Finance and Jobs: How Financial Markets and Prudential Regulation Shape Unemployment Dynamics
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- Financial market developments have a significant albeit ambiguous influence on unemployment dynamics. In particular, market-based financial development (both stock and bond markets) appears conducive to more labor market turbulence with higher unemployment in- and out-flows. On the other hand, greater international financial openness has the opposite effect, again with an ambiguous effect on overall unemployment rates.
- Regarding financial market reforms, securities market liberalization also leads to higher labor market turbulence, confirming the effect of the de facto development of stock and bond markets. Similarly, banking sector reforms such as loosening credit controls and banking sector privatization strengthen job creation without affecting unemployment inflows. At the same time, improved prudential regulation of banks leads unambiguously to lower unemployment as both unemployment outflows increase and unemployment inflows decline. In contrast to de facto international openness, de jure capital account openness has an unambiguous positive effect on employment by increasing unemployment outflows and lowering unemployment inflows.
- Looking at the post-crisis period, financial market re-regulation appears modest when assessed in a historical context. Only a few additional constraints have been introduced that make financial regulation appear less market-friendly. When assessing the evolution of financial sector deregulation beyond 2009, financial market reform continues to display a distinctive pattern of increased labor market turbulence. Only the removal of entry barriers to the entry of new banks seem to reduce labor market turnover, albeit at the cost of an overall reduction in employment dynamics. Taken as a whole, financial market re-regulation had only a very limited positive effect on labor market developments.
- A scenario analysis suggests that much higher benefits for jobs could have been obtained had financial market reforms been bundled into a substantive regulation package. Adopting a political economy perspective, we present reasons why such an encompassing reform package has not been adopted despite its obvious labor market benefits. We demonstrate the potential positive impact on employment that a fully-fledged financial market reform could have had in comparison to a no-reform benchmark, but also with respect to partial reforms such as those effectively observed.
2. Finance and Regulation: An Overview of the Literature
2.1. Finance and Growth
2.2. Financial Market Development and Employment Dynamics
2.3. Financial Market Regulation: Between Economic Development and Instability
- Regulation of international capital flows and the international financial architecture will affect the availability of foreign capital in the domestic economy, lifting competition on the domestic banking sector and providing additional liquidity. This will help reduce domestic financial market frictions and should in principle lower the real long-term interest rate. At the same time, at the macroeconomic level, it can also increase economic volatility, in particular when financial deregulation is met with poor macroeconomic management and exchange rate misalignment. Over the long-run, this needs to be matched against the potentially positive effects of better integrated financial markets that can help especially low-income countries to overcome capital shortages and thereby promote job creation and limit job destruction.
- Banking sector regulation is expected to lead to lower credit growth and potentially to higher real interest rates. The former will reduce the growth rate of aggregate demand, dampening gross fixed capital formation and growth in disposable household income. In addition, the interest rate effect will not only slow down aggregate demand growth, but will directly affect the value of a new job, thereby lowering the rate at which new vacancies are being created and increasing the job destruction rate. At the same time, prudential banking sector reforms are expected to stabilize the financial sector, thereby raising the prospects for job stability and employment growth.
- The regulation of financial products, in particular regarding the derivatives market, can be expected to have ambiguous effects on labor markets. On the one hand, stricter regulation of certain products—regarding, for instance, the disclosure of information, the standardization and trading of these products on centralized platforms, or the outright prohibition of certain products such as uncovered short-selling—is likely to reduce market liquidity, with the risk of higher risk premia and more market volatility, translating into greater macroeconomic uncertainty and lower employment creation. On the other hand, to the extent that these products are themselves at the origin of macroeconomic volatility, regulating such activities can help stabilize the banking sector and thereby lower the macroeconomic risk premia.
3. Unemployment Flows and Financial Market Interactions
3.1. The Impact of Financial Market Frictions on Labor Market Outcomes
3.2. From Theory to Empirical Analysis: Unemployment Flows Accounting
4. Data, Methodology, and Hypotheses
4.1. Data: Unemployment Flows, Labor Market Institutions, and Financial Structure
4.2. Methodology and Hypotheses
- Country-specific information is not always available for all variables over the entire time period. Moreover, some of the financial reform indicators suffer from very limited time variability within country panels.
- Both unemployment in- and out-flows are highly persistent within countries, introducing problems of auto-correlation.
- Some of the right-hand side variables are endogenous to the dependent variable (in- and out-flows).
- Financial market development might simultaneously increase job creation and lower job destruction due to stronger investment that is being directed towards its most productive use;
- financial market development might also lead to higher labor market turnover as both unemployment out- and in-flows increase due to faster restructuring, which is implied by deeper financial markets;
- in contrast, financial market development might depress both job creation and increase job destruction if it brings about an increase in unproductive, speculative activities that do not generate jobs.
- Stricter regulation of banking sector activities will lead to an increase in the user cost of capital, thereby reducing unemployment outflows and increasing unemployment inflows.
- Better prudential regulation reduces financial market stress and stabilizes the banking sector, thereby relieving credit constraints; this should support job creation and limit job destruction.
5. Financial Market Determinants of Unemployment Flows
5.1. Financial Market Development and Unemployment Flows
5.2. Financial Market Reforms and Labor Market Flows
5.3. Robustness Check
6. Reform Scenarios and Unemployment Dynamics
- The financial and economic recovery actually complicates the task of substantial regulatory reform of financial markets. Political pressure for reforms wears off as business activities resume. The immediate sense of urgency recedes, making policy makers more lenient when putting forward an encompassing reform agenda. In addition, even though the crisis had somewhat reduced the political influence of financial firms in the immediate aftermath, as soon as the outlook improved, financial sector lobby groups started to gain a stronger political voice again. Finally, financial sector (re-)regulation will take place in a substantially different macroeconomic environment. Even 10 years after the crisis, the risk appetite of investors has resumed only partially. Over the longer term, however, investors are likely to re-evaluate their environment and consider investing in higher yielding and more risky assets.
- At the same time, countries and policy makers are limited in their action by the high level of public debt that has accumulated during the crisis and has not been brought down since. This will reduce their scope for action and hence the extent to which they can effectively introduce any kind of regulation without regard to the interests of capital owners and their own financiers. In the past, periods of rapid increase in public sector debt have often preceded periods of financial deregulation. In other words, even if it were possible to identify ex ante the optimal package of financial sector regulation, such a reform bundle is unlikely to be implemented ex post as policy makers rely heavily on financial markets to (re)finance their high and still increasing debt levels.
- Finally, regulatory competition between jurisdictions prevents countries from implementing all measures deemed necessary for fear of losing (financial sector) market share to competitors. As countries compete to attract financial firms through favorable regulatory conditions, overly stiff prudential regulation may hamper further growth of the financial sector. Highly-qualified staff may consider moving to different locations with a more attractive tax and regulatory environment (for instance regarding bonus regulation). Similarly, financial firms may consider moving their activities to jurisdictions where limitations on leverage and credit growth are less stringent, offering their services to clients abroad or arbitraging across different regulatory conditions through branching.
7. Conclusions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Abiad, Abiad, Enrica Detragiache, and Thierry Tressel. 2008. A New Database of Financial Reforms. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund (IMF). [Google Scholar]
- Acemoglu, Daron, Philippe Aghion, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2006. Distance to frontier, selection and economic growth. Journal of the European Economic Association 4: 37–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Admati, Anat R., Peter M. DeMarzo, Martin F. Hellwig, and Paul Pfleiderer. 2013. Fallacies, Irrelevant Facts, and Myths in the Discussion of Capital Regulation: Why Bank Equity Is Not Socially Expensive. Stanford: Stanford Graduate School of Business. [Google Scholar]
- Aghion, Philippe, Peter Howitt, and David Mayer-Foulkes. 2005. The effect of financial development on convergence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120: 173–222. [Google Scholar]
- Aizenman, Joshua, Donghyun Park, and Yothin Jinjarak. 2015. Financial Development and Output Growth in Developing Asia and Latin America: A Comparative Sectoral Analysis. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- Allen, Franklin, and Douglas Gale. 1999. Comparing Financial Systems. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Arcand, Jean Louis, Enrico Berkes, and Ugo Panizza. 2015. Too much finance? Journal of Economic Growth 20: 105–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Balakrishnan, Ravi, Stephan Danninger, Selim Elekdag, and Irina Tytell. 2009. The Transmission of Financial Stress From Advanced to Emerging Economies. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund (IMF). [Google Scholar]
- Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2010. An Assessment of the Long-Term Economic Impat of Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements. Technical Report. Basel: Bank for International Settlements (BIS). [Google Scholar]
- Beck, Thorsten. 2009. The econometrics of finance and growth. In Palgrave Handbook of Econometrics. Edited by Terence C. Mills and Kerry D. Patterson. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 1180–209. [Google Scholar]
- Beck, Thorsten, Asli Demirgüç-Kunt, and Ross Levine. 2000. A new database on financial development and structure. World Bank Economic Review 14: 597–605. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beck, Thorsten, Ross Levine, and Norman Loayza. 2000. Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics 58: 261–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bentolila, Samuel, Marcel Jansen, and Gabriel Jiménez. 2017. When credit dries up: Job losses in the great recession. Journal of the European Economic Association 16: 650–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berton, Fabio, Sauro Mocetti, Andrea F. Presbitero, and Matteo Richiardi. 2018. Banks, firms and jobs. Review of Financial Studies 31: 2113–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Blanchard, Olivier, Jonathan D. Ostry, Atish R. Ghosh, and Marcos Chamon. 2016. Capital flows: Expansionary or contractionary? American Economic Review 106: 565–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Brezigar-Masten, Arjana, Fabrizio Coricelli, and Igor Masten. 2008. Non-linear growth effects of financial development: Does financial integration matter? Journal of International Money and Finance 27: 295–313. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Burniaux, Jean-Marc, Romain Duval, and Florence Jaumotte. 2003. Coping With Ageing: A Dynamic Approach to Quantify the Impact of Alternative Policy Options on Future Labor Supply in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD Economics Department Working Papers. [Google Scholar]
- Caballero, Ricardo J. 2007. Specificity and the Macroeconomics of Restructuring. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Caggese, Andrea, and Vicente Cunat. 2008. Financing constraints and fixed-term employment contracts. The Economic Journal 118: 2013–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carlin, Wendy, and Colin Mayer. 2003. Finance, investment, and growth. Journal of Financial Economics 69: 191–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Carlsson, Mikael, Stefan Eriksson, and Nils Gottfries. 2006. Testing Theories of Job Creation: Does Supply Create Its Own Demand? Munich: CESifo Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
- Chugh, Sanjay K. 2013. Costly external finance and labor market dynamics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37: 2882–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Claessens, Stijn, and Laura Kodres. 2014. The Regulatory Responses to the Global Financial Crisis: Some Uncomfortable Questions. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund (IMF). [Google Scholar]
- Compton, Ryan A., and Daniel C. Giedeman. 2011. Panel evidence on finance, institutions and economic growth. Applied Economics 43: 3523–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Deli, Yota D., and Iftekhar Hasan. 2018. Real effects of bank capital regulations: Global evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance 82: 217–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli, and Ross Levine, eds. 2001. Financial Structure and Economic Growth: A Cross-Country Comparison of Banks, Markets, and Developpement. Cambridge: MIT-Press. [Google Scholar]
- Elsby, Michael, Bart Hobijn, and Asegül Sahin. 2013. Unemployment dynamics in the OECD. Review of Economics and Statistics 95: 530–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Epstein, Brendan, and Alan Finkelstein Shapiro. 2019. Financial development, unemployment volatility, and sectoral dynamics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 99: 82–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ernst, Ekkehard. 2011. Determinants of Unemployment Flows. Labour Market Institutions And Macroeconomic Policies. Geneva: International Labour Organization (ILO). [Google Scholar]
- Ernst, Ekkehard, and Verónica Escudero. 2008. The Effects of Financial Globalization on Global Imbalances, Employment and Inequality. Geneva: International Labour Organization (ILO). [Google Scholar]
- Ernst, Ekkehard, Stefan Mittnik, and Willi Semmler. 2016. Interaction of labor and credit market in growth regimes: A theoretical and empirical analysis. Economic Notes 45: 393–422. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ernst, Ekkehard, and Uma Rani. 2011. Understanding unemployment flows. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 27: 268–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ernst, Ekkehard, and Faten Saliba. 2018. Are house prices responsible for unemployment persistence? Open Economies Review 29: 795–833. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ernst, Ekkehard, and Willi Semmler. 2010. Global dynamics in a model with search and matching in labor and capital markets. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 34: 1651–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Financial Stability Board. 2010. Assessing the Macroeconomic Impact of the Transition to Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements: Interim Report. Technical Report. Basel: Bank for International Settlements (BIS). [Google Scholar]
- Shapiro, Alan Finkelstein, and Andrés Gónzalez Gómez. 2015. Macroprudential Policy and Labor Market Dynamics in Emerging Economies. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. [Google Scholar]
- Shapiro, Alan Finkelstein, and Andrés Gónzalez Gómez. 2017. Credit market imperfections, labor markets, and leverage dynamics in emerging economies. Journal of International Money and Finance 78: 44–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gatti, Donatella, Christophe Rault, and Anne-Gael Vaubourg. 2012. Unemployment and finance: How do financial and labor market factors interact? Oxford Economic Papers 64: 464–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- International Labour Organization (ILO). 2013a. Global Employment Trends. Recovering From a Second Jobs Dip. Geneva: International Labour Organization (ILO). [Google Scholar]
- International Labour Organization (ILO). 2013b. The ilo estimates on unemployment flows: Introducing flows to assess the variations in unemployment. In Key Indicators of the Labour Market, 8th ed. Geneva: International Labour Office. [Google Scholar]
- Institute of International Finance. 2010. Interim Report on the Cumulative Impact on the Global Economy of Proposed Changes in the Banking Regulatory Framework. Technical Report. Washington, DC: IIF. [Google Scholar]
- Intartaglia, Maurizio, Andreas Antoniades, and Sambit Bhattacharyya. 2018. Unbundled debt and economic growth in developed and developing economies: An empirical analysis. The World Economy 41: 3345–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- International Institute for Labour Studies. 2010. World of Work Report 2010. From One Crisis to the Next? Geneva: International Labour Organization (ILO). [Google Scholar]
- Kashyap, Anil, Jeremy C. Stein, and Samuel G. Hanson. 2010. An Analysis of the Impact of “Substantially Heightened” Capital Requirements on Large Financial Institutions. Chicago: University of Chicago. [Google Scholar]
- Kumhof, Michael, Romain Rancière, and Pablo Winant. 2015. Inequality, leverage, and crises. American Economic Reivew 105: 1217–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lane, Philip R., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti. 2007. The External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 1970–2004. Journal of International Economics 73: 223–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levine, Ross. 1997. Financial development and economic growth: Views and agenda. Journal of Economic Literature 35: 688–726. [Google Scholar]
- Levine, Ross. 2005. Finance and Growth: Theory and Evidence. London: Elsevier B. V, pp. 865–934. [Google Scholar]
- Levine, Ross, and Sara Zervos. 1998. Stock markets, banks, and economic growth. American Economic Review 88: 537–58. [Google Scholar]
- Loayza, Norman, Amine Ouazad, and Romain Rancière. 2018. Financial Development, Growth, and Crisis: Is There a Trade-Off? Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- Love, Inessa. 2003. Financial development and financing constraints: International evidence from the structural investment model. Review of Financial Studies 16: 765–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Monnin, Pierre, and Terhi Jokipii. 2013. The impact of banking sector stability on the real economy. Journal of International Money and Finance 32: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [Green Version]
- Pagano, Marco, and Giovanni Pica. 2012. Finance and employment. Economic Policy 27: 5–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pagano, Marco, and Paolo F. Volpin. 2005. Managers, workers, and corporate control. Journal of Finance 60: 843–70. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pagano, Marco, and Paolo F. Volpin. 2005. The political economy of corporate governance. American Economic Review 95: 1005–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Petrongolo, Barbara, and Christopher A. Pissarides. 2008. The ins and outs of european unemployment. American Economic Review 98: 256–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Phelps, Edmund S. 1998. Structural Slumps: The Modern Equilibrium Theory Of Unemployment, Interest, and Assets. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Pissarides, Christopher A. 2000. Equilibrium Unemployment Theory. Cambridge: The MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Rajan, Raghuram. G. 2010. Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Rajan, Raghuram G., and Luigi Zingales. 1998. Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review 88: 559–86. [Google Scholar]
- Rancière, Romain, Aaron Tornell, and Frank Westermann. 2006. Decomposing the effects of financial liberalization: Growth vs. crises. Journal of Banking and Finance 30: 3331–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rousseau, Peter L., and Dadanee Vuthipadadorn. 2005. Finance, investment, and growth: Time series evidence from 10 asian economies. Journal of Macroeconomics 27: 87–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rousseau, Peter L., and Paul Wachtel. 1998. Financial intermediation and economic performance: Historical evidence from five industrial countries. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 30: 657–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shimer, Robert. 2005. The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies. American Economic Review 95: 25–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shimer, Robert. 2012. Reassessing the ins and outs of unemployment. Review of Economic Dynamics 15: 127–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tooze, Adam. 2018. Crashed: How a Decade of Financial Crises Changed the World. London: Allen Lane. [Google Scholar]
- Wasmer, Etienne, and Philippe Weil. 2004. The macroeconomics of labor and credit market imperfections. American Economic Review 94: 944–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zoega, Gylfi. 2012. Employment and asset prices. Applied Economics 44: 3343–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1 | Standard macro-economic models that abstract from financial frictions often have difficulties in replicating observed employment volatility, which has been dubbed the “Shimer puzzle”, following Shimer (2005). Alternative specifications of the labor market matching process exist that can accommodate this volatility without resortingto counter-cyclical external finance premiums. |
Dependent Variable: Unemployment Inflows | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1.1) | (1.2) | (1.3) | (1.4) | (1.5) | |
Unemployment inflows | 0.881 *** | 0.912 *** | 0.836 *** | 0.831 *** | 0.808 *** |
(lagged) | (1.9 ) | (1.9 ) | (2.2 ) | (2.4 ) | (3.1 ) |
Output gap | −3.3 *** | −2.6 ** | −3.8 *** | −4.2 *** | −5.1 *** |
(9.0 ) | (1.1 ) | (1.0 ) | (1.0 ) | (1.5 ) | |
TFP growth | 2.4 ** | 2.8 *** | 2.6 ** | 2.5 ** | 3.4 ** |
(lagged) | (1.0 ) | (1.2 ) | (1.1 ) | (1.2 ) | (1.6 ) |
Labor force growth | 1.247 *** | −1.4 | 1.228 *** | 1.291 *** | 8.7 *** |
(lagged) | (3.2 ) | (1.5 ) | (3.0 ) | (3.2 ) | (2.8 ) |
Real share price growth | −1.3 *** | −1.5 *** | −9.8 *** | −1.2 *** | −1.9 *** |
(lagged) | (3.7 ) | (3.9 ) | (3.8 ) | (3.9 ) | (4.9 ) |
Financial market | −4.5 ** | −1.2 *** | |||
development | (2.1 ) | (3.2 ) | |||
International | −1.1 ** | −1.8 *** | |||
financial openness | (4.0 ) | (5.6 ) | |||
Stock market | 1.9 ** | 8.2 *** | |||
development | (1.0 ) | (2.9 ) | |||
Private bond market | 1.5 *** | 2.0 *** | |||
capitalization | (3.1 ) | (4.8 ) | |||
Observations | 399 | 315 | 342 | 307 | 206 |
Number of countries | 19 | 19 | 19 | 18 | 18 |
Dependent Variable: Unemployment Outflows | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
(2.1) | (2.2) | (2.3) | (2.4) | (2.5) | |
Unemployment outflows | 0.770 *** | 0.726 *** | 0.770 *** | 0.712 *** | 0.700 *** |
(lagged) | (2.9 ) | (3.5 ) | (3.2 ) | (3.8 ) | (4.4 ) |
Output gap | 1.9 *** | 2.4 *** | 1.1 | 1.6 * | 3.5 ** |
(7.0 ) | (9.0 ) | (7.0 ) | (9.0 ) | (1.1 ) | |
Real long term | −4.0 | −1.6 ** | 1.0 | −3.0 *** | |
interest rate | (6.0 ) | (7.0 ) | (6.0 ) | (8.0 ) | |
Wage-interest rate | −4.2 ** | −8.8 *** | −5.9 *** | −5.4 ** | −1.0 * |
ratio | (2.0 ) | (4.5 ) | (2.1 ) | (2.1 ) | (5.2 ) |
Real share price growth | 1.7 ** | ||||
(7.0 ) | |||||
Gross fixed capital | 1.232 *** | 1.188 *** | 1.164 *** | 1.288 *** | |
investment | (2.0 ) | (2.4 ) | (2.1 ) | (2.4 ) | |
Financial market | 0.149 *** | 8.1 ** | |||
development | (3.1 ) | (4.1 ) | |||
International financial | −0.044 *** | −4-5 *** | |||
openness | (8.0 ) | (8.4 ) | |||
Stock market | 0.182 *** | 0.171 *** | |||
development | (3.7 ) | (4.8 ) | |||
Private bond market | 0.378 *** | 0.358 *** | |||
capitalization | (6.2 ) | (7.2 ) | |||
Observations | 390 | 302 | 332 | 303 | 214 |
Number of countries | 20 | 20 | 20 | 18 | 18 |
Dependent Variable: Unemployment Outflows | |||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(3.1) | (3.2) | (3.3) | (3.4) | (3.5) | (3.6) | (3.7) | (3.8) | (3.9) | (3.10) | (3.11) | |
Unemployment outflows | 0.734 *** | 0.799 *** | 0.800 *** | 0.745 *** | 0.788 *** | 0.836 *** | 0.836 *** | 0.815 *** | 0.816 *** | 0.838 *** | 0.857 *** |
(lagged) | (0.0345) | (0.0283) | (0.0283) | (0.0342) | (0.0320) | (0.0273) | (0.0307) | (0.0275) | (0.0301) | (0.0271) | (0.0273) |
Output gap | 0.0133 ** | 0.00451 | 0.00498 | 0.0134** | 0.0103* | 0.0139** | 0.00938 | 0.00637 | 0.00354 | 0.00912 | 0.00283 |
(0.00593) | (0.00626) | (0.00626) | (0.00628) | (0.00624) | (0.00662) | (0.00639) | (0.00621) | (0.00651) | (0.00621) | (0.00670) | |
Real short-term interest rate | −0.0196 *** | −0.0133 *** | −0.0136 *** | −0.0189 *** | −0.0143 *** | −0.0126 ** | −0.0200 *** | −0.00946 * | −0.0154 *** | −0.0119 ** | −0.0124 ** |
(0.00478) | (0.00505) | (0.00506) | (0.00483) | (0.00522) | (0.00551) | (0.00527) | (0.00536) | (0.00510) | (0.00522) | (0.00542) | |
Change in wage-capital ratio | −0.105 *** | −0.132 *** | −0.132 *** | −0.108 *** | −0.116 *** | −0.107 *** | −0.121 *** | −0.129 *** | −0.131 *** | −0.121 *** | −0.135 *** |
(0.0316) | (0.0332) | (0.0333) | (0.0321) | (0.0330) | (0.0345) | (0.0362) | (0.0333) | (0.0336) | (0.0332) | (0.0364) | |
Real share price inflation | 0.102 ** | 0.0816 * | 0.0846 * | 0.104 ** | 0.109 ** | 0.118 ** | 0.111 ** | 0.104 ** | 0.145 *** | 0.103 ** | 0.136 *** |
(0.0466) | (0.0496) | (0.0497) | (0.0473) | (0.0482) | (0.0505) | (0.0510) | (0.0492) | (0.0503) | (0.0492) | (0.0525) | |
Gross fixed capital formation | 4.383 *** | 5.038 *** | 5.009 *** | 4.145 *** | 4.302 *** | 2.803 *** | 3.752 *** | 4.582 *** | 4.762 *** | 3.912 *** | 4.575 *** |
(0.874) | (0.954) | (0.956) | (0.939) | (0.913) | (0.949) | (0.979) | (0.933) | (0.963) | (0.907) | (1.015) | |
Growth in real household | 1.361 ** | 1.698 *** | 1.702 *** | 1.375 ** | 1.481 ** | 1.400 ** | 1.348 ** | 1.592 ** | 1.859 *** | 1.523 ** | 1.851 *** |
disposable income | (0.604) | (0.639) | (0.640) | (0.613) | (0.626) | (0.656) | (0.670) | (0.638) | (0.654) | (0.637) | (0.685) |
Financial derivatives liabilities | −2.760 *** | −2.883 *** | −2.891 *** | −2.665 *** | −2.174 *** | −3.205 *** | −2.538 *** | −3.351 *** | −2.237 *** | −2.729 *** | −2.851 *** |
(in % of GDP, lagged) | (0.552) | (0.585) | (0.588) | (0.557) | (0.525) | (0.702) | (0.695) | (0.620) | (0.567) | (0.587) | (0.711) |
Removing directed credit | 0.130 *** | ||||||||||
provisions (lagged) | (0.0175) | ||||||||||
Loosening of credit controls | 0.130 *** | ||||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0177) | ||||||||||
Loosening of interest rate controls | 0.0168 | ||||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0214) | ||||||||||
Lifting of entry barriers | 0.00438 | ||||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0106) | ||||||||||
Bank privatization | 0.0810 *** | ||||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0189) | ||||||||||
Capital account openness | 0.0514 *** | 0.0350 ** | |||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0168) | (0.0156) | |||||||||
Financial reforms | 0.0251 *** | ||||||||||
(lagged) | (0.00373) | ||||||||||
Securities markets’ deregulation | 0.203 *** | 0.123 *** | |||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0327) | (0.0345) | |||||||||
Prudential regulation of banks | 0.0566 *** | 0.0376 *** | |||||||||
(lagged) | (0.00879) | (0.00911) | |||||||||
Constant | −0.531 *** | −0.805 *** | −0.803 *** | −0.555 *** | −0.474 *** | −0.514 *** | −0.458 *** | −0.886 *** | −1.036 *** | −0.480 *** | −0.883 *** |
(0.0727) | (0.106) | (0.107) | (0.110) | (0.0730) | (0.0915) | (0.0975) | (0.121) | (0.147) | (0.0741) | (0.152) | |
Observations | 152 | 152 | 152 | 152 | 152 | 152 | 145 | 152 | 152 | 152 | 145 |
Number of countries | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 | 8 |
Dependent Variable: Unemployment Inflows | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(4.1) | (4.2) | (4.3) | (4.4) | (4.5) | (4.6) | (4.7) | (4.8) | (4.9) | |
Unemployment inflows | 0.940 *** | 0.942 *** | 0.911 *** | 0.941 *** | 0.930 *** | 0.925 *** | 0.935 *** | 0.912 *** | 0.939 *** |
(lagged) | (0.0179) | (0.0229) | (0.0235) | (0.0176) | (0.0177) | (0.0170) | (0.0164) | (0.0177) | (0.0184) |
Output gap | −0.00208 | −0.00654 | −0.00632 | −0.00194 | −0.00237 | −0.00286 | −0.00244 | −0.00284 | −0.00813 *** |
(0.00288) | (0.00548) | (0.00514) | (0.00289) | (0.00287) | (0.00286) | (0.00287) | (0.00281) | (0.00303) | |
Total factor productivity | 0.167 ** | 0.421 *** | 0.442 *** | 0.169 ** | 0.170 ** | 0.177 ** | 0.163 ** | 0.171 ** | 0.202 ** |
(annual growth) | (0.0766) | (0.112) | (0.113) | (0.0765) | (0.0756) | (0.0750) | (0.0763) | (0.0775) | (0.0799) |
Labor force participation rate | 0.495 ** | −0.0287 | 0.229 | 0.471 ** | 0.605 *** | 0.617 *** | 0.494 ** | 0.492 ** | 0.849 *** |
(lagged) | (0.233) | (0.280) | (0.283) | (0.231) | (0.215) | (0.223) | (0.210) | (0.207) | (0.223) |
User cost of capital | 0.01000 *** | 0.0173 *** | 0.0194 *** | 0.0100 *** | 0.0100 *** | 0.00914 *** | 0.00964 *** | 0.00967 *** | 0.00785 ** |
(lagged) | (0.00335) | (0.00509) | (0.00500) | (0.00334) | (0.00326) | (0.00325) | (0.00327) | (0.00328) | (0.00344) |
Real imports growth | −0.518 *** | −0.432 ** | −0.417 ** | −0.517 *** | −0.506 *** | −0.502 *** | −0.517 *** | −0.496 *** | −0.392 *** |
(lagged) | (0.112) | (0.180) | (0.170) | (0.112) | (0.111) | (0.111) | (0.111) | (0.109) | (0.113) |
Removing directed credit | 0.00526 | ||||||||
provisions (lagged) | (0.00983) | ||||||||
Removing credit ceilings | −0.0530 | −0.0465 | |||||||
(lagged) | (0.0583) | (0.0551) | |||||||
Financial derivatives liabilities | −5.842 *** | −1.118 *** | 0.194 | ||||||
(in % of GDP, lagged) | (2.063) | (0.372) | (0.406) | ||||||
Loosening of credit controls | 0.00736 | ||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0106) | ||||||||
Loosening of interest rate controls | −0.0109 | ||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0114) | ||||||||
Lifting of entry barriers | −0.0130* | ||||||||
(lagged) | (0.00683) | ||||||||
Bank privatization | 0.0121 | 0.0250 *** | |||||||
(lagged) | (0.00751) | (0.00844) | |||||||
Capital account openness | −0.0530 *** | ||||||||
(lagged) | (0.00939) | ||||||||
Securities markets’ deregulation | 0.0546 *** | ||||||||
(lagged) | (0.0152) | ||||||||
Prudential regulation of banks | −0.0123 ** | ||||||||
(lagged) | (0.00547) | ||||||||
Constant | −0.767 *** | −0.566 *** | −0.884 *** | −0.752 *** | −0.848 *** | −0.888 *** | −0.797 *** | −0.933 *** | −1.064 *** |
(0.178) | (0.201) | (0.213) | (0.176) | (0.178) | (0.184) | (0.177) | (0.181) | (0.175) | |
Observations | 221 | 75 | 75 | 221 | 221 | 221 | 221 | 221 | 211 |
Number of countries | 12 | 5 | 5 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 | 12 |
Dependent Variable: Unemployment Inflows | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(5.1) | (5.2) | (5.3) | (5.4) | (5.5) | (5.6) | (5.7) | |
Inflows | 0.762 *** | 0.767 *** | 0.770 *** | 0.795 *** | 0.790 *** | 0.735 *** | 0.757 *** |
(lagged) | (0.0275) | (0.0279) | (0.0287) | (0.0268) | (0.0266) | (0.0290) | (0.0322) |
Output gap | −0.0194 *** | −0.0187 *** | −0.0177 *** | -0.0197 *** | −0.0206 *** | −0.0170 *** | −0.0160 *** |
(0.00336) | (0.00331) | (0.00345) | (0.00311) | (0.00314) | (0.00334) | (0.00376) | |
Total factor | 9.85 *** | 8.64 *** | 7.99 *** | 8.12 *** | 8.31 *** | 9.77 *** | 8.04 *** |
productivity growth | (2.20 ) | (2.11 ) | (2.16 ) | (2.15 ) | (2.16 ) | (2.18 ) | (2.27 ) |
Real long term | 0.0143 *** | 0.0102 ** | 0.0134 ** | 0.0136 *** | 0.0128 ** | ||
interest rate | (0.00509) | (0.00466) | (0.00526) | (0.00522) | (0.00607) | ||
Real long term | 0.0131 *** | 0.0137 *** | |||||
interest rate (change) | (0.00463) | (0.00464) | |||||
Real wage growth | 0.00902 ** | 0.00644 * | 0.00694 * | 0.00538 * | 0.00739 ** | 0.00680 * | 0.00785 * |
(lagged) | (0.00403) | (0.00389) | (0.00404) | (0.00296) | (0.00297) | (0.00401) | (0.00451) |
Financial reforms | 0.0214 *** | ||||||
(lagged) | (0.00739) | ||||||
Capital account | 0.178 *** | 0.133 *** | 0.176 *** | ||||
opening | (0.0446) | (0.0462) | (0.0489) | ||||
Prudential regulation | 0.0462 ** | 0.0620 *** | 0.0509 ** | ||||
of banks | (0.0193) | (0.0200) | (0.0210) | ||||
Removal of banks | −0.0695 *** | −0.0918 *** | −0.0828 *** | ||||
entry barriers | (0.0186) | (0.0250) | (0.0278) | ||||
Loosening of credit | 0.0352 ** | 0.0451 | |||||
controls (lagged) | (0.0152) | (0.0336) | |||||
Removal of credit | 1.034 * | ||||||
ceilings | (0.617) | ||||||
Constant | −1.648 *** | −1.720 *** | −1.304 *** | −0.815 *** | −1.142 *** | −1.760 *** | −2.691 *** |
(0.216) | (0.201) | (0.159) | (0.113) | (0.146) | (0.210) | (0.669) | |
Observations | 331 | 331 | 331 | 323 | 323 | 331 | 275 |
Number of countries | 18 | 18 | 18 | 18 | 18 | 18 | 15 |
Dependent Variable: Unemployment Outflows | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(6.1) | (6.2) | (6.3) | (6.4) | (6.5) | (6.6) | (6.7) | (6.8) | (6.9) | |
Outflows | 0.446 *** | 0.437 *** | 0.426 *** | 0.442 *** | 0.419 *** | 0.426 *** | 0.410 *** | 0.676 *** | 0.668 *** |
(lagged) | (0.0871) | (0.0887) | (0.0899) | (0.0865) | (0.0851) | (0.0863) | (0.0741) | (0.0350) | (0.0367) |
Output gap | 0.0270 *** | 0.0268 *** | 0.0241 *** | 0.0277 *** | 0.0288 *** | 0.0279 *** | 0.0301 *** | 0.0411 *** | 0.0397 *** |
(0.00714) | (0.00714) | (0.00723) | (0.00704) | (0.00696) | (0.00701) | (0.00657) | (0.00522) | (0.00522) | |
Real long term | −0.0575 *** | −0.0592 *** | −0.0612 *** | -0.0565 *** | −0.0548 *** | −0.0562 *** | −0.0530 *** | −0.0258 *** | −0.0278 *** |
interest rates | (0.0100) | (0.0103) | (0.0104) | (0.00969) | (0.00926) | (0.00951) | (0.00778) | (0.00597) | (0.00609) |
Real wage growth | −0.0177 *** | −0.0183 *** | −0.0164 *** | -0.0180 *** | −0.0173 *** | −0.0166 *** | −0.0143 *** | −0.0177 *** | −0.0167 *** |
(lagged) | (0.00357) | (0.00355) | (0.00356) | (0.00358) | (0.00352) | (0.00360) | (0.00354) | (0.00360) | (0.00360) |
Real share price | 0.0872** | 0.0858** | 0.0886 ** | 0.0847** | 0.0732 ** | 0.0774 ** | 0.0468 | 0.114 *** | 0.115 *** |
variation | (0.0370) | (0.0370) | (0.0368) | (0.0372) | (0.0370) | (0.0372) | (0.0344) | (0.0326) | (0.0326) |
Financial reforms | 0.0147 *** | ||||||||
(0.00523) | |||||||||
Loosening of credit | 0.0544 *** | ||||||||
controls | (0.0169) | ||||||||
Privatization | 0.109 *** | 0.0479 *** | |||||||
of banks | (0.0211) | (0.0127) | |||||||
Prudential regulation | 0.0198** | ||||||||
of banks | (0.0101) | ||||||||
Security markets | −0.233 *** | −0.281 *** | 0.108 * | 0.104 * | |||||
deregulation | (0.0632) | (0.0648) | (0.0611) | (0.0610) | |||||
Capital account | 0.126 *** | 0.117 *** | 0.121 *** | 0.130 *** | |||||
opening (lagged) | (0.0419) | (0.0396) | (0.0417) | (0.0424) | |||||
Prudential regulation | 0.0202 ** | 0.0476 *** | 0.0329 *** | ||||||
of banks (lagged) | (0.0103) | (0.0116) | (0.0117) | ||||||
Removal of bank | −0.230 *** | −0.232 *** | |||||||
entry barriers | (0.0272) | (0.0276) | |||||||
Constant | −1.181 *** | −1.053 *** | −1.180 *** | −0.955 *** | -0.262 | −1.315 *** | −0.542 ** | −0.640 *** | −0.736 *** |
(0.227) | (0.188) | (0.201) | (0.159) | (0.165) | (0.250) | (0.216) | (0.225) | (0.233) | |
Observations | 423 | 423 | 423 | 423 | 423 | 423 | 423 | 423 | 423 |
Number of countries | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 | 22 |
International Capital Flows | Unreformed | Tightened Regulation | |
---|---|---|---|
Domestic Financial Markets | |||
Unreformed | Scenario I: Permanent increase in financial stress Return to highly-valued shares Continued export and import growth High international capital flows | Scenario III: Moderate reduction in financial stress Moderate reduction or stable share prices Further export and import growth Moderate increase in international capital flows | |
Tightened regulation | Scenario II: Moderate increase in financial stress Stable share prices Slower trade growth Reduced international capital flows | Scenario IV: Permanent reduction in financial stress Lower real share prices Slower growth of world trade Reduction in international capital flows |
Outflows | Output | Real long term | Wage-interest rate | Real share price | Investment growth | Capital | Securities | Prudential | Financial stress | |
(lagged) | gap | interest rate | (yearly change) | (yearly change) | (per cent) | openness | markets | regulation | index (change) | |
Outflows | *** | * | ** | * | *** | *** | * | *** | *** | |
Inflows | Output | Labor force | Total factor productivity | Banking sector | Capital | Securities | Prudential | Financial stress | ||
(lagged) | gap | growth (p.a.) | growth (lagged) | entry barriers | openness | markets | regulation | index (lagged) | ||
Inflows | *** | *** | ** | * | ** | ** | *** | *** | ||
© 2019 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Ernst, E. Finance and Jobs: How Financial Markets and Prudential Regulation Shape Unemployment Dynamics. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2019, 12, 20. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010020
Ernst E. Finance and Jobs: How Financial Markets and Prudential Regulation Shape Unemployment Dynamics. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2019; 12(1):20. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010020
Chicago/Turabian StyleErnst, Ekkehard. 2019. "Finance and Jobs: How Financial Markets and Prudential Regulation Shape Unemployment Dynamics" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 12, no. 1: 20. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010020
APA StyleErnst, E. (2019). Finance and Jobs: How Financial Markets and Prudential Regulation Shape Unemployment Dynamics. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 12(1), 20. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm12010020