1. Introduction
The financial crisis of 2007–2009 generates a significant amount of interest in measuring systemic risk and ensuring the health of the financial system. The most vivid response is the passing of the Dodd-Frank Act. Measuring systemic risk has been at the center of academic research since 2008. For example,
Acharya (
2009),
Acharya et al. (
2012), and
Brownless and Engle (
2016) show that time-varying correlation structure plays a crucial role in their systemic risk measurements and develop an expected shortfall measure approach.
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016) develop a CoVaR approach conditional on financial institutions being in a state of financial distress.
Acemoglu et al. (
2015), and
Elliott et al. (
2014) develop a network approach for systemic risk.
1 While these quantitative and statistical metrics are straightforward to apply, the precise economic channel to which the systemic risk enters the metrics is somewhat lacking. Moreover,
Benoit et al. (
2019) identify several shortcomings in the systemic-risk scoring methodology.
From an insurance equilibrium perspective,
Panttser and Tian (
2013) and
Ivanov (
2017) present a capital insurance approach to address systemic risk and identify
too-big-to-fail (TBTF) banks. Developing a rational expectation equilibrium model of the capital insurance market to address systemic risk was initially proposed in
Kashyap et al. (
2008). In the equilibrium model of capital insurance, a central player (regulator or insurer) sells an insurance product,
capital insurance, on the systemic risk of all banks. The insurer injects the guaranteed capital contingent upon a stressed period, while each bank pays insurance premium upfront in exchange for an
implicit guarantee subsidy. In equilibrium, each bank predicts the optimal insured amount and the insurer determines the optimal pricing structure. As a result, those banks purchasing capital insurance are characterized as TBTF banks under this approach, so TBTF banks are identified endogenously. In characterizing the equilibrium, this approach introduces a new equilibrium-based systemic risk measure,
loss beta.
Compared with numerous systemic risk measures in previous literature, the equilibrium-based systemic risk measure, such as loss beta, is unique since it captures the perspective from all banks together as well as an issuer about each bank’s systemic risk. Moreover, both the implicit guarantee subsidy and TBTF banks are determined endogenously and simultaneously.
2 Since the framework and its pricing structure are motivated by a classical insurance setting, the capital insurance equilibrium is similar to classical insurance equilibrium models such as
Borch (
1962),
Arrow (
1971), and
Raviv (
1979) for a new type of insurance product on the systemic risk. Nevertheless, the strong law of large numbers is no longer satisfied for capital insurance because of the particular correlated feature of systemic risk among banks (
Acharya et al. (
2012) and
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016)).
This paper extends the equilibrium analysis in
Panttser and Tian (
2013) and
Ivanov (
2017) in several theoretical and empirical aspects. First, this paper characterizes the equilibrium for a general class of capital insurance. We focus on identifying TBTF banks, whereas
Panttser and Tian (
2013) study the welfare analysis of capital insurance as a financial innovation. Second, and more importantly, we introduce a new methodology to construct an individual bank’s loss portfolio with systemic risk components consistent with Basel documentations.
3 Building on the deposit insurance model developed in
Diamond and Dybvig (
1983) and
Peck and Shell (
2003), we construct an appropriate loss portfolio with systemic risk exposure by modifying a recent accounting model in
Atkeson et al. (
2019) for commercial banks. Using deposit, loan, equity, and debt together, we construct a loss portfolio in every period and the time series of loss beta for each bank. In contrast, an asset-equity leverage ratio is used in
Ivanov (
2017) to construct the asset loss portfolio, but other specific information for commercial banks is not incorporated. Finally, we implement the proposed approach for U.S. banks and provide a comparison to the previously developed systemic risk measures.
Specifically, there are three significant contributions in this paper.
First, we characterize the equilibrium of general capital insurance for the entire banking sector. This equilibrium model helps us identify TBTF and how much premium TBTF banks should pay upfront to hedge the systemic risk. Since our model is building on the insurance principle, it complements the equilibrium asset-pricing model of systemic risk in
Allen and Gale (
2000). At the same time, since our model focuses on the systemic risk only, we can construct an equilibrium-based systemic risk measure and identify TBTF simultaneously, which is not addressed in
Allen and Gale (
2000).
Second, we propose a new methodology to construct the loss portfolio and use this loss portfolio to develop an equilibrium systemic risk measure—bank loss beta. Given each bank’s loss portfolio, a bank’s loss beta is a ratio of the covariance between a bank’s loss portfolio with the aggregate loss portfolio in the entire banking sector to the variance of the aggregate loss portfolio. The innovation of this methodology is to use all deposit, loan, and equity and debt information that is important to analyze a commercial bank’s systemic risk exposure.
Third, we implement the equilibrium approach for U.S. banks.
4 Using the “Call Report" of all U.S. banks with assets over
$50 billion in each quarter from 2002 to 2019, we identify TBTF banks in each quarter. Our empirical findings suggest highly concentrated TBTF banks in the financial crises period and a significant number of TBTF banks starting from 2019Q1. We also calculate CoVaR simultaneously and find a positive and significant relationship between CoVaR and loss beta for a comparative purpose. As a comparison, we further implement the asset loss beta approach in
Ivanov (
2017) for all institutions with a Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code between 6000 and 6499 and assets over
$50 billion from quarter 1 of 2002 to quarter 2 of 2019. In our empirical findings, both approaches to constructing the loss portfolio generate a reasonably consistent group of TBTF banks during the same period, but the accounting approach covers a much larger group of commercial banks. Overall, the empirical implementation and comparison between these two approaches support the idea of using capital insurance to identify TBTF banks.
The paper contributes to the literature on TBTF banks and identifies such banks through a new equilibrium approach. For instance, in the network approach to systemic risk of
Acemoglu et al. (
2015) and
Elliott et al. (
2014), the connectedness amongst the banks plays a key role. In other words, only the most relevant banks affect a bank’s systemic risk. By contrast, whether one bank is TBTF in our approach relies on
all loss betas of financial institutions in the market. Therefore, the capital insurance approach highlights the
relative weight of loss beta in the whole financial system. In
Acharya et al. (
2012) and
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016), specific distribution-based measures are calculated and sorted, so all banks’ systemic risks are compared with each other. In our approach, we use the loss beta as a criterion to measure and sort the systemic risk, so this approach provides an intuitive and robust way to measure the systemic risk in the spirit of CAPM.
Eisenberg and Noe (
2001) consider each bank’s cash flow and outflow and study the clearing payment to ensure each system member clears the obligation (not default). We also use the deposit, loan, debt, and equity information in our approach, but this information is used to construct a loss portfolio with systemic risk exposure. Instead of examining the clearing payment vector (with a topology method) in
Eisenberg and Noe (
2001), we characterize the equilibrium of systemic risk based on economic and finance principles.
Since we study the appropriate amount of guarantee subsidy in exchange for a government bailout (injection), this paper also complements a recent paper by
Berndt et al. (
2021) on TBTF banks. Statistically speaking, it is impossible to estimate the government bailout probability since Lehman Brothers might be the only large bank that has not been bailed out. Therefore,
Berndt et al. (
2021) develop a structural model to compute a government bailout’s market-implied (
risk-neutral) probabilities, and these authors find a significant post-Lehman reduction in market-implied probabilities of government bailout for both globally systemically important banks (GSIBs) in the U.S. and other large banks that are not large enough to be classified as GSIBs.
5 Kelly et al. (
2016) also demonstrate the collective government guarantee for the financial sector using options data on the financial sector index and individual banks. Because
Kelly et al. (
2016) use the options data, the government guarantee is also interpreted under the risk-neutral probability measure. By contrast, our approach builds on the insurance principle to compute the insurance premium under the
real-world expectation of the loss portfolio. In our approach, we do not estimate the real-world bailout probability directly. However, since the firm should pay a premium to buy insurance from the government in exchange for the government bailout, the capital insurance premium is essentially the
expected bailout amount, a product of the bailout exposure and the bailout probability under the real-world probability measure. Like
Berndt et al. (
2021), we find that the number of TBTF banks gradually decreases post-Lehman until 2019.
6The paper proceeds as follows.
Section 2 introduces a simple accounting model to construct each bank’s loss portfolio with a systemic risk component. In
Section 3, we characterize the capital insurance equilibrium and derive a general property about the loss beta measure. Finally, we report our empirical results in
Section 4, and
Section 5 concludes.
Appendix A presents several properties of general capital insurance.
3. Loss Beta Measure
In this section, we introduce an equilibrium-based loss beta measure of a bank’s systemic risk. We present an equilibrium model of a capital insurance market and characterize TBTF banks in this equilibrium approach. Our classification of TBTF relies on equilibrium-based loss beta measures of all banks simultaneously in the banking system. We further discuss several examples of the loss beta measures.
3.1. An Equilibrium Model
There are
N financial institutions, namely banks, indexed by
, in a financial sector. Each bank is endowed with a loss portfolio (or exposure, and we do not distinguish between these two concepts in this paper),
, respectively. The
aggregate loss portfolio is
While our empirical results are based on the bank loss portfolio introduced in the last section, we highlight that the loss portfolios are merely inputs in the presented equilibrium model.
To hedge the potential loss, each bank decides whether or not to purchase a capital insurance contract from an insurance company, which determines the insurance premium. The insurance contract is written on the aggregate loss portfolio
L instead of individual loss to each bank. Specifically, the payoff of one unit of the insurance payoff is written as
, where
is a continuous monotonic increasing function.
10 Thus, the insurance company and all banks are the market participants in the capital insurance market, in which the equilibrium is obtained if all participants achieve their highest expected utilities, respectively.
Following the standard insurance equilibrium literature (
Arrow (
1971) and
Raviv (
1979)), the insurance premium for each unit is
where
is a load factor that is determined by the issuer. Given the premium structure, each bank
i decides how much insurance to purchase, namely,
, where
, for a premium
accordingly. A bank decides the percentage coefficient
to optimize its expected utility. At the same time, the insurance company determines the load factor, i.e., the premium structure, by the market demand
from each bank
i. Therefore,
are determined in this equilibrium.
Specifically, we assume that each bank is risk-averse, and its risk preference is represented entirely by the mean and the variance of the wealth with the reciprocal of risk aversion parameter
.
11 Given a premium structure
, bank
i solves an optimal portfolio problem by choosing the best coinsurance coefficient:
where
is the
ex post terminal wealth for the bank
i after purchasing the capital insurance and
is the initial wealth of bank
i. Similarly,
represents the
ex ante wealth of bank
i before buying capital insurance.
By the first-order condition in (
7), the optimal coinsurance coefficient for bank
i is given by
The issuer is assumed to be risk-neutral.
12 Therefore, the expected terminal wealth of the issuer is
where
denotes the issuance cost, which can be a fixed cost, a constant percentage of the indemnity or a general function of the indemnity. To focus on the equilibrium analysis of TBTF, we assume that the regulatory cost is a constant for each bank.
Given the optimal demand
for each bank with a load factor
in (
8), the issuer maximizes the expected welfare
. By plugging Equation (
8) into Equation (
9), the issuer’s optimal load factor is derived from the following optimization problem:
and the optimal coinsurance coefficient for each bank
is given by
, where
is the optimal load factor in (
10). As a result, the capital insurance’s payoff for each bank
i,
, relies on both demand (from all banks) and supply (from the regulator) in a rational expectation equilibrium. Both the optimal
and
are determined endogenously. Bank
i is TBTF under the capital insurance
if and only if
.
Equation (
10) is first discussed and solved for particular capital insurance contract in
Panttser and Tian (
2013) and
Ivanov (
2017). We next discuss in detail how to determine TBTF banks in this equilibrium approach for general capital insurance.
3.2. Characterizing TBTF Banks
In this subsection, we characterize the equilibrium for general capital insurance. Our new result is to demonstrate that this approach captures each bank’s systemic risk to some extent (Proposition 1) for a general capital insurance contract.
We first
assume that all banks are TBTF under this approach. Then, Equation (
10) becomes
yielding the optimal load factor
13Since
must be positive, for each
i, the covariance between the loss
with
satisfies
Clearly, if all covariances are sufficiently close so that each of them is greater than the half of their average, the last condition is satisfied, and the optimal load factor is . In particular, if , all banks are TBTF.
From the above analysis, we see that the covariance
provides some insights about the bank’s systemic risk. More importantly, the TBTF concept depends on all covariances
, instead of on individual bank’s loss portfolio. Indeed, by virtue of Equation (
8), bank
i is too-big-to-fail as long as
But the optimal load factor
in (
11) is determined endogenously. The optimal load factor is solved by (
10), and it depends on all loss portfolio information. Even the load factor
depends on all covariance terms
. Therefore, an individual bank’s loss beta is
not sufficient yet to recognize whether it is too big to fail or not; rather, we have to study the entire financial sector as a whole to identify all TBTF banks simultaneously. Briefly speaking, a bank is TBTF only when its covariance with the aggregate loss portfolio is relatively large compared with other banks’ corresponding covariances in the same financial sector.
Therefore, we introduce the loss beta of bank
i with a capital insurance
,
in analyzing systemic risk. We reorder
such that
. We omit those banks with negative or zero loss betas. Clearly,
The total beta of all banks is the beta (regression) coefficient of the aggregate loss portfolio to the indemnity of the capital insurance.
Appendix A presents an algorithm to characterize all TBTF banks. In particular, a bank with high loss beta is TBTF. Conversely, the next result shows that all TBTF banks’s loss betas must be bounded below by
, regardless of the distribution of loss exposure of each bank. Therefore, a TBTF must have a large loss beta, and vice versa to a certain extent. Proposition 1 thus justifies our systemic risk measurement in terms of loss betas.
Proposition 1. For any capital insurance , the loss beta of a TBTF bank must be greater than or equal to .
We present two examples below to illustrate the equilibrium approach to identify TBTF banks.
Example 1. We assume that . The loss portfolios follow a one-factor model, ; billion and , has standard deviation moving from 40% to 12% equally from to , while moves from 4% to 6.8% equally. We also assume that and .
Table 1 represents loss betas,
and the optimal coinsurance
. We note that when
,
for
. Moreover, the first 12 banks are TBTF. The optimal load factor is
. The expected total aggregate loss is
billion. The coinsurance coefficient
increases with respect to the loss beta.
Example 2. Assume that , and any two different banks’ loss portfolios have the same correlation coefficient . for .
Table 2 demonstrates that TBTF banks must have large betas, but the inverse statement is not completely valid. In fact, only the last bank has a small beta, but the first three banks are TBTF banks. Both examples provide a crucial insight into the equilibrium approach. Even though some banks contribute positively to systemic risk and banks are heavily correlated, those banks might still not be TBTF banks, as shown by the last example. The intuition is as follows. By insuring the bank with the most significant systemic risk exposure, other banks’ systemic risks can be insured to some extent. As a consequence, other banks are not TBTF anymore.
3.3. Examples of Loss Beta
In the above equilibrium model of capital insurance, the payoff function (i.e., indemnity of the insurance contract) of the aggregative loss, , is an input element. In this subsection, we provide several examples of loss beta for various payoff functions of the aggregative loss portfolio.
3.3.1. Aggregate Loss Beta
We first specialize the capital insurance-aggregate capital insurance-by assuming that the indemnity, , is the aggregate loss L. It is motivated by the standard coinsurance contract in the insurance market.
Since the loss beta concept depends on the capital insurance contract, we call the loss beta for the aggregate capital insurance an
aggregate loss beta. Clearly, the aggregate loss beta becomes the classical beta in classical portfolio choice literature (See
Hogan and Warren (
1974) and
Bawa and Lindenberg (
1977)),
and the total loss beta,
. If each
, all banks are TBTF. In this case, Proposition 1 is proved in
Ivanov (
2017) that a TBTF bank’s aggregate loss beta is greater than
.
3.3.2. Deductible Loss Beta
In addition to the coinsurance,
as we discuss above, it is natural to consider a deductible capital insurance with payoff
where
M is a deductible level. In other words, the bank does not receive a percentage of the aggregate loss, but receives a percentage of the deductible
. In the insurance literature, this deductible part (loss)
is borne by the bank itself.
Arrow (
1971) shows that the deductible is optimal for the insured under the linear premium principle. The corresponding beta is the deductible loss beta
3.3.3. Cap Loss Beta
If the deductible represents an optimal one for the insured,
Raviv (
1979) finds the optimal one from the insurer’s perspective in classical insurance literature. In a principal-agency setting,
Raviv (
1979) shows that the cap insurance is optimal for the insurer. Therefore, we can also consider a cap capital insurance with the payoff
, and the corresponding loss beta is
Despite the difference among aggregate, deducible, and cap loss beta, the empirical implications are reasonably similar, as shown in
Ivanov (
2017). Therefore, the payoff structure of capital insurance is only second-order, while the construction of the loss portfolio has first-order importance, as will be explained in detail in empirical
Section 4 below.
3.3.4. Other Capital Insurance Contracts
Our equilibrium approach can be applied to a larger class of capital insurance concept. Instead of the aggregate loss portfolio
L, we can consider a general specification in all individual loss such as
where
is a multi-variable function which is increasing with respect to each component. By a similar analysis about multi-claim in
Raviv (
1979) we can show that the payoff structure of the optimal contract must be a function of the aggregate variable
. Therefore, the capital insurance written on the aggregate loss portfolio is an optimal design from the insurance perspective.
However, other specifications of the capital insurance are also plausible. For instance, in their earlier proposal,
Kashyap et al. (
2008) suggest the following specification of the capital insurance for bank
i,
in which this bank’s loss portfolio is excluded. Its intuition is to reduce the asymmetric information effect so the bank has no incentive to misreport the loss information. In a welfare analysis of certain correlated structures of the loss portfolios,
Peck and Shell (
2003) document that this kind of capital insurance is dominated by the capital insurance on the aggregate insurance. Furthermore,
Ivanov (
2017) demonstrates that the moral hazard issue can be resolved effectively by implementing capital insurance. For these reasons, we suggest the specification form
as a capital insurance in studying the systemic risk through this presented insurance approach.
3.4. Analytical Expression of Loss Betas
We examine the loss beta calculation when the loss portfolios are normally distributed. We assume that all P &L portfolios
are represented in a factor model as follows.
in which the factors
, a standard multivariate normal distribution. Each noise,
, is independent from each other, and these noises are independent from all factors. Therefore, the distribution of the individual loss is given by
, and
is truncated and normally distributed. The aggregate loss
. Therefore, the loss beta
can be obtained analytically or well approximated.
3.5. Conditional Loss Betas
At first sight, it is challenging to extend the loss beta concept in a dynamic setting due to the time-inconsistent feature of the mean-variance preference. However, we can consider the capital insurance contract repeatedly, so both the regulator and the financial market monitor systemic risk in a prompt manner. At each period, the existing capital insurance is expired, and the bank updates new loss portfolios. The insurance company issues the capital insurance at each period. Then each bank’s systemic risk is updated, and all TBTF are also updated through the new capital insurance market.
Specifically, we use
to represent the information set at time
t, and the updated loss portfolios at time
t are
. Therefore, the loss beta at time
t is
and the same discussion on (unconditional) loss beta in the previous section can be applied in this situation.
For instance, we consider the same factor model as in the last subsection, and a shock
arrives at time
t. Assume that
has a multivariate normal distribution. Therefore, the conditional P&L variables are
We assume that the covariance-variance matrix of
is
Then, these factors , are multivariate normally distributed conditional on , with mean , and the covariance-variance matrix . Analytical expression of the conditional loss betas follows from the discussion in the last subsection.
3.6. Loss Betas with Tail Risks
Since our equilibrium approach is model-free, any profit and loss portfolio distribution and the loss portfolio can be used.
14 Therefore, we can incorporate tail risk or the skewness in the profit and loss portfolio, particularly for the portfolio with significant derivative positions. Moreover, the correlation structure between these loss portfolios can calibrate the correlated structure in the market.
Specifically, we let
denote the distribution of the loss variable
, and the joint distribution of
is written as
where
is a copula function. Sklar’s theorem states that any joint distribution can be written in this way, so the copula function
measures the correlation structure of the loss variables. In practice, the copula functions can be Gaussian copula and Archimedean copula. Those marginal distributions
can be chosen to capture the tail risk.
The loss beta in this setting can be calculated easily via a simulation method. For instance,
4. Empirical Results
This section takes our model into the data to study the empirical implication of our equilibrium-based measure of systemic risk. Our objective is to identify TBTF banks in the U.S. financial market over the period 2002 to 2019. We first construct the loss portfolio of each bank based on an empirically accessible proxy. Then we calculate the loss beta and identify TBTF banks using the algorithm in
Section 3.
We conduct two approaches in constructing the loss portfolio. In the first approach, we follow the accounting-based methodology introduced in
Section 2. In the second approach, we follow
Ivanov (
2017) to construct the loss portfolio. Moreover, we compare with the CoVaR approach in
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016).
4.1. Data and Sample
In our first approach to construct the loss portfolio, we use data from FFIEC 031 Forms, also called “Call Reports”. FEIEC 031 forms are the forms that every commercial bank or thrift institution must file quarterly, regardless of regulation by the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), or Federal Reserve. FFIEC 031 includes bank deposits, loans, and other bank characteristics of interest.
In our sample, we focus on all commercial U.S.banks with assets over $50 billion, which is the threshold to be classified as Large Banking Organization by the Federal Reserve. Large Banking Organizations are subject to stricter examination for their systemic risk, as evident by an additional layer of examination in annual stress testing. We choose Large Banking Organizations to be in our sample of interest since they are the candidates for higher systemic risk. The final sample contains 2821 bank-quarter observations over 70 quarters, from the first quarter of 2002 to the second quarter of 2019. Since the data panel is unbalanced as banks exit and enter the sample throughout the sample period, there are 67 unique banks in total.
In this section, we compare our loss beta with an established measure of systemic risk, CoVaR.
15 To calculate CoVaR, we extend the measure from
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016) to the second quarter of 2019 based on stock return data from CRSP and macroeconomic variables from the FRED.
16 For tests on the correlation between loss beta and CoVaR, the sample is restricted to public banks since CoVaR requires stock return data that are only available to public firms. We use the CRSP-FRB link provided by the Federal Reserve Bank of New York to merge our loss data measures with the CoVaR measure.
Finally, in our second approach to construct the loss portfolio, we construct the bank’s loss portfolio based on information available in Compustat and CRSP, following
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016) and
Ivanov (
2017). Specifically, we obtain the bank total asset from Compustat and bank total equity from CRSP. Our sample is limited to publicly traded financial institutions only in this approach.
4.2. Bank Loss Beta
Following the model provided in
Section 2, we estimate the bank loss portfolio. From the Call Reports, we gather the book value of the bank’s total loans, the book value of the bank’s total equity, the book value of the bank’s total deposits, and the book value of the bank’s subordinated debt. We use these book values as proxies for the fair value of the loans and deposits, and the market value of the equity and the subordinated debt. Then, we use these book values to calculate each bank’s loss portfolio for each quarter as explained in
Section 2. The aggregate loss portfolio is also calculated for each quarter in the sample period.
Figure A1 shows the histogram of all banks’ loss portfolios by quarter. As shown, the distribution of loss portfolio across all banks is highly skewed. Moreover, the probability of a large loss, such as an over
$800 billion loss, is not marginal, showing a clear tail risk in the banks’ portfolios.
Given all loss portfolios and assuming that
, we compute all aggregate loss betas,
, for each quarter.
Figure A2 reports both mean and the standard deviation of all loss betas for each quarter. Since the total number of banks in our sample is
, the mean of loss beta is close to
. However, we observe a relatively high standard deviation, meaning that some banks have substantial systemic risk components. Therefore, some banks are TBTF and some are not.
TBTF banks are identified in each quarter using the algorithm described in
Appendix A.
Figure A3 reports the number of TBTF in each quarter from 2002 to 2019. The number of TBTF is time-varying. For example, there are 9 TBTF in 2004, then the number gradually decreases. During the 2007–2008 financial crisis period, there are 3–5 TBTF, but each TBTF’s systemic risk is substantial. As shown in
Acharya et al. (
2012), 5 firms provide 50% of the entire systemic risk in the U.S. financial markets, and 15 firms account for 92% of the systemic risk. This highly concentrated feature of TBTF banks is thus consistent with
Acharya et al. (
2012). This finding is also confirmed by the second empirical approach below.
Table 3 reports all TBTF in a particular quarter. No bank is TBTF for the whole sample period, but four banks are TBTF the vast majority of the time. Not surprisingly, those banks are the “Big Four”—Bank of America, JP Morgan Chase, Wells Fargo, and Citibank. From the start of the data in 2001, the number of TBTF banks declined steadily even before the crisis, dropping to just three TBTF banks in the fourth quarter of 2008 (JP Morgan Chase, Bank of America, and Citibank). Interestingly, Wachovia is identified as TBTF over the period 2007 Q4 to 2008 Q3. The number of TBTF banks stayed low until 2014, when BNY Mellon, State Street, and Capital One briefly joined the Big Four before abruptly falling out after 2015. The number of TBTF banks reached a sample low of two (Bank of America and Wells Fargo) TBTF banks from 2017Q2 to 2018Q1, before rapidly expanding to 2019Q2, with a sample high of 11 banks.
4.3. Comparison between Loss Beta and CoVaR
As a comparison, we implement the CoVaR methodology in
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016). We calculate CoVaR for each quarter in the same time period.
Figure A4 reports mean and standard deviation (SD) of CoVaR in each quarter.
Table 4 reports summary statistics of bank assets, loss portfolios, loss beta, TBTF, and CoVaR. Bank assets are from Call Reports.
We also take a step further by running panel regressions of loss beta with respect to CoVaR.
Table 5 reports the regression coefficients and statistical significance. The number of sample is slightly different, reducing from 2824 to 2018, because the stocks of some of the banks in the Call Report are not publicly traded.
Table 5 show a positive and significant relationship between Loss Beta and CoVaR. The magnitude decreases once we control for quarter fixed effect and a bank-specific characteristic, total assets. As shown in
Table 5, loss beta is positively correlated with an established systemic risk measure, CoVaR, and captures some additional aspects of systemic risk.
4.4. Alternative Approach: Asset Loss Beta
In this subsection, we present the result of loss beta using an alternative approach. Specifically, we calculate the loss beta using the total asset from Compustat and total equity from CRSP, in the spirit of
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016). This approach was implemented in
Ivanov (
2017) for 14 big financial institutions between 2004 to 2012.
17 For a comparison purpose, we extend
Ivanov (
2017) to include all institutions with a Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) code between 6000 and 6499 and assets over
$50 billion from quarter 1 of 2002 to quarter 2 of 2019. This sample has significant overlap from our banking loss portfolio, in particular, the publicly traded Large Banking Organization. It includes financial institutions that are not banks, such as insurance companies and securities brokers and dealers.
18 To distinguish, we name the loss beta in this approach as “asset loss beta”, whereas the first one is “bank loss beta”. Our purpose is to identify TBTF banks in this period with the asset loss beta and present the effect of loss portfolio input to the identification of TBTF banks. In particular, we explain that the bank loss beta might be more appropriate for commercial banks.
In this alternative approach, we estimate the key input parameters in this approach as follows. For each financial institution i. Let
: the leverage ratio of institution i at time t, the ratio of total asset value over the total equity value;
: the market capitalization of institution i at time t;
: the profit and loss of institution i at time t, that is, ;
: the loss portfolio of institution i at time t, that is, .
Table 6 shows the TBTF financial institutions identified using this alternative approach. Among the TBTF are traditional large commercial banks, such as JP Morgan Chase, Bank of America, Citigroup, and Wells Fargo, large investment banks such as Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs, and large insurance firms like American International (AIG) and Metlife. Interestingly, AIG, Wachovia, and Countrywide Financial were identified as TBTF financial institutions before they were bankrupt or acquired. Specifically,
Table 6 identifies Countrywide Financial as TBTF in the third quarter of 2007, but this firm was not considered in
Ivanov (
2017). We also notice that American Express, which is missing in
Ivanov (
2017), is identified as a TBTF in 2001Q1–2003Q2 and 2004Q1–2005Q4.
Table 6 provides additional empirical evidence on the validity of our measure.
Compared with
Ivanov (
2017), the identified TBTF banks are relatively similar even though our dataset contains significantly more financial institutions than
Ivanov (
2017). We also find that the Big Four commercial banks—Bank of America, Citigroup, JP Morgan Chase, and Wells Fargo—are identified as TBTF since 2008. In addition, Morgan Stanley and Goldman Sachs are also consistently identified as TBTF after 2014.
A comparison of bank loss beta with asset loss beta yields interesting results. Asset loss beta can identify non-bank financial firms that are TBTF, such as AIG and Metlfie, or the large investment banks before they reorganized in 2008. However, asset loss beta fails to take into account any firms that are not publicly traded. Since bank loss beta relies on only banks’ data, it cannot identify non-bank financial institutions as TBTF. However, bank loss beta has the benefit of identifying TBTF regardless of the public status of the firm. It also identifies more banks as TBTF than the asset loss beta measure. Moreover, it is convenient from a policy perspective as banks fall under the same regulatory structure, unlike other non-bank financial institutions.
Table 3 identifies TBTF institutions using bank loss beta, and
Table 6 uses asset loss beta. The findings are slightly different even when only looking at banks. Both approaches are fairly consistent in identifying the largest commercial banks, such as Bank of America, JP Morgan Chase, Citigroup, Wachovia, and Wells Fargo, as TBTF. However, the bank loss beta, by not taking into consideration non-bank financial institutions, is more informative within the banking sector as it much more consistently and frequently identifies relatively smaller banks as TBTF, such as Bank One, Fleet National, US Bank, and Suntrust as TBTF before the 2008 Financial Crisis, and BNY Mellon and State Street after the crisis, and even Capital One, Charles Schwab, Ally, and TD Bank in the most recent quarters of the data sample. Notably, in the most recent quarter 2019Q2, using asset loss beta, only 6 institutions, Bank of America, Citigroup, JP Morgan Chase, Morgan Stanley, Goldman Sachs, and Wells Fargo, were TBTF. However, using bank loss beta, 11 institutions are TBTF, the six under asset loss beta, and Capital One, Charles Schwab, Ally, TD Bank, and American Express. Overall, the bank loss beta provides a more consistent and frequent signal that a commercial bank should be considered TBTF.
5. Conclusions
In this paper, we provide an equilibrium approach based on economic theories to measure the systemic risk of financial institutions and identify TBTF financial intermediaries such as banks, insurance companies, or other types of intermediaries. This paper sheds light on why and how financial crises such as the 2007–2009 form and grow in magnitude. The recent episode of Covid-19 also sparks considerable interests on the systemic risk due to unexpected shocks. By constructing each financial intermediary’s expected loss portfolio in a recent accounting model, we suggest a capital-based insurance approach to address the systemic risk that is crucial to the health of the entire financial market. We derive a systemic risk measure, termed loss beta, in a characterization of the capital-based insurance equilibrium. We perform a comprehensive empirical implication and document U.S. TBTF financial intermediaries from 2002 to 2019. We demonstrate a time-series pattern of U.S. TBTF financial intermediaries, and a significant number of TBTF banks starting from 2019.
Compared with previous literature on systemic risk, our approach relies on an insurance equilibrium in which all banks with systemic risk exposures and a regulator with implicit guarantee obligation maximize expected utility separably. Previous important studies such as
Acharya et al. (
2012),
Billio et al. (
2012) and
Adrian and Brunnermeier (
2016) introduce some statistical measures that are easy to apply, but these measures are mostly constructed exogenously. On the other hand, other measures that provide specific channels such as liquidity mismatching or consumer/real property risk require future data, which is impossible to implement ex-ante. Our proposed approach advances the literature by providing a forward-looking systemic risk measure with an insurance equilibrium approach to determine the TBTF financial intermediaries endogenously. Moreover, since we develop this approach in an insurance framework, this approach can also be helpful to estimate the expected bailout and bailout probability under the real-world probability measure.
Our results have policy implications and practical appeals. First, the implementation of this approach is straightforward. By using a loss portfolio for each bank (provided by each bank or constructed by the regulator), the regulator can calculate each bank’s loss beta and identify TBTF banks with a simple algorithm in this conceptual framework. Second, the regulator is allowed to choose capital insurance contracts in the framework. In this way, various loss betas can be used to check the robustness of a bank’s systemic risk. Third, the regulator can use the capital insurance premium to assess the implied guarantee subsidy or another type of capital for TBTF banks. Finally, through the analysis of the loss portfolio, the bank can reduce the systemic risk exposure with this approach.
According to our theoretical and empirical study, a loss portfolio is a crucial input in our approach and affects the identification of TBTF banks. However, the construction of a loss portfolio is far from unique. While we suggest some accounting-based or asset-based methods, constructing the most appropriate loss portfolio with systemic risk exposure is not resolved yet. In other words, we need to understand which bank factors/characteristics contribute to the systemic risk before constricting the loss portfolio, and there are many studies in the literature to identify those factors. This paper only compares the loss beta approach with CoVaR, but it is also essential to compare it with numerous other systemic risk measures to understand the loss beta measure better. More importantly, we do not consider the availability of this approach to other regions, particularly European banks. We leave these topics to a future study.