A Comparative Study of Pricing Mechanisms to Reduce Side-Payments in the Electricity Market: A Case Study for South Korea
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- Marginal-cost pricing: This is the pricing mechanism generally adopted in most of the existing electricity markets. The market price is determined only by marginal costs, and discriminate side-payments are paid to generators that suffer financial losses due to the quasi-fixed costs or for other reasons.
- SMP in the Korean CBP market [12]: It is a method of calculating the market price by adding no-load and start-up costs to marginal costs.
- Convex hull pricing [9]: This mechanism was originally formulated as the Lagrangian dual problem, which cannot guarantee the polynomial time convergence. So, we adopt the primal formulation, which is one of the most actively studied methods recently that can guarantee the polynomial time convergence.
- The ELMP mechanism of the US MISO market [13]: This is a pricing mechanism that can be considered an approximation of convex hull pricing, which decomposes convex hull pricing into each hour by ignoring inter-temporal constraints. This method allows FSRs to set prices, and reduces side-payments, by adding their commitment costs (no-load and start-up costs) to the market price.
- Uniform Vickrey pricing: This is a pricing mechanism based on the Vickrey auction concept [14]. This method determines the market price at an incremental cost of the runner-up generator (the generator that is one rank higher than the marginal generator in the merit-order). The market price increases slightly compared to marginal-cost pricing, which enables generators to recover some of the quasi-fixed costs, and reduces side-payments.
2. Pricing Mechanisms
2.1. Side-Payments in the Electricity Market
2.2. SMP in the Korean CBP Market
2.3. Convex Hull Pricing
2.4. ELMP in MISO Market
2.5. Vickrey Pricing in a Uniform-Price Market
3. Case Study
3.1. Description of the Simulation Study
3.2. Assumptions
3.2.1. Pricing Schemes
- Marginal-cost price: the marginal price is calculated from the value of the dual multiplier of the supply-and-demand balance equation of the UCED problem;
- System Marginal Price: SMP is calculated with Equation (3) using the results of the UCED problem;
- Convex hull price: Convex hull price is derived from the dual multiplier in Equation (6). In order to derive a convex hull price, it is necessary to construct the convex hull of the feasible set. The primal formulation in Section 2.3 derives convex hull prices in the absence of ramping constraints, which can be seen as the lower bound of exact convex hull prices considering ramping constraints. Considering the current status of research on convex hull pricing, it is realistic to not consider ramping constraints, as suggested by Hua and Baldick [5]. Therefore, ramping constraints are not considered in this study. However, in practice, ignoring the ramping constraints does not cause a significant error because most of the peak generators that determine the market prices can ramp their outputs up or down between the minimum and the maximum limits within an hour;
- Extended Locational Marginal Price: ELMP is derived from the dual multiplier in Equation (14). Before determining ELMP, however, it is needed to specify qualified generators. ELMP Phase I, introduced in 2015, designated generators with a minimum run time of less than one hour and a start-up notification time of less than 10 min as FSRs. This tight control resulted in a very limited number of generators being included in the FSRs. In order to broaden the benefits of the ELMP mechanism, MISO initiated ELMP Phase II in 2017, which eases FSR eligibility to on-line generators with both the minimum run time and a start-up time of less than one hour [33]. In general, as the number of qualified generators increases, the market price tends to rise. It was judged that the eligibility of an FSR should not be defined based on a specific theoretical background, but arbitrarily determined to maintain the market price at an appropriate level. Hence, in order to properly introduce the ELMP method in a specific electricity market, it should be decided which generators will be qualified considering the specific market conditions and policies. In this study, the following two cases were considered as qualifications for generators in the Korean electricity market.
- (1)
- ELMP(a): all generators for which MWPs are to be paid when marginal-cost pricing is qualified.
- (2)
- ELMP(b): if the marginal generator for each hour of the UCED problem is CCGT, this generator is qualified.
- 5
- Vickrey price: the Vickrey price is calculated using Equation (18).
3.2.2. Financial Analysis
3.3. Simulation Results
3.4. Discussions
4. Conclusions
- The SMP mechanism currently applied to the Korean electricity market has the smallest side-payments amounts, but the price regressivity problem prevents new modern market elements (such as demand-response) from entering the electricity market. The SMP mechanism can be a good option when the market price is too low, and it is necessary to improve the profits of generation companies.
- The convex hull pricing mechanism minimizes LOCs, and the settlement costs of an electricity sales company seem to be the lowest from among the alternative pricing models. Although the pricing mechanism needs to be modified to reduce side-payments, it is a good option if you do not want to significantly increase the profits of power generation companies.
- The ELMP mechanism variants show slightly different results according to the qualification requirements of the fast-start resources that are subject to partial commitment in the pricing process. The most distinctive feature is that market prices tend to rise relatively higher during high-demand periods than during low-demand periods. Hence, it is a good option if you want to selectively increase the profits of peak generators rather than baseload generators.
- The Vickrey pricing mechanism tends to be the opposite of the ELMP mechanism. Market prices under Vickrey pricing tend to rise relatively higher during low-demand periods than during high-demand periods. Hence, it is a good option if you want to selectively increase the profits of baseload generators rather than peak generators.
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Schweppe, F.C.; Caramanis, M.C.; Tabors, R.D.; Bohn, R.E. Spot Pricing of Electricity; Kluwer Academic Publishers: Dordrecht, The Netherlands, 2000. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, C.; Luh, P.B.; Gribik, P.; Peng, T.; Zhang, L. Commitment Cost Allocation of Fast-Start Units for Approximate Extended Locational Marginal Prices. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2016, 31, 4176–4184. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vazquez, C.; Hallack, M.; Vazquez, M. Price computation in electricity auctions with complex rules: An analysis of investment signals. Energy Policy 2017, 105, 550–561. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hytowitz, R.B.; Frew, B.; Stephen, G.; Ela, E.; Singhal, N.; Bloom, A.; Lau, J.; Hytowitz, R.B.; Frew, B.; Stephen, G.; et al. Impacts of Price Formation Efforts Considering High Renewable Penetration Levels and System Resource Adequacy Targets Impacts of Price Formation Efforts Considering High Renewable Penetration Levels and System Resource Adequacy Targets. Natl. Renew. Energy Lab. 2020, NREL/TP-6A. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hua, B.; Baldick, R. A Convex Primal Formulation for Convex Hull Pricing. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2017, 32, 3814–3823. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Schiro, D.A.; Zheng, T.; Zhao, F.; Litvinov, E. Convex Hull Pricing in Electricity Markets: Formulation, Analysis, and Implementation Challenges. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2016, 31, 4068–4075. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kim, M.Y.; Cho, S.B. The Influence of Excluding No-load Cost from SMP on Cost Reduction Incentive of Generators. Environ. Resour. Econ. Rev. 2014, 23, 617–641. (In Korean) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- FERC. Docket No. AD14-14-000 Price Formation in Energy and Ancillary Services Markets Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators; Federal Energy Regulatory Committee: Washington, DC, USA, 2015.
- Gribik, P.R.; Hogan, W.W.; Pope, S.L. Market-Clearing Electricity Prices and Energy Uplift; Harvard Electricity Policy Group Working Paper; Harvard Electricity Policy Group: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2007; pp. 1–46. [Google Scholar]
- FERC. Docket No. RM17-3-000 Fast-Start Pricing in Markets Operated by Regional Transmission Organizations and Independent System Operators; Federal Energy Regulatory Committee: Washington, DC, USA, 2016.
- Moon, K.S. Alternatives and Improvements of the Trading mechanism in Korean Electricity Market. Ph.D. Thesis, Graduate School of Konkuk University, Seoul, Korea, 2015. (In Korean). [Google Scholar]
- Hyun Kim, T.; Shin, H.; Kim, W.; Cho, K.; Lee, S. Consideration of a Combined Cycle Gas Turbine’s Operating Modes in Pricing Mechanisms: A Korean Electricity Market Study. J. Electr. Eng. Technol. 2019, 14, 1919–1931. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- MISO Business Practices Manual Energy and Operating Reserve Markets Attachment B Day-Ahead Energy and Operating Reserve Market Software Formulations and Business Logic 2018. Available online: https://www.misoenergy.org/legal/business-practice-manuals/ (accessed on 8 June 2021).
- Vickrey, W. Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders Export Find Similar. J. Financ. 1961, 16, 8–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rothkopf, M.H.; Teisberg, T.J.; Kahn, E.P. Why Are Vickrey Auctions Rare? J. Political Econ. 1990, 98, 94–109. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Morey, M.J. Power Market Auction Design: Rules and Lessons in Market Based Control for the New Electricity Industry; Edison Electric Institute: Washington, DC, USA, 2001; pp. 1–86. [Google Scholar]
- Song, Y.H.; Kim, H.J.; Kim, S.W.; Jin, Y.G.; Yoon, Y.T. How to find a reasonable energy transition strategy in Korea?: Quantitative analysis based on power market simulation. Energy Policy 2018, 119, 396–409. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Andrianesis, P.; Liberopoulos, G.; Kozanidis, G.; Papalexopoulos, A.D. Recovery mechanisms in day-ahead electricity markets with non-convexities-Part II: Implementation and numerical evaluation. IEEE Trans. Power Syst. 2013, 28, 969–977. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- KPX. A Study on How to Reflect Demand Response Resources in the Korean CBP; KPX: Jeollanam-do, Korea, 2014; pp. 1–197. (In Korean) [Google Scholar]
- Chen, Y. MISO Market Design Overview and Evolution; MISO, 2019. Available online: https://curent.utk.edu/industry/seminar-series/yonghong-chen/ (accessed on 8 June 2021).
- Ausubel, L.M.; Milgrom, P. The Lovely but Lonely Vickrey Auction. Comb. Auction. 2006, 17, 22–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fabra, N.; Von Der Fehr, N.-H.; Harbord, D. Designing Electricity Auctions: Uniform, Discriminatory and Vickrey. In Proceedings of the First Conference on Wholesale Markets for Electricity, Toulouse, France, 22–23 November 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Hobbs, B.F.; Rothkopf, M.H.; Hyde, L.C.; O’Neill, R.P. Evaluation of a Truthful Revelation Auction in the Context of Energy Markets with Nonconcave Benefits. J. Regul. Econ. 2000, 18, 5–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liao, Z.; Sugianto, L.F. A Comparative Study on Pricing Rules and Its Effect on Total Dispatch Cost. Procedia Comput. Sci. 2011, 6, 505–510. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Sessa, P.G.; Walton, N.; Kamgarpour, M. Exploring the Vickrey-Clarke-Groves Mechanism for Electricity Markets. IFAC-PapersOnLine 2017, 50, 189–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- O’Mahoney, A.; Denny, E. Electricity prices and generator behaviour in gross pool electricity markets. Energy Policy 2013, 63, 628–637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kim, H.; Kim, S.S. The resource adequacy scheme in the Korean electricity market. Energy Policy 2012, 47, 133–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- KPX Korea Power Exchange Homepage. Available online: http://www.kpx.or.kr/ (accessed on 3 May 2021). (In Korean).
- KPX. Status of Power Generation Facilities in 2015; KPX: Jeollanam-do, Korea, 2016; pp. 1–325. (In Korean) [Google Scholar]
- KPX. Status of Power Generation Facilities in 2016; KPX: Jeollanam-do, Korea, 2017; pp. 1–340. (In Korean) [Google Scholar]
- KPX. Status of Power Generation Facilities in 2017; KPX: Jeollanam-do, Korea, 2018; pp. 1–352. (In Korean) [Google Scholar]
- Rosenthal, R.E. GAMS—A User’s Guide; GAMS Development Corporation: Washington DC, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- MISO Staff. ELMP III White Paper I: R&D report and Design Recommendation on Short-Term Enhancements. 2019. Available online: https://cdn.misoenergy.org/20190117 MSC Item 05 ELMP III Whitepaper315878.pdf (accessed on 8 June 2021).
- Borowski, P.F. Zonal and Nodal Models of Energy Market in European Union. Energies 2020, 13, 4182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Poyrazoglu, G. Determination of Price Zones during Transition from Uniform to Zonal Electricity Market: A Case Study for Turkey. Energies 2021, 14, 1014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
2015 | 2016 | 2017 | |
---|---|---|---|
Peak demand (MW) | 73,550 | 79,940 | 82,090 |
Annual consumption (GWh) | 493,310 | 509,122 | 518,443 |
Installed capacity (MW) | 97,688 | 104,238 | 110,937 |
Power Source | 2015 | 2016 | 2017 | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Installed capacity (MW) | Nuclear | 22,205 | 23,582 | 23,687 |
Coal | 27,094 | 30,450 | 33,997 | |
Combined cycle gas turbine | 38,745 | 40,707 | 45,056 | |
Oil | 2908 | 2761 | 2720 | |
Combined heat and power plant | 401 | 403 | 403 | |
Installed capacity (MW) | Nuclear | 2176 | 2304 | 2387 |
Coal | 18,557 | 17,155 | 24,272 | |
Combined cycle gas turbine | 81,830 | 54,450 | 56,882 | |
Oil | 73,581 | 37,734 | 46,713 | |
Combined heat and power plant | 78,364 | 57,279 | 53,253 | |
Installed capacity (MW) | Nuclear | 60 | 50 | 42 |
Coal | 41 | 32 | 31 | |
Combined cycle gas turbine | 34 | 30 | 27 | |
Oil | 38 | 42 | 25 | |
Combined heat and power plant | 38 | 29 | 34 |
Pricing Scheme | 2015 | Rate of Change | 2016 | Rate of Change | 2017 | Rate of Change | Average | Average Change |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
SMP (base) | 97.07 | 70.44 | 74.02 | 80.51 | ||||
Marginal price | 92.50 | −4.7% | 66.30 | −5.9% | 68.43 | −7.6% | 75.74 | −5.9% |
Convex hull price | 95.20 | −1.9% | 68.55 | −2.7% | 70.93 | −4.2% | 78.23 | −2.8% |
ELMP(a) | 98.27 | 1.2% | 72.04 | 2.3% | 76.02 | 2.7% | 82.11 | 2.0% |
ELMP(b) | 96.72 | −0.4% | 69.53 | −1.3% | 72.40 | −2.2% | 79.55 | −1.2% |
Vickrey price | 101.17 | 4.2% | 74.84 | 6.3% | 79.05 | 6.8% | 85.02 | 5.6% |
Year | Pricing Scheme | Power Purchase Cost | Side-Payment | Total Settlement Cost | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
MWP | LOC | ||||
2015 | SMP | 458,560 | 12 | 295 | 458,571 |
Marginal price | 437,774 (−4.53%) | 563 | 793 | 438,337 (−4.41%) | |
Convex hull price | 449,771 (−1.92%) | 18 | 114 | 449,790 (−1.91%) | |
ELMP(a) | 464,304 (1.25%) | 13 | 400 | 464,316 (1.25%) | |
ELMP(b) | 456,977 (−0.35%) | 44 | 309 | 457,021 (−0.34%) | |
Vickrey price | 477,570(4.15%) | 137 | 1373 | 477,707 (4.17%) | |
2016 | SMP | 341,883 | 7 | 338 | 341,890 |
Marginal price | 322,550 (−5.65%) | 503 | 661 | 323,054 (−5.51%) | |
Convex hull price | 332,762 (−2.67%) | 15 | 96 | 332,777 (−2.67%) | |
ELMP(a) | 349,748 (2.30%) | 9 | 330 | 349,757 (2.30%) | |
ELMP(b) | 337,553 (−1.27%) | 31 | 266 | 337,584 (−1.26%) | |
Vickrey price | 362,841 (6.13%) | 79 | 1706 | 362,920 (6.15%) | |
2017 | SMP | 363,805 | 14 | 565 | 363,819 |
Marginal price | 337,956 (−7.11%) | 693 | 865 | 338,649 (−6.92%) | |
Convex hull price | 348,664 (−4.16%) | 20 | 120 | 348,684 (−4.16%) | |
ELMP(a) | 373,805 (2.75%) | 15 | 386 | 373,820 (2.75%) | |
ELMP(b) | 355,930 (−2.16%) | 68 | 338 | 355,998 (−2.15%) | |
Vickrey price | 388,108 (6.68%) | 98 | 2346 | 388,206 (6.70%) |
Year | Pricing Scheme | Total Plant Profit | Base-Load Plant Profit | CCGT Plant Profit | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Nuclear | Coal | ||||
2015 | SMP | 284,712 | 152,896 | 122,829 | 8070 |
Marginal price | 264,413 (−7.1%) | 145,285 (−5.0%) | 113,344 (−7.7%) | 5067 (−37.2%) | |
Convex hull price | 275,935 (−3.1%) | 149,591 (−2.2%) | 118,743 (−3.3%) | 6779 (−16.0%) | |
ELMP(a) | 290,456 (2.0%) | 154,409 (1.0%) | 124,871 (1.7%) | 10,225 (26.7%) | |
ELMP(b) | 283,157 (−0.5%) | 152,037 (−0.6%) | 121,873 (−0.8%) | 8345 (3.4%) | |
Vickrey price | 303,844 (6.7%) | 162,178 (6.1%) | 133,244 (8.5%) | 7477 (−7.3%) | |
2016 | SMP | 198,694 | 116,546 | 76,761 | 4079 |
Marginal price | 179,806 (−9.5%) | 109,088 (−6.4%) | 67,589 (−11.9%) | 2140 (−47.5%) | |
Convex hull price | 189,583 (−4.6%) | 112,864 (−3.2%) | 72,329 (−5.8%) | 3227 (−20.9%) | |
ELMP(a) | 206,562 (4.0%) | 118,794 (1.9%) | 79,788 (3.9%) | 6475 (58.7%) | |
ELMP(b) | 194,386 (−2.2%) | 114,558 (−1.7%) | 74,490 (−3.0%) | 4064 (−0.4%) | |
Vickrey price | 219,723 (10.6%) | 126,514 (8.6%) | 88,145 (14.8%) | 3753 (−8.0%) | |
2017 | SMP | 193,783 | 124,177 | 63,489 | 6108 |
Marginal price | 168,496 (−13.0%) | 114,319 (−7.9%) | 50,488 (−20.5%) | 3685 (−39.7%) | |
Convex hull price | 178,650 (−7.8%) | 118,121 (−4.9%) | 55,733 (−12.2%) | 4792 (−21.5%) | |
ELMP(a) | 203,784 (5.2%) | 126,698 (2.0%) | 67,867 (6.9%) | 9206 (50.7%) | |
ELMP(b) | 185,959 (−4.0%) | 120,603 (−2.9%) | 59,314 (−6.6%) | 6038 (−1.1%) | |
Vickrey price | 218,170 (12.6%) | 135,574 (9.2%) | 76,582 (20.6%) | 6009 (−1.6%) |
Pricing Scheme | High Demand | Low Demand |
---|---|---|
SMP | 86.47 | 57.93 |
Marginal price | 80.53 (−5.94%) | 52.70 (−5.23%) |
Convex hull price | 83.93 (−2.54%) | 54.02 (−3.92%) |
ELMP(a) | 92.59 (6.12%) | 54.57 (−3.36%) |
ELMP(b) | 86.79 (0.32%) | 53.83 (−4.11%) |
Vickrey price | 86.90 (0.43%) | 69.53 (11.59%) |
Pricing Scheme | Pros | Cons |
---|---|---|
Marginal price | theoretically safe (marginal-cost pricing) lowest total settlement costs | higher side-payments lowest profits |
SMP | lowest MWPs stable margin for peak generators | excessive profits for base-load generators price regressivity problem |
Convex hull price | lowest LOCs lower total settlement costs increase with demand | lower profits ramping constraints are ignored |
ELMP | lower side-payments higher profit for peak generators | additional research is required to decide appropriate qualified generator groups |
Vickrey price | a straightforward methodology extra inframarginal rents for peak generators | highest LOCs affected by the distribution of fuel cost levels |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Shin, H.; Kim, T.H.; Kwag, K.; Kim, W. A Comparative Study of Pricing Mechanisms to Reduce Side-Payments in the Electricity Market: A Case Study for South Korea. Energies 2021, 14, 3395. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123395
Shin H, Kim TH, Kwag K, Kim W. A Comparative Study of Pricing Mechanisms to Reduce Side-Payments in the Electricity Market: A Case Study for South Korea. Energies. 2021; 14(12):3395. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123395
Chicago/Turabian StyleShin, Hansol, Tae Hyun Kim, Kyuhyeong Kwag, and Wook Kim. 2021. "A Comparative Study of Pricing Mechanisms to Reduce Side-Payments in the Electricity Market: A Case Study for South Korea" Energies 14, no. 12: 3395. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123395
APA StyleShin, H., Kim, T. H., Kwag, K., & Kim, W. (2021). A Comparative Study of Pricing Mechanisms to Reduce Side-Payments in the Electricity Market: A Case Study for South Korea. Energies, 14(12), 3395. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14123395