78 species is in general unfeasible for random matrices [37]. Therefore, simulations were stopped for a time, T, for which the first species extinguished (A species is considered extinguished when its biomass drops below a cutoff vmin << 1 (here I use vmin =10−5)). For small values of δ, T can be quite large (thousands of time steps). However, as δ increases, T decreases, until T~30 for δ = 0.9. Hence, to use the same simulation cutoff time for all values of δ, T = 30 was fixed (qualitatively similar results were obtained for smaller values of T, as shown in Appendix C).
The results of simulations are shown in Figure 5. For δ = 0.1, only slight deviations in V and E from their initial values, V(1) = 39 and E(1) = 0.957, occur (Figure 5a). As δ increases, the community moves towards higher values of V and lower values of E. Indeed, the curves E ¯ ( δ )   and   V ¯ [ δ ] (the bars denote average over simulations) appear to be mirror images of each other.
These opposite trends for E ¯ ( δ )   and   V ¯ [ δ ] can be understood as follows. It is immediate that the evenness will decline when δ is increased. This is because for δ = 0 the interaction matrix αij, given by Equation (6), reduces to the identity matrix, and then all distinction among the companies disappears, Therefore, the evenness tends to its maximum possible value of E0* = 1 (see Appendix C). As the interactions between companies are “turned on” (δ > 0), the equivalence between companies breaks down and the system departs from this state of maximum evenness. The larger the heterogeneity (variance) of these interactions the larger this departure. A derivation that V ¯ [δ] is a monotonic increasing function of δ requires a little bit more of algebra. In a nutshell the idea is that, even though by Equation (6) positive and negative interspecific interactions are equally likely, the effect of positive interactions outweighs the effect of negative interactions, as it is shown in Appendix C. Moreover, it can also be derived that the time derivative of V ¯ [δ], i.e., R ¯ [δ], is a monotonic increasing function of δ.
Therefore, a way to generate the observed inverse relationship between productivity metrics and E, is by changing the interaction strength between companies: if δ increases (decreases) R and V tend to increase (decrease) and simultaneously E tends to do the opposite, i.e., to decline (rise).
Regarding the mechanism promoting the growth of δ, and ultimately behind the negative relationship between productivity and evenness, monetary policy is a natural candidate. That is, when the monetary policy is loose and interest rates are low, capital flows to firms. This injection of money promotes the idea that firms address new business opportunities which multiply the interactions between them, either in the form of cooperation through new contracts, joint ventures, etc. or competition in new segments. Such an increase in the heterogeneity of interactions among companies is equivalent in our model to increase δ. Indeed, high productivity coincided with an expansion in money supply, M1 [59], and mainly with low effective interest rates (see Appendix D). The relationship between interest rates and evenness, or between money supply and evenness is less clear. Although at the beginning of the period the evenness soared with high interest rates, it persisted high during 2009–2015 when, in order to combat the Great Recession, the U.S. Federal Reserve ran a quantitative easing program and kept the effective interest rate at virtually zero [59] (see Appendix D). In a similar vein, it was observed that algal biovolume, a surrogate for biomass, increased, whereas evenness decreased with increasing total supply of resources in algal communities [60].
Two remarks are in order. Firstly, the monotonic curves E ¯ ( δ ) , R ¯ [ δ ]   and   V ¯ [ δ ] of Figure 5 were obtained as averages over 1000 simulations. Nevertheless, this does not imply that if δ1 < δ2 all simulations performed with δ1 will produce a V smaller than the one produced by all simulation with δ2 or an E larger than the one produced by all simulation with δ2. Hence, this approach is also able to yield periods in which R and/or V move in the same direction as E (either both upward or downward), but they will be less likely than periods in which productivity metrics and E move in opposite directions. This is in agreement with what is shown in Figure 4 for the empirical trajectory of V vs. E: those sections in which both variables move in the same direction are rarer and shorter (e.g., during 2004).
Secondly, this approach, in terms of random matrices, produces only qualitative evidence for the observed V vs. E trend in the U.S. stock market. To obtain a better quantitative description, one has to consider more complicated structured interaction matrices. This issue is beyond the scope of this study, but some recent advances are briefly reviewed in the next subsection. Indeed, the random matrices approach, which is commonly used in various fields such as physics, mathematics, and finance, has certain limitations and restrictions. A main restriction is its assumptions of randomness. The random matrices approach relies on the assumption that the matrix elements are independent and identically distributed random variables. However, in some real-world scenarios, this assumption may not hold true. Real-world data often exhibit correlations, dependencies, or non-random patterns that may not be accurately captured by random matrices.

4.2. Other Ecologically Based Approaches Supporting the Negative Relationship between Productivity and Evenness

The classical Ecological Niche Theory (ENT) states that an ecological community is made up of a limited number of niches, each occupied by a single species and that differences among species in their niches are important in determining the outcome of species interactions as might be revealed in their distributions and/or abundances in ecosystems [61]. Using ENT, the pattern of increasing biomass accompanied by decreasing evenness was firstly mathematically derived for the case of pure competition [62], which implies a restriction of the general interactions of LVGT only to mutually competitive interactions for resources. More recently, this result was extended to the more realistic case of generalized interactions. This was performed through the so-called Lotka–Volterra Niche Game Model (LVNGM) [63], resulting from the combination of ENT and Game Theory. Other recent works approaching financial markets as ecosystems have contributed to support the generality of the inverse relationship between productivity and evenness. Indeed, population dynamic models can be used in conjunction with time series of species abundances to infer the interaction coefficients between companies through indirect methods. One of such indirect methods is the so-called Pairwise Maximum-Entropy (PME) modeling [64]. PME modeling is a particular implementation of the of Maximum Entropy general approach proposed by Jaynes [65,66] which has been used in finance for different purposes, like ranking the performance of mutual funds [67], retrieving the risk neutral density of asset returns [68], investigating the effect of size differences on cost efficiency heterogeneity in U.S. commercial banks [69], etc. In the last two decades, PME models have been used to analyze ecological data associated with diverse problems, such as animal flocks [70], and community ecology [37,71,72,73]. In fact, PME modeling has been applied for a subset of the US companies I consider here in two recent studies, each one focused on a different subject, across different time lengths or training periods Ttr. The first one addressed the issue of inferring adjacency matrices defining the network that describe the interactions between firms in a fashion similar to how theoretical ecology pictures the interaction of species in an ecosystem [74]. A main finding of a community analysis on the resultant networks was that the network modules derived from a PME matrix, Mij, coincide almost exactly with the industry groupings of the firms defined by the Global Industry Classification Standard (GICS) [75]. The second study tested the combination of this PME approach with evolutionary game theory for quantitative market forecasting by taking αij = Mij [7]. It turns out that the resulting forecasting method does a decent job of predicting empirical shares of the companies along several choices of validation periods. Interestingly, these interaction matrices αij obtained by the PME method in [7,74] exhibit properties which are similar to the ones of the synthetic communities defined by Equation (6), namely that (a) most of its off-diagonal element are in the interval (−1, +1) and (b) with a mean close to 0.

5. Conclusions

As we have seen, regarding markets as ecosystems can be traced back to the late 1950s [3]. Since then, different authors have contributed to building this analogy and used it to gain insight into market forces. However, there has been a lack of quantitative tools so far useful to the practitioners [76]. Indeed, the main novelties of this study are as follows:
Firstly, it raises the productivity vs. diversity issue, a fundamental question of community ecology, in the context of financial markets modeling. It is worth mentioning that a similar conclusion was drawn using a different diversity measure provided by the largest eigenvalue of the correlation matrix among stocks [77]. The productivity–diversity tradeoff is important because, as it happens in ecology, in economics, decision makers need to strike a balance in resource allocation by considering both productivity-enhancing investments and maintaining a diverse to mitigate risks and promote long-term sustainability and resilience.
Secondly, it uses the Shannon evenness of market values to quantify the market diversity as opposed to market concentration. Being a normalized metric, the Shannon evenness is particularly useful when working with samples of companies of large markets such as NYSE. Additionally, it allows a quantitative comparison of the evenness among different markets or among different industrial sectors of the same market. The use of the Shannon evenness was instrumental to detect an important pattern of NYSE market dynamics between 2001 and 2021, namely the fact that high productivity was achieved when the evenness dropped; conversely when the evenness soared (during the business cycle 2001–2008) productivity plunged. Interestingly, such negatively correlated regime parallels the relationship between total biomass and species evenness observed in several ecosystems across distinct taxa (plants, algae, protozoa, etc.). In the case of economics and finance, balancing productivity and diversity is crucial for sustainable economic growth. High productivity can boost overall output and efficiency, leading to economic expansion. Diversity, on the other hand, can contribute to resilience and adaptability, allowing economies to better withstand disruptions. Diversity also plays a vital role in fostering innovation and creativity. When a system encompasses diverse perspectives, knowledge, and skill sets, it is more likely that it promotes the generation of new ideas and approaches. Recognizing the potential adverse effects of losing diversity, decision makers can implement policies that promote a more diverse economic landscape. This can involve supporting industries with growth potential, fostering entrepreneurship, encouraging small and medium-sized enterprises, and providing incentives for diverse business models and market entrants. Such policies can help maintain a resilient economy, reduce concentration risks, and encourage innovation and competition.
Thirdly, as far as the author knows, May’s model [38] has not been previously used to analyze the relationship between evenness and productivity, neither in ecology nor in economics. Specifically, the model allows to explain how an inverse relationship between productivity and diversity can emerge when loosening or tightening the monetary policy. This has profound implications for decision makers, who need to carefully balance the short-term benefits of loosening monetary policy, such as increased liquidity and economic stimulus, with the potential long-term undesired effects on the economy. While monetary easing may provide immediate economic boosts, it can also discourage productivity improvements and hinder the development of a diverse and resilient economy. In that sense, the above finding serves to assess the trade-offs and evaluate the long-term consequences of monetary policy decisions.
Let us conclude with some research directions that seem worth investigating in future works. One important issue is the generality of negative correlation between market productivity and market evenness. For example, one may wonder whether this pattern is a particularity of the US stock market or if it is shared by other stock markets in different countries? Thus, analyzing financial markets from other countries is a natural next step. Another question is how the detected pattern is connected to long-term trends in demographics and the inter-industry reconfiguration of firms away from traditional manufacturing [78]. The business ecosystem perspective is also useful to develop quantitative methods to forecast future market values of firms [79], or to define fitnesses for firms and disentangle the effects of selection and the environment in the evolutionary dynamics of financial markets [80].

Funding

Partial financial support was received from PEDECIBA-Uruguay and SNI-ANII-Uruguay.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data that support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Acknowledgments

I thank R. Donangelo, E. Mordecki and A. Segura for useful discussions. Work supported in part by PEDECIBA & ANII-Uruguay for SNI support.

Conflicts of Interest

The author has no competing interest to declare that are relevant to the content of this article.

Abbreviations

EEEcological Economics
ENTEcological Niche Theory
GICSGlobal Industry Classification Standard
LVGTLotka–Volterra generalized theory
NYSENew York Stock Exchange
PMEPairwise Maximum-Entropy

Appendix A. Other Metrics of Evenness

In addition to Shannon evenness there are other metrics to assess the equitability or evenness in a community. A couple of popular metrics are based on the Simpson index, which is given by:
λ i = 1 N x i 2 ,
where N is the number of companies and xi is the market share of company i, i.e.,
x i = v i V .
The first one is the inverse Simpson index, given by:
I S 1 / λ .
The second one is the Gini–Simpson index, given by:
G S 1 λ .
It turns out that both the above indices provide qualitatively identical curves to the Shannon evenness, as it can be seen in Figure A1 which shows the curves of E(t) and GS(t).
Figure A1. E(t) (green, left axis) and GS(t) (orange, right axis) for the set of the largest 78 companies. The curves were obtained by taking 252 days (i.e., 1 year) moving averages.
Figure A1. E(t) (green, left axis) and GS(t) (orange, right axis) for the set of the largest 78 companies. The curves were obtained by taking 252 days (i.e., 1 year) moving averages.
Entropy 25 01029 g0a1

Appendix B. The Evenness of a Randomly Distributed Shares

Suppose that using a uniform distribution in the [0, 1] interval, we draw a set of S fractions yi, which we assume that are proportional to the market values, vi, of S firms. Therefore, the mean values y ¯ i will be uniformly distributed in the [0, 1] interval:
Entropy 25 01029 i001
i.e.,
y i = i S + 1 , with   i = 1 , 2 , , S .  
To transform the fractions yi into shares xi we have to normalize them, i.e.,
x i = y ¯ i j = 1 S y ¯ j = y ¯ i S 2 ( S + 1 ) 1 S + 1 = 2 S y ¯ i .  
Using Equation (4) we can write the evenness in terms of the fractions yi as:
E = i = 1 S x i ln ( 2 S y i ) ln S = 2 S i = 1 S y i ln y i + ln ( 2 S ) ln S .
Substituting Equation (A5) into (A7) we obtain:
E = 2 S ( S + 1 ) ln S i = 1 S [ i ln S + 1 i ] + ln S 2 ln S .
For example, Equation (A8) produces for S = 2 species, E = 0.9813, whereas for S = 78 companies, by performing the sum from 1 to 78, we obtain 0.11619 and then adding up ln19/ln38 (=0.84090), we finally obtain E = 0.95709.
The sum in the expression (A8) can be approximated as the integral (the larger S the larger the accuracy of this approximation):
i = 1 S [ i ln S + 1 i ] ( S + 1 ) 2 0 1 y ln y d y = ( S + 1 ) 2 4 .
Hence, substituting Equation (A9) into (A8), we obtain the following approximate expression of the evenness as a function of S:
E S + 1 2 S ln S + ln S 2 ln S .
For S = 78, the evenness thus becomes E 0.11623 + 0.84090 = 0.95713 , which differs in 0.004% of the value we obtained performing the sum.

Appendix C. The Total Market Value as a Function of δ

The system of Equation (1) with an interaction matrix given by Equation (6) will converge towards an equilibrium total market value, V*(δ). It is helpful to consider for a moment the effect of “switching off” the interspecific interactions, which corresponds to the trivial community of non-interacting species, so that as δ = 0, the interaction matrix αij given by Equation (6) reduces to the identity matrix. In this case, the Lotka–Volterra equations reduce to a set of uncoupled logistic equations:
v i ( t + 1 ) v i ( t ) = r i v i ( t ) ( 1 v i ( t ) ) , i = 1 , 2 , , S .
The solution of Equation (A11) converges for asymptotically large times towards the equilibrium vi* = 1 for all species i. Then, by Equations (A11), (2) and (4), the corresponding total market value and evenness become V0* = j = 1 78 v 0 j * = 78 and E0* = 1 (the sub index 0 are used to emphasize that these results hold for the trivial case δ = 0).
If we now “switch on” the interspecific interactions, i.e., δ > 0, from Equation (1), we have for the equilibrium in which the S companies coexist:
j = 1 S α i j v j * = 1 , i = 1 , 2 , , S ,
Inverting Equation (A12), we can write the equilibrium total market value, to which the system eventually converges in terms of the inverse of the interaction matrix, α 1 i j , as:
V * = i = 1 S v i * = i S j S α 1 i j , i , j = 1 , 2 , , S .
A general analytical expression of V* in terms of the coefficients αI ij is very cumbersome and thus not very useful. In addition, we still have to perform the integrations in those αi ij between −δ and δ to obtain the expected total market value at equilibrium for a given δ, V*(δ). However, for a given value of δ, such multiple integral of Equation (A13) can be computed numerically. To illustrate this calculation, let us consider the case of an ensemble for a community of just two companies. Hence, v1* and v2* can be written as [37]:
v 1 *   = 1 + α 12   1 α 12 . α 21   ,   v 2 *   = 1 + α 21   1 α 12 . α 21  
Therefore, Equation (A13) reduces to:
V * ( δ ) = δ + δ δ + δ d α 12 d α 21 ( v 1 * + v 2 * ) = δ + δ δ + δ d α 12 d α 21 2 + α 12 + α 21   1 α 12 . α 21   .
Performing the above double integral numerically, we obtain the total market value curve, V*(δ), at equilibrium towards this system, which is depicted in Figure A2. Notice that it is a monotonic function of δ. This implies that, even though positive and negative interactions are equally likely, the effect of positive interactions is not entirely erased by negative interactions.
Figure A2. Total expected market value V* towards a community of two species or a market of two companies converges at equilibrium as a function of the intensity of interspecific interactions, δ.
Figure A2. Total expected market value V* towards a community of two species or a market of two companies converges at equilibrium as a function of the intensity of interspecific interactions, δ.
Entropy 25 01029 g0a2
The calculation shown above for two species can be generalized to any arbitrary S > 2 number of interacting companies.
The results of simulations of 78 species/companies governed by Equation (1), with random interaction matrices, given by Equation (6), and starting from the initial conditions given by Equation (7), are shown in Figure A3 for different values of δ, varying the simulation time cutoff, T, from 2 to 20. In panel (A), one can see that for δ = 0.1, independently of the cutoff time T, only slight deviations in V and E from their initial values, V(1) = 39 and E(1) = 0.957, occur. As δ increases, the initial configuration moves further away from the equilibrium state. The community then moves towards higher values of V and lower values of E when increasing T, as shown in panel (A) for δ = 0.3 and 0.5. Above δ = 0.5, the tendency towards the upper left corner in the plane E-V becomes monotonic, as shown in panel (B) of Figure A3.
Figure A3. Curves of V(T) vs. E(T) for synthetic communities with different values of δ (see text). The simulation time runs upward as indicated by the black arrow; each symbol corresponds to a point V(T), E(T) with a cutoff simulation time T = 2, 3,…, 20; the higher the symbol, the larger the simulation cutoff time T. (A): δ = 0.1, 0.3 and 0.5. (B): δ = 0.6, 0.7 and 0.8.
Figure A3. Curves of V(T) vs. E(T) for synthetic communities with different values of δ (see text). The simulation time runs upward as indicated by the black arrow; each symbol corresponds to a point V(T), E(T) with a cutoff simulation time T = 2, 3,…, 20; the higher the symbol, the larger the simulation cutoff time T. (A): δ = 0.1, 0.3 and 0.5. (B): δ = 0.6, 0.7 and 0.8.
Entropy 25 01029 g0a3

Appendix D. Effective U.S. FED Rates Compared with the Total Market Value and Evenness

In Figure A4, the curve of the U.S. Federal Reserve effective interest rate along 2000–2021 [59] is compared with E and V (in trillion USD) in panels (A) and (B), respectively.
Figure A4. (A): Variation in the effective interest rate [59] and the total market value V. (B): Variation in the effective interest rate [59] and E.
Figure A4. (A): Variation in the effective interest rate [59] and the total market value V. (B): Variation in the effective interest rate [59] and E.
Entropy 25 01029 g0a4
For the evenness, no clear pattern emerges. As shown in panel (A), at the beginning of the period, E soared with high interest rates, but from 2009 to 2015, the effective interest remained virtually zero [59] and E remained high. On the other hand, high productivity occurred entirely during the period of very low to moderate interest rates. Conversely, the first business cycle 2001–2008 was characterized in general by high interest rates and low productivity (panel (B)).

References

  1. Simon, H.A. A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice. Q. J. Econ. 1955, 69, 99–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Shiller, R.J. Market Volatility; MIT Press: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
  3. Alderson, W. Marketing Behavior and Executive Action: A Functionalist Approach to Marketing Theory; Homewood: Irwin, IL, USA, 1957. [Google Scholar]
  4. Alderson, W. Dynamic Marketing Behavior: A Functionalist Theory of Marketing; Homewood: Irwin, IL, USA, 1965. [Google Scholar]
  5. Potters, M.; Cont, R.; Bouchaud, J.P. Financial Markets as Adaptive Ecosystems. Europhys. Lett. 2004, 41, 239. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Manahov, V.; Hudson, R. A note on the relationship between market efficiency and adaptability. New evidence from artificial stock markets. Expert Syst. Appl. Int. J. 2014, 41, 7436–7454. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Fort, H. Forecasting with Maximum Entropy: The Interface between Physics, Biology, Economics and Information Theory; Institute of Physics Publishing: Bristol, UK, 2022. [Google Scholar]
  8. Moore, J.F. Predators and Prey: A new ecology of competition. Harv. Bus. Rev. 1993, 71, 75–86. [Google Scholar]
  9. Morin, P. Community Ecology; Wiley-Blackwell: Chichester, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  10. Moore, J.F. The Death of Competition: Leadership and Strategy in the Age of Business Ecosystems; Harper Paperbacks: New York, NY, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  11. Farmer, D.J.; Lo, A.W. Frontiers of finance: Evolution and efficient markets. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 1999, 96, 9991–9992. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Krebs, C.J. Ecology: The Experimental Analysis of Distribution and Abundance, 2nd ed.; Harper & Row: New York, NY, USA, 1978. [Google Scholar]
  13. Grime, J.P.; Pierce, S. The Evolutionary Strategies That Shape Ecosystems; Wiley: Chichester, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  14. Mittelbach, G.G.; Steiner, C.F.; Scheiner, S.M.; Gross, K.L.; Reynolds, H.L.; Waide, R.B.; Willig, M.R.; Dodson, S.I.; Gough, L. What is the observed relationship between species richness and productivity? Ecology 2001, 82, 2381–2396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Cardinale, B.J.; Hillebrand, H.; Harpole, W.S.; Gross, K.L.; Ptacnick, R. Separating the influence of resource ‘availability’ from resource ‘imbalance’ on productivity–diversity relationships. Ecol. Lett. 2009, 12, 475–487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Allaby, M. (Ed.) A Dictionary of Ecology, 3rd ed.; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  17. Vandermeer, J.H. The Ecology of Intercropping; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1989. [Google Scholar]
  18. Hayes, A. What Is Crop Yield? Investopedia. Available online: https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/crop-yield.asp (accessed on 14 November 2022).
  19. Magurran, A.E. Measuring Biological Diversity; Blackwell Science: Malden, MA, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  20. Chiarucci, A.; Bacaro, G.; Scheiner, S.M. Old and new challenges in using species diversity for assessing biodiversity. Philos. Trans. R. Soc. B Biol. Sci. 2011, 366, 2426–2437. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  21. Costanza, R. What is ecological economics? Ecol. Econ. 1989, 1, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Potts, J.; Foster, J.; Straton, A. An entrepreneurial model of economic and environmental co-evolution. Ecol. Econ. 2010, 70, 375–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Farmer, D.J. Market Force, Ecology and Evolution. Ind. Corp. Chang. 2002, 11, 895–953. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Moore, J.F. Business Ecosystems and the View from the Firm. Antitrust Bull. 2006, 51, 31–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  25. Hileman, J.; Kallstenius, I.; Häyhä, T.; Palm, C.; Cornell, S. Keystone actors do not act alone: A business ecosystem perspective on sustainability in the global clothing industry. PLoS ONE 2020, 15, e0241453. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Pielou, E. An Introduction to Mathematical Ecology; Wiley: New York, NY, USA, 1969. [Google Scholar]
  27. Van Dyke, F. Conservation Biology: Foundations, Concepts, Applications, 2nd ed.; Springer: New York, NY, USA, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  28. Maignan, C.; Ottaviano, G.; Pinelli, D.; Rullani, F. Bio-Ecological Diversity vs. Socio-Economic Diversity: A Comparison of Existing Measures Nota di Lavoro. 2003. Available online: http://www.feem.it/web/activ/_wp.html (accessed on 15 March 2023).
  29. Baumgärtner, S. Measuring the Diversity of What? And for What Purpose? A Conceptual Comparison of Ecological and Economic Biodiversity Indices. 2006. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=894782 (accessed on 15 March 2023).
  30. Boyte-White, C. Market Capitalization Versus Market Value: What’s the Difference? Investopedia. Available online: https://www.investopedia.com/ask/answers/122314/what-difference-between-market-capitalization-and-market-value.asp (accessed on 9 November 2022).
  31. Huston, M. A general hypothesis of species diversity. Am. Nat. 1979, 113, 81–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Huston, M.A.; Aarssen, L.W.; Austin, M.P.; Cade, B.S.; Fridley, J.D.; Garnier, E.; Grime, J.P.; Hodgson, J.; Lauenroth, W.K.; Wardle, D.A. No consistent effect of plant diversity on productivity. Science 2000, 289, 1255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Schmid, B. The species richness-productivity controversy. Trends Ecol. Evol. 2002, 17, 113–114. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Lotka, A.J. Elements of Physical Biology; Williams & Wilkins: New York, NY, USA, 1925. [Google Scholar]
  35. Volterra, V. Fluctuations in the abundance of a species considered mathematically. Nature 1926, 118, 558–560. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  36. Hofbauer, M.; Sigmund, K. Evolutionary Games and Population Dynamics; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1998. [Google Scholar]
  37. Fort, H. Ecological Modelling and Ecophysics: Agricultural and Environmental Applications; Institute of Physics Publishing: Bristol, UK, 2020. [Google Scholar]
  38. May, R.M. Will a large complex system be stable? Nature 1972, 238, 413–414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Chesson, P. Mechanisms of maintenance of species diversity. Ann. Rev. Ecol. Evol. Syst. 2000, 31, 343–366. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Fortune Magazine. Available online: https://fortune.com/rankings/ (accessed on 9 November 2022).
  41. Core US Fundamentals Dataset. Available online: http://www.quandl.com/databases/SF1 (accessed on 15 March 2023).
  42. Wakil, G. Firm size proxies and the value relevance of predictive stock return models. J. Econ. Financ. 2020, 44, 434–457. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Hamilton, J. Dates of U.S. Recessions as Inferred by GDP-Based Recession Indicator JHDUSRGDPBR, Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Available online: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/JHDUSRGDPBR (accessed on 12 October 2022).
  44. Money Morning. The Dot-Com Crash of 2000–2002. Available online: https://moneymorning.com/2015/06/12/the-dot-com-crash-of-2000-2002/ (accessed on 23 November 2022).
  45. NYT 2007. Bear Stearns Reports First Ever Quarterly Loss. Available online: https://archive.nytimes.com/dealbook.nytimes.com/2007/12/20/bear-reports-steep-but-expected-4th-quarter-loss/?_r=0 (accessed on 10 February 2023).
  46. NYSE 2022. Available online: https://www.nyse.com/market-cap (accessed on 10 July 2022).
  47. Kenton, W. What Is Trumponomics. Investopedia. Available online: https://www.investopedia.com.cach3.com/terms/t/trumponomics.asp.html (accessed on 14 November 2022).
  48. Mulder, C.P.; Bazeley-White, E.; Dimitrakopoulos, P.G.; Hector, A.; Scherer-Lorenzen, M.; Schmid, B. Species Evenness and Productivity in Experimental Plant Communities. Oikos 2004, 107, 50–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Halty, V.; Valdés, M.; Tejera, M.; Picasso, V.; Fort, H. Modelling plant interspecific interactions from experiments of perennial crop mixtures to predict optimal combinations. Ecol. Appl. 2017, 27, 2277–2289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Vandermeer, J.H. The competitive structure of communities: An experimental approach with protozoa. Ecology 1969, 50, 362–371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  51. Huisman, J.; Jonker, R.R.; Zonneveld, C.; Weissing, F.J. Competition for light between phytoplankton species: Experimental tests of mechanistic theory. Ecology 1999, 80, 211–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Connel, J.H. Apparent vs. “rea” competition in plants. In Perspectives on Plant Competition; Grace, J.B., Tilman, D., Eds.; Academic Press: New York, NY, USA, 1990; pp. 9–26. [Google Scholar]
  53. Miller, T.E. Direct and indirect species interactions in an early old-field plant community. Am. Nat. 1994, 143, 1007–1025. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Adler, F.R.; Morris, W.F. A general test for interaction modification. Ecology 1994, 75, 1552–1559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Fort, H. On predicting species yields in multispecies communities: Quantifying the accuracy of the linear Lotka-Volterra generalized model. Ecol. Model. 2018, 387, 154–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Callaway, R.M.; Walker, L.R. Competition and facilitation: A synthetic approach to interactions in plant communities. Ecology 1997, 78, 1958–1965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Silknetter, S.; Creed, R.P.; Brown, B.L.; Frimpong, E.A.; Skelton, J.; Peoples, B.K. Positive biotic interactions in freshwaters: A review and research directive. Freshw. Biol. 2020, 65, 811–832. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  58. Yodzis, P. The stability of real ecosystems. Nature 1981, 289, 674–676. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Federal Funds Effective Rate. Retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Available online: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/ (accessed on 2 December 2022).
  60. Gamfeldt, L.; Hillebrand, H. Effects of Total Resources, Resource Ratios, and Species Richness on Algal Productivity and Evenness at Both Metacommunity and Local Scales. PLoS ONE 2011, 6, e21972. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  61. Chase, J.M.; Leibold, M.A. Ecological Niches; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  62. Fort, H. Community diversity and total abundance: Quantitative predictions from competition niche theory. Ecol. Complex. 2015, 21, 120–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Fort, H. Combining niche and game theories to address interspecific cooperation in ecological communities. Community Ecol. 2020, 21, 13–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Roudi, Y.; Nirenberg, S.; Latham, P.E. Pairwise Maximum Entropy Models for Studying Large Biological Systems: When They Can Work and When They Can’t. PLoS Comput. Biol. 2009, 5, e1000380. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  65. Jaynes, E.T. Information theory and statistical mechanics I. Phys. Rev. 1957, 106, 620–630. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Jaynes, E.T. Information theory and statistical mechanics II. Phys. Rev. 1957, 108, 171–190. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Vinod, H.D. Ranking mutual funds using unconventional utility theory and stochastic dominance. J. Empir. Financ. 2004, 11, 353–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Rompolis, L. Retrieving risk neutral densities from European option prices based on the principle of maximum entropy. J. Empir. Financ. 2010, 17, 918–937. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Balasubramanyan, L.; Stefanou, S.E.; Stokes, J.R. An entropy approach to size and variance heterogeneity in U.S. commercial banks. J. Econ. Financ. 2012, 36, 728–749. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  70. Bialek, W.; Cavagna, A.; Giardina, I.; Mora, T.; Silvestri, E.; Viale, M.; Walczak, A.M. Statistical mechanics for natural flocks of birds. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2012, 109, 4786–4791. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Volkov, I.; Banavar, J.R.; Hubbell, S.P.; Maritan, A. Inferring species interactions in tropical forests. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2009, 106, 13854–13859. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Fort, H.; Grigera, T. A method for predicting species trajectories tested with trees in Barro Colorado tropical forest. Ecol. Model. 2021, 446, 109504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Fort, H.; Grigera, T. A new early warning indicator of tree species crashes from effective intraspecific interactions in tropical forests. Ecol. Indic. 2021, 125, 107506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Emary, C.; Fort, H. Markets as ecological networks: Inferring interactions and identifying communities. J. Complex Netw. 2021, 9, cnab022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. The Global Industry Classification Standard (GICS). Available online: https://www.msci.com/our-solutions/indexes/gics (accessed on 25 May 2023).
  76. Adomavicius, G.; Bockstedt, J.C.; Gupta, A.; Kauffman, R.J. Technology roles and paths of influence in an ecosystem model of technology evolution. Inf. Technol. Manag. 2007, 8, 185–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Drożdż, S.; Grümmer, F.; Górski, A.Z.; Ruf, F.; Speth, J. Dynamics of competition between collectivity and noise in the stock market. Phys. A 2000, 287, 440–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  78. Triplett, R.; Ozdemir, N.; Mason, P. Structural Change in the Investment Function. J. Econ. Financ. 2022, 46, 220–236. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Fort, H. A quantitative assessment of the evolutionary dynamics of firms: Estimating the fitnesses from time series of their market caps and forecasting their shares. J. Evol. Econ. 2023; submitted. [Google Scholar]
  80. Fort, H. Disentangling the effects of selection and the environment in the evolutionary dynamics of financial markets in terms of Malthusian fitness. Work in progress, to be published elsewhere.
Figure 1. The total market value V vs. the S&P 500 index, for the period 2012–2021 [41].
Figure 1. The total market value V vs. the S&P 500 index, for the period 2012–2021 [41].
Entropy 25 01029 g001
Figure 2. The Shannon evenness curves EN (t) computed for the top N = 20 companies, the top N = 30, …, the whole set of 78 companies (thick gray curve).
Figure 2. The Shannon evenness curves EN (t) computed for the top N = 20 companies, the top N = 30, …, the whole set of 78 companies (thick gray curve).
Entropy 25 01029 g002
Figure 5. For each value of δ the corresponding E, R and V were obtained as averages E ¯ , R ¯   and   V ¯ over 1000 simulations of synthetic communities, defined by the interaction matrix of Equation (6), starting with the initial random configuration of Equation (7). (a): Curves of E ¯ vs. δ (circles, left axis) and V ¯ vs. δ (triangles, right axis). (b): Curves of E ¯ vs. δ (circles, left axis) and R ¯ vs. δ (triangles, right axis).
Figure 5. For each value of δ the corresponding E, R and V were obtained as averages E ¯ , R ¯   and   V ¯ over 1000 simulations of synthetic communities, defined by the interaction matrix of Equation (6), starting with the initial random configuration of Equation (7). (a): Curves of E ¯ vs. δ (circles, left axis) and V ¯ vs. δ (triangles, right axis). (b): Curves of E ¯ vs. δ (circles, left axis) and R ¯ vs. δ (triangles, right axis).
Entropy 25 01029 g005
Table 1. The 78 companies considered in this study ordered by their market value as of 31 December 2021 [41].
Table 1. The 78 companies considered in this study ordered by their market value as of 31 December 2021 [41].
CompanyTickerMarket Val (USD Bill)Rank    SectorIndustry
AppleAAPL29021     TechnologyConsumer Electronics
MicrosoftMSFT25222     TechnologySoftware–Infrastructure
AmazonAMZN16973    Consumer CyclicalInternet Retail
Berkshire HathawayBRK662.634     Financial ServicesInsurance
JP MorganJPM472.515     Financial ServicesBanks
United Health GroupUNH466.216     HealthcareHealthcare Plans
Johnson & JohnsonJNJ450.367     HealthcareDrug Manufacturers
Home DepotHD433.378    Consumer CyclicalHome Retail
WalmartWMT401.359    Consumer DefensiveDiscount Stores
P&GPG392.1110    Consumer DefensiveHousehold
Bank of AmericaBAC359.3811     Financial ServicesBanks
Pfizer Inc.PFE331.8612     HealthcareDrug Manufacturers
The Walt Disney CompanyDIS281.5413    Comm. ServicesEntertainment
Cisco Systems, Inc.CSCO267.2714     TechnologyComm. Equipment
NikeNKE263.5515    Consumer CyclicalFootwear and Access.
Thermo Fisher Scientific Inc.TMO263.1816     HealthcareDiagnosis and Research
Exxon MobilXOM259.3817    EnergyOil and Gas
The Coca-Cola CompanyKO256.0918    Consumer DefensiveBeverages
CostcoCOST251.7419    Consumer DefensiveDiscount Stores
Abbott LaboratoriesABT248.2820     HealthcareMedical Devices
PepsiCo, Inc.PEP240.2421    Consumer DefensiveBeverages
OracleORCL232.8922     TechnologySoftware–Infrastructure
ComcastCMCSA228.1623    Comm. ServicesTelecom Services
ChevronCVX226.4624    EnergyOil and Gas
VerizonVZ218.1225    Comm. ServicesTelecom Services
Intel CorporationINTC209.626     TechnologySemiconductors
QUALCOMM IncorporatedQCOM205.7327     TechnologySemiconductors
Merck & Co., Inc.MRK193.7228     HealthcareDrug Manufacturers
Wells FargoWFC186.4429     Financial ServicesBanks
AnthemUPS186.4130     IndustrialsIntegrated Freight and Logistics
Lowe’sLOW174.1531    Consumer CyclicalHome Retail
Morgan StanleyMS173.9632     Financial ServicesBanks
Honeywell International Inc.HON142.7933     IndustrialsConglomerates
CVS CaremarkCVS136.3834     HealthcareHealthcare Plans
Bristol-Myers Squibb CompanyBMY134.2435     HealthcareDrug Manufacturers
AT&TT132.5836    Comm. ServicesTelecom Services
Raytheon Technologies Corp.RTX128.5137     IndustrialsAerospace and Defense
The Goldman Sachs Group, Inc.GS127.6138     Financial ServicesBanks
American Express CompanyAXP124.539     Financial ServicesCredit Services
IBMIBM120.0440     TechnologyInformation Tech. Serv.
CitigroupC119.8441     Financial ServicesBanks
BoeingBA118.5642     IndustrialsAerospace and Defense
TargetTGT110.8943    Consumer DefensiveDiscount Stores
Caterpillar Inc.CAT110.7944     IndustrialsFarm and Heavy Constr.
Deere & CompanyDE105.6845     IndustrialsFarm and Heavy Constr.
General electricsGE103.8346     IndustrialsSpecialty Industr. Machinery
3M CompanyMMM101.5847     IndustrialsConglomerates
Lockheed Martin CorporationLMT96.3248     IndustrialsAerospace and Defense
ConocoPhillipsCOP9449     EnergyOil and Gas
Phillips 66TJX90.5650    EnergyOil and Gas
Ford MotorsF85.5951    Consumer CyclicalAuto Manufacturers
Cigna CorporationCI74.1652     HealthcareHealthcare Plans
FedEx CorporationFDX68.5353     IndustrialsIntegrated Freight and Logistics
Northrop Grumman Corp.NOC60.4954     IndustrialsAerospace and Defense
Capital One Financial Corp.COF60.0555     Financial ServicesCredit Services
The Progressive CorporationPGR59.9956     Financial ServicesInsurance
Humana Inc.HUM59.7557     HealthcareHealthcare Plans
General DynamicsGD57.8858     IndustrialsAerospace and Defense
Enterprise Products Partners L.P.EPD47.7959    EnergyOil and Gas
AIGAIG46.5560     Financial ServicesInsurance
Walgreens Boots AllianceWBA45.0361     HealthcarePharmaceutical Retailers
HP Inc.HPQ40.7962     TechnologyComputer Hardware
Exelon CorporationEXC40.3463    UtilitiesUtilities-Regulated Electric
Sysco CorporationSYY40.2764    Consumer DefensiveFood Distribution
Archer-Daniels-Midland Comp.ADM37.8565    Consumer DefensiveFarm Products
The Travelers Companies, Inc.TRV37.7366     Financial ServicesInsurance
McKesson Corp.MCK37.2467     HealthcareMedical Distribution
The Kroger Co.KR33.2868    Consumer DefensiveGrocery Stores
The Allstate CorporationALL33.0669     Financial ServicesInsurance
Tyson Foods, Inc.TSN31.6570    Consumer DefensiveFarm Products
Nucor CorporationNUE31.171    Basic MaterialsSteel
Valero EnergyVLO30.7372    EnergyOil and Gas
AmerisourceBergenABC27.7873     HealthcareMedical Distribution
Best Buy Co., Inc.BBY24.4474    Consumer CyclicalSpecialty Retail
Cardinal HealthCAH14.2675     HealthcareMedical Distribution
Arrow Electronics, Inc.ARW9.1476     TechnologyElectronics Distribution
Fannie MaeFNMA0.9577     Financial ServicesMortgage Finance
Chico’s FAS, Inc.CHS0.6678     Consumer CyclicalApparel Retail
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Fort, H. Productivity vs. Evenness in the U.S. Financial Market: A Business Ecosystem Perspective. Entropy 2023, 25, 1029. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25071029

AMA Style

Fort H. Productivity vs. Evenness in the U.S. Financial Market: A Business Ecosystem Perspective. Entropy. 2023; 25(7):1029. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25071029

Chicago/Turabian Style

Fort, Hugo. 2023. "Productivity vs. Evenness in the U.S. Financial Market: A Business Ecosystem Perspective" Entropy 25, no. 7: 1029. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25071029

APA Style

Fort, H. (2023). Productivity vs. Evenness in the U.S. Financial Market: A Business Ecosystem Perspective. Entropy, 25(7), 1029. https://doi.org/10.3390/e25071029

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop