Upstream-Downstream Joint Carbon Reduction Strategies Based on Low-Carbon Promotion
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Problem Description and Assumptions
2.1. Problem Description
2.2. Symbol Description
2.3. Model Assumptions
- (1)
- According to [11,12], the relationship between the cost of the emissions reduction effort for low-carbon products and the level of effort in emissions reduction, , is as follows. The cost of the emissions reduction effort is , where () indicates the coefficient of the cost of the emissions reduction effort. The relationship between the cost of the promotional effort for low-carbon products and the degree of the promotional effort, , is as follows. The cost of the promotional effort , where (), indicates the coefficient of the cost of the promotional effort.
- (2)
- The unit product emissions reduction is related to the degree of emissions reduction effort of the manufacturer and is a dynamic process. The differential equation, Equation (1), shows the process of change in product unit emissions reduction:In the equation, is the amount of emissions reduction per unit of product at time t. For the initial emissions reduction , indicates the extent of the impact of the emissions reduction effort on the emissions reductions per unit of product and () indicates the attenuation coefficient of emissions reduction due to aging equipment without any emissions reduction effort. Similar usage of (1) is visible in [6,13].
- (3)
- The demand function is as follows:In the equation, represents the potential demand for low-carbon products in the market, , α indicates the reaction coefficient of consumers to unit retail price , indicates the reaction coefficient of consumers to the extent of emissions reduction efforts in low-carbon products, and indicates the reaction coefficient of consumers to the extent of promotional efforts to support low-carbon products. Similar usage of (2) is visible [14].
- (4)
3. Model Solution
3.1. Under Decentralized Decision-Making
3.1.1. When Retailers Bear the Promotional Cost of Low-Carbon Products
(1) | |
(2) | |
(3) |
3.1.2. When the Manufacturer Bears the Promotional Cost of Low-Carbon Products
(1) | |
(2) | |
(3) |
3.2. Under Centralized Decision-Making
(1) | |
(2) | |
(3) |
4. Comparative Analysis
4.1. The Impact on System Stability
4.2. The Impact on Price and Sales Volume
4.3. The Impact on Efforts
5. Conclusions
- (1)
- The retail price per product unit increases when manufacturers bear the promotional cost of low-carbon products. However, the corresponding carbon reduction effort and promotional effort are greater than when retailers bear the promotional cost. In addition, the impact of carbon emissions reduction and low-carbon product promotion on the demand for low-carbon products is greater than the impact of increased prices on sales, ultimately promoting low-carbon product sales volume. Not only can the retail price per unit product be decreased, but the emissions reduction efforts and promotional efforts can also be increased to promote low-carbon sales when the supply chain is under centralized decision-making. That is, centralized decision-making in the supply chain can optimize the supply chain.
- (2)
- The carbon emissions reduction per product unit is the smallest when retailers bear the promotion costs, followed by when manufacturers bear the promotional cost, and lastly when under centralized decision-making. The main reason is that under centralized decision-making, the sales volume of low-carbon products, promotional efforts, and carbon emissions reduction efforts per product unit are the highest. This outcome increases the willingness of the manufacturers to reduce carbon emissions for low-carbon products and ultimately promotes carbon emissions reductions, thus achieving the largest carbon emissions reduction trajectory. Promotional efforts in support of low-carbon products and carbon emissions reduction efforts are the largest under centralized decision-making, followed by when manufacturers bear the promotional costs, and lastly when retailers bear the promotional costs. This phenomenon primarily occurs because when the manufacturers bear the promotional cost of low-carbon products, the level of carbon emissions reduction efforts increases, which is more conducive to the promotion of low-carbon products.
- (3)
- The retail price per product unit is the largest when manufacturers bear the promotional cost for low-carbon products, followed by when retailers bear the cost, and lastly when under centralized decision-making. Sales volume is the greatest under centralized decision-making, followed by when manufacturers bear the promotional cost, and lastly when retailers bear the promotional cost. This outcome in turn promotes the sales of low-carbon products, and its impact on sales is greater than the impact of higher prices, which ultimately increases the sales volume of low-carbon products. Further, it can be noted that under centralized decision-making, the unit retail price of low-carbon products is the lowest. However, the promotional efforts and carbon reduction efforts are the highest, ultimately maximizing the sales volume. That is, the entire supply chain is optimal under centralized decision-making.
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Chen, X.; Luo, Z.; Wang, X.J. Impact of efficiency, investment, and competition on low carbon manufacturing. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 143, 388–400. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wei, Y.; Liu, L.; Fan, Y.; Wu, G. The impact of lifestyle on energy use and CO2 emission: An empirical analysis of China’s residents. Energy Policy 2007, 35, 247–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, F.; Dong, S.; Xue, L.; Liang, Q.; Yang, W. Energy consumption-economic growth relationship and carbon dioxide emissions in China. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 568–574. [Google Scholar]
- Zhang, D.; Zou, F.; Li, S.; Zhou, L. Green Supply Chain Network Design with Economies of Scale and Environmental Concerns. J. Adv. Transp. 2017, 2017, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Du, S.F.; Zhu, J.; Jiao, H.F.; Ye, W.Y. Game-theoretical analysis for supply chain with consumer preference to low carbon. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2015, 53, 3753–3768. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Q.P.; Zhao, D.Z.; He, L.F. Contracting emission reduction for supply chains considering market low-carbon preference. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 120, 72–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ji, J.N.; Zhang, Z.Y.; Yang, L. Comparisons of initial carbon allowance allocation rules in an O2O retail supply chain with the cap-and-trade regulation. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 187, 68–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bai, Q.G.; Chen, M.Y.; Xu, L. Revenue and promotional cost-sharing contract versus two-part tariff contract in coordinating sustainable supply chain systems with deteriorating items. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 187, 85–101. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shao, L.L.; Yang, J.; Zhang, M. Subsidy scheme or price discount scheme? Mass adoption of electric vehicles under different market structures. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 262, 1181–1195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cao, K.Y.; Xu, X.P.; Wu, Q.; Zhang, Q.P. Optimal production and carbon emission reduction level under cap-and-trade and low carbon subsidy policies. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 167, 505–513. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kim, K.; Chhajed, D. Commonality in product design: Cost saving, valuation change and cannibalization. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2000, 125, 602–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mukhopadhyay, S.K.; Setoputro, R. Optimal return policy and modular design for build-to-order products. J. Oper. Manag. 2005, 23, 496–506. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nerlove, M.; Arrow, K.J. Optimal advertising police under dynamic conditions. Economica 1962, 39, 129–142. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Z.G.; Anderson, T.D.; Cruz, J.M. Consumer environmental awareness and competition in two-stage supply chains. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2012, 218, 602–613. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xie, J.X.; Wei, J.C. Coordinating advertising and pricing in a manufacturer-retailer channel. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2009, 197, 785–791. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, D.Q.; Xiao, T.J. Coordination of a supply chain with loss-averse consumers in service quality. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2017, 55, 3411–3430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, R.; Zhou, X.; Han, J.; Liu, C. For the sustainable performance of the carbon reduction labeling policies under an evolutionary game simulation. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2016, 112, 262–274. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, J.; Piao, S.R. Research on Regional Synergy Carbon Reduction Cost Allocation Based on Cooperative Game. Adv. Mater. Res. 2013, 781–784, 2569–2572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
© 2018 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Xia, X.; Ruan, J.; Juan, Z.; Shi, Y.; Wang, X.; Chan, F.T.S. Upstream-Downstream Joint Carbon Reduction Strategies Based on Low-Carbon Promotion. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2018, 15, 1351. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph15071351
Xia X, Ruan J, Juan Z, Shi Y, Wang X, Chan FTS. Upstream-Downstream Joint Carbon Reduction Strategies Based on Low-Carbon Promotion. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2018; 15(7):1351. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph15071351
Chicago/Turabian StyleXia, Xiqiang, Junhu Ruan, Zhiru Juan, Yan Shi, Xuping Wang, and Felix T. S. Chan. 2018. "Upstream-Downstream Joint Carbon Reduction Strategies Based on Low-Carbon Promotion" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 15, no. 7: 1351. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph15071351
APA StyleXia, X., Ruan, J., Juan, Z., Shi, Y., Wang, X., & Chan, F. T. S. (2018). Upstream-Downstream Joint Carbon Reduction Strategies Based on Low-Carbon Promotion. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 15(7), 1351. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph15071351