Next Article in Journal
Estimation of State of Charge for Two Types of Lithium-Ion Batteries by Nonlinear Predictive Filter for Electric Vehicles
Next Article in Special Issue
Investors’ Perspectives on Barriers to the Deployment of Renewable Energy Sources in Chile
Previous Article in Journal
Sustainability Assessment of the Agricultural and Energy Systems of Senegal
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Impact of a Carbon Tax on the Chilean Electricity Generation Sector
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

China’s Low-Carbon Scenario Analysis of CO2 Mitigation Measures towards 2050 Using a Hybrid AIM/CGE Model

1
Department of Economics and Management, North China Electric Power University, No. 619 Yonghua Street, Baoding 071003, Hebei, China
2
Philosophy and Social Science Research Base of Hebei Province, North China Electric Power University, Baoding 071003, Hebei, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2015, 8(5), 3529-3555; https://doi.org/10.3390/en8053529
Submission received: 20 January 2015 / Revised: 20 April 2015 / Accepted: 20 April 2015 / Published: 27 April 2015
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Energy Policy and Climate Change)

Abstract

:
China’s emissions continue to rise rapidly in line with its mounting energy consumption, which puts considerable pressure on China to meet its emission reductioncommitments. This paper assesses the impacts of CO2 mitigation measures in China during the period from 2010 to 2050 by using a computable general equilibrium method, called AIM/CGE. Results show that renewable energy makes a critical difference in abating emissions during the period from 2010 to 2020. The scenarios with emission trading would drive more emission reductions, whereby the emission-cutting commitment for 2020 would be achieved and emission reductions in 2050 would be more than 57.90%. Meanwhile, the share of non-fossil energy increases significantly and would be more than doubled in 2050 compared with the BAU scenario. A carbon tax would result in a significant decline in emissions in the short term, but would have an adverse effect on economic growth and energy structure improvements. It is also observed that the integrated measures would not only substantially decrease the total emissions, but also improve the energy structure.

1. Introduction

There is a growing awareness that global climate change caused by the increase in greenhouse gas emissions into the biosphere is one of the main challenges in the 21st century. In order to meet the challenge of global climate change and to achieve energy-environment-economy development, the building of a low carbon society is a priority in the national development strategies of many countries. The concept of a low carbon society concerns all aspects of the society, including economy, culture and life [1]. The European Union (EU) has officially declared that it would cut emissions by at least 80% by 2050 [2]. Meanwhile, the U.S. and Japan have also made it clear that substantial investment in clean energy development is expected to prompt the reduction of CO2 emissions by 80% in 2050 compared with those in 2005 [3]. Developing countries represented by the BRICS nations (Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa) have also expressed a strong willingness to control emissions, while putting forward their own specific plans or programs for emission mitigation. According to China’s decarbonisation roadmap, the emissions per unit of gross domestic product (GDP) are required to be reduced by 40% to 45% compared with those in 2005, and renewable energy consumption should account for 15% of the total by 2020 [4]. However, China’s emissions are more likely to continue rising rapidly in line with its ongoing industrialization and urbanization, which will result in more energy consumption [5], hence, China will face tremendous challenges in achieving its mitigation targets provided effective measures are not taken. In response, the Chinese central government has made unremitting efforts towards exploring mitigation policies and other measures.
In the context of pursuing climate policy targets for 2020, a number of studies are underway to deeply probe different emission abatement policies and assess the corresponding compliance costs. Economists exceptionally value market-based climate management tools, to strive to minimize the economic costs in realizing the given emission reduction goals, and to provide dynamic incentives for long-term development of cheaper abatement technologies. The legislative package is designed to curb carbon emissions and to maintain low-cost abatement incentives in which carbon renewable, taxes and emission trading may all play a prominent role.
There is evidence that a broader set of energy and climate policies must be implemented to lower the abatement costs as much as possible. Research on imposing duties on carbon emissions has been done in the past few decades, mainly to identify the right tax rate that would help reduce carbon emissions with the lowest adverse impact on economic operations, and consequently alleviate climate change [6,7,8]. Emission trading is the most important regulatory instrument that makes emission allowances obligatory for CO2 emissions from electricity generation as well as energy-intensive industries [9,10,11]. There is extensive literature on emission reduction targets, possible mitigation policies and costs in developed countries [12,13], but few studies are focused on the impacts of energy and climate policies in the context of emission mitigation in China. Undoubtedly, it is very necessary to quantitatively assess the potential results of the deployment of mitigation policies to reach the objective of impacting both the national economy and the energy mix to a large extent. Impact assessments of emission reduction commitments and non-fossil energy target plans for 2020, have been performed in [5,14].
Currently, renewable energy, considered as the main way to achieve energy savings and emission cuts, will see a substantial expansion over the next several decades. Subsequently, under a reasonable policy guidance for key economic sectors, technological changes will have great economic implications through improving energy efficiency whilst reducing the reliance on fossil fuels and cutting emission intensity [15]. Different from the carbon market in developed countries, an absolute cap on emissions needs to be set in China, which is eventually to be implemented by the different sectors and enterprises. Both carbon taxes and ET encourage enterprises to mitigate emissions in the production process by means of market forces. It is expected that timely introduction of a carbon tax from 2015 to 2020 which will achieve its impact through price measures will curb mounting emissions, while emission trading, a cap mechanism based on market competition, provides cost-effective and flexible environmental compliance for energy systems.
Increases of carbon emissions and their possible negative effects are major concerns in the imposition of any policy strategy [16]. Considering that climate policies including renewable energy plans, carbon taxes and emission trading are particularly helpful to combat climate change, it is very necessary to investigate the implications of alternative climate policies on economic and social development, so as to consequently provide policy recommendations for the state.
In recent years, as a popular policy simulation tool, computable general equilibrium (CGE) models have been widely employed in the analysis of climate policy, in particular, the assessment of long-term effects on economic consequences, sector productivity and energy systems [14,17,18]. This study aimed to provide an in-depth analysis of these mitigation measures, especially the impacts of renewable energy, ET and carbon taxes, on economic development, sectoral output, energy systems, etc. by establishing a new and revised hybrid static Asia-Pacific Integrated Model/computable general equilibrium (AIM/CGE) model.
The analysis is organized as follows: Section 2 briefly describes the AIM/CGE model and design scenarios. Section 3 presents the acquired simulation results, including the impacts of mitigation commitment on GDP, sectoral output, energy supply, and energy consumption by sectors and by types, energy intensity, carbon intensity and carbon prices and the impacts of different time levels to cancel the electricity price subsidies, increasing carbon taxes and limited emission trading. Finally, the results are summarized in brief, which also shows the useful policy implications of the study.

2. Methodology

2.1. AIM/CGE Model

The AIM/CGE model was developed by the National Institute for Environmental Studies (NIES), Japan. The AIM/CGE model is a recursive dynamic model, used to investigate the influence of climate policy at both the global [19,20] and country levels [21,22].
In this study, based on the “Standard CGE model”, an improved AIM/CGE model is established to evaluate the impact of China’s climate commitments, incorporating alternative energies and climate policies. The structure of China’s AIM/CGE is approximately the same as that of the standard version [23]. It consists of four parts: production block, income block, expenditure block and market block. The present version of AIM/CGE is shown in Figure 1.
Figure 1. Overview of China’s AIM/CGE model structure (for one region).
Figure 1. Overview of China’s AIM/CGE model structure (for one region).
Energies 08 03529 g001

2.1.1. Production Block

In the standard AIM/CGE model, the default classification has 19 non-energy sectors and 19 energy sectors. In this model, in consideration of the study purpose and convenience, the sector classifications are disaggregated to 24 sectors, including 17 non-energy sectors and seven energy sectors. There are three basic types of inputs, including intermediate commodities, energy commodities and primary factors of capital and labor, regardless of land. It is assumed that the labor and capital are fully employed, perfectly competitive and freely mobile. The aggregation of intermediate commodities is in Leontief form while the composite of energy is a constant elasticity of substitution (CES) aggregation of fossil fuel (the bundle of six kinds of primary energy) and electricity. For the specific value of elasticity of substitution for inputs and outputs, see [5]. The following mathematical terms describes the production module at the lowest level:
F i = A i f [ k = 1 8 α k , i E C k , i σ f , i 1 σ f , i ] σ f , i σ f , i 1
where eight kinds of energies, including coal, coke, crude oil, gasoline, kerosene, diesel, fuel oil, and natural gas, with the sum of share coefficients being 1. Moreover, produced emissions owing to the consumption of fossil energy would be calculated as follows:
E M i = k = 1 8 c k E C i , k
At the second level, the CES function represents the substitution possibilities between the demand for aggregation of fossil fuels and electricity as well as the value added composite of capital and labor:
E i = A i e [ α F , i F i σ E , i 1 σ E , i + ( 1 α F , i ) E L i σ E , i 1 σ E , i ] σ E , i σ E , i 1
K L i = A i k l [ α L , i K i σ K L , i 1 σ K L , i + ( 1 α L , i ) L i σ K L , i 1 σ K L , i ] σ K L , i σ K L , i 1
Subsequently, the value-add and energy aggregates a value added energy bundle with the CES composite, subject to a constant elasticity of substitution σ K L E :
K L E i = A i k l e [ α K L E , i K L i σ K L E , i 1 σ K L E , i + ( 1 α K L E , i ) E i σ K L E , i 1 σ K L E , i ] σ K L E , i σ K L E , i 1
However, the composite of intermediate inputs trades off with the production function of Leontief forms with a fixed proportion of input factors, which is different from others:
M i = j = 1 m α i , j X i , j
At the last level, the output comes from a CES nesting indicating the demand of sectors for value-added energy bundle and intermediate products:
Q i = A i q [ α K L E M , i K L E i σ K L E M , i 1 σ K L E M , i + ( 1 α K L E M , i ) M i σ K L E M , i 1 σ K L E M , i ] σ K L E M , i σ K L E M , i 1

2.1.2. Income Block

The income module consists of three sectors, namely, households, government and enterprises. The representative household acquires income from the rental of basic factors and the lump-sum transfer from the government and enterprises. The enterprises or corporations mainly derive their income from capital income and lump-sum transfers from the government. The government collects its earning mainly from various taxes, including carbon taxes and uses the income to purchase commodities for its consumption and for transfers to other institutions. This block mainly describes the income allocation and distribution. The equations below give an excellent description of the earnings that institutions acquire:
Y h = i = 1 24 W i L i + r i H K + β T R g o v ¯ + T R e n t ¯
Y e n t = i = 1 24 r i K i + γ T R g o v ¯
Y g o v = i 24 ( τ i P i Q i ) + τ r Y h + τ e n t Y e n t + T A R I F F + T A X c a r b o n
It must be pointed out that institutions, including households and enterprises, should pay the carbon tax based on their CO2 emissions, seen in Figure 1. The CO2 emissions by each sector and household are estimated according to their fossil energy consumption. In the basic model version, the revenues are assumed to be received by the households. However, in this model, the revenues collected through carbon taxes are distributed to households and enterprises in the form of temporary tax cuts and transfer payments. Meanwhile, the returns are consistent with the calculation of confirmed taxable income rate, respectively. This study ignores the impact of carbon tax on households and focuses on the impact on sectors.
In this study, we follow the assumption that direct taxes and transfers to other domestic institutions are defined as fixed shares in the basic model version. In addition, the assumption of the balance of government financial revenues and expenditure is applied in this model. The taxation tariffs are also an important tax revenue and a control means for the central government. Products brought into one country are often subject to import taxes, or customs duties. Accordingly, imports are controlled by the adjustment of customs duty rates.

2.1.3. Expenditure Block

The expenditure block describes household expenditures, government spending and capital formation, whose final consumption is goods. The income of the representative household is spent on commodities or investments. It is natural that households intend to maximize commodity utility, which is subject to the constraints of income and prices. In terms of investment, household expenditures are assumed to grow linearly at the same pace as the GDP growth rate. Government spending and capital formation is assumed as a constant coefficient function. Both purchases and transfer of the government are introduced as an exogenous variable, so that the consuming quantity is fixed.

2.1.4. Market Block

The market block represents the process of commodity trading. Domestic commodities are disaggregated into domestic and export markets. Based on the Armington assumption, the aggregation of domestically produced and imported commodities with an imperfect substitute supplies the domestic market, derived on the assumption that domestic demanders minimize cost. The derived demands for imported commodities are met by international supplies that are infinitely elastic at given world prices. The import prices paid by domestic demanders also include import tariffs (at fixed ad valorem rates) and the cost of a fixed quantity of transactions services per import unit, covering the cost of moving the commodity from the border to the demander. Similarly, the derived demand for domestic output is met by domestic suppliers. The key difference with the standard version is that certified emission reductions (CERs) are regarded as a commodity in this model. We are working on the assumption that CERs are a commodity produced by enterprises. The amount of CERs owned by enterprises is determined by the emissions gap between the limits set by the government and the real value. The CERs can be traded in the carbon market. The carbon market demands are for a composite commodity made up of imports and domestic output. Developers of emission reduction projects act as a buyer transacting the entity of emissions reduction at a lower cost.
The AIM/CGE model treats the volume of all commodities as monetary units. Domestic energy sectors produce energy commodities and ensure supplies if not imported. The energy sectors in this study are classified into seven kinds. In the basic version, the share of imported and domestic consumption is determined by the ratio of the current price to the previous year’s price. In this study, we solve the CES aggregation function to find the optimal value. The Equations (11)–(14) show how the optimal allocation of all commodities including energy between the imports and domestic supply:
Q C l = A l a m [ α m , l Q M l σ m , l + ( 1 α m , l ) Q A M l σ m , l ] 1 σ m , l
P M l P A M l = α m , l ( 1 α m , l ) ( Q A M l Q M l ) 1 σ m , l
P C l Q C l = P M l Q M l + P A M l Q A M l
P M l = ( 1 + τ m , l ) p w m l ¯ E X R ¯

2.2. Dataset

The dataset used in this model includes the 2005 input-output table [24], energy balance table [25], and CO2 emission factors of fossil fuels [26]. The year of 2005 is thus used as a base year. In this study, we use a single country social accounting matrix (SAM) which covers the typical sectors. The SAM in 2005 in this model is from the prolonged input-output table. In China’s input output table, petroleum and natural gas are treated as one sector, the disaggregation of which in this study is done by using the consumption information of petroleum and natural gas among sectors in the energy balance table. The SAM describes physical volume transaction data as physical unit volumes. The volume of energy consumption is calculated based on the monetary volume transaction data and the energy price in the base year.
In the CGE model, energy consumption is commonly treated as a monetary term. However, in this paper, energy consumption is discussed in physical terms. Data from the energy balance table in 2010 is used to turn monetary terms into physical counterparts. SAM is formulated based on the energy balance table, whose balance is adjusted by a cross-entropy method [27]. Relevant coefficients include carbon emission factors and elasticity of substitution. It is assumed that the annual GDP growth rate is 7.5% from 2011 to 2015 in accordance with the policy guidance [28]. For the total GDP and growth rate after 2015, we refer to [29]. The current population growth rate in China is slow. If the total fertility rate is held at 1.8, the population in China will reach a peak of 1500 million persons around 2033, but then drop to 1383 million in 2050 [30]. Consequently, the annual growth rate of population can be roughly calculated (see Table 1).
Table 1. GDP and population growth.
Table 1. GDP and population growth.
YearGDPPopulation
2005 (base year)Billion USD2903.75Million persons1307.56
2006–2010Growth rate9.57%Growth rate0.80%
2011–20157.50%0.61%
2016–20206.15%0.61%
2021–20255.82%0.14%
2026–20305.50%0.12%
2031–20355.20%−0.08%
2036–20404.90%−0.13%
2041–20454.61%−0.33%
2046–20503.05%−0.52%
The labor grows at exactly the same rate as population change. The capital stock is dynamically determined by the previous year’s stock, capital formation and depreciation. The relevant data are based on [31]. The efficiency coefficients in the CES energy and value-added function, known as the total factor productivity (TFP), stand for the technology status. The efficiency coefficients change autonomously at 1.5% per year in agriculture, construction and the service sector. However, the efficiency coefficients in the industrial sector are determined by labor and capital stocks and will be calculated every year [14]. The direct subsidies to the production of renewable electricity are used to assess the impact of the renewable plan. The feed-in tariff and subsidy rate for the renewable during the study period are displayed in Table 2 [15].
Table 2. The feed-in tariff and subsidy rate for the renewable during the study period.
Table 2. The feed-in tariff and subsidy rate for the renewable during the study period.
Renewable electricityRenewable electricity feed-in tariff (Yuan/kwh)Fossil fuel electricity sale price (Yuan/kwh)Subsidy rate (%)
Wind0.550.4038
Solar0.95-138
Biomass0.75-88
Looking ahead, the non-fossil energy share is predicted to be at 11.4% in 2015 and 15% in 2020, the specific target of which is shown in Figure 2 [32]. The total CO2 trading volume is likely to exceed 24 million tons this year, which will surge to about 227 million tons in 2015, nearly nine times higher than the current level. Furthermore, the implementation of subsidies for renewable electricity will occur between 2010 and 2020, and possibly be phased out in 2020, referring to the corresponding data [15].
Figure 2. Published situation and targets for installed capacity of renewable energy towards 2015 and 2020 in China.
Figure 2. Published situation and targets for installed capacity of renewable energy towards 2015 and 2020 in China.
Energies 08 03529 g002

2.3. CO2 Mitigation Scenarios

In this paper, a total of 11 scenarios are analyzed to investigate the impacts of three key policy measures. In the business as usual (BAU) scenario, it is assumed that the three CO2 mitigation countermeasures or policies have not been introduced during the study phase. The GDP growth and population change follow the assumptions of Table 1. In addition, some variables including labor productivity changes, energy efficiency and capital productivity improvement are introduced to indicate technical progress and the corresponding values refer to [5]. The fossil fuel consumption from 2010 to 2050 is adopted from [33]. The other ten scenarios are designed to assess the impacts of policy combinations in fulfilling CO2 mitigation commitments in contrast to the BAU scenario by using the AIM/CGE model. China has made an ambitious commitment to cut down its carbon dioxide emissions of GDP per unit from 40% to 45% by 2020 compared with that in 2005. Accordingly, all scenarios are divided into CM40 and CM50, which are roughly consistent with the national mitigation targets, i.e., 40% and 50% reduction of the total CO2 emissions. In this paper, all sectors should cut their emissions by 40% or 50%, respectively, compared with those in 2005. The CO2 emissions come from the fossil energy consumption when enterprises produce their products. All sectors should take emission reduction into account and then decide the appropriate activity level. The CO2 emissions will restrict the activity level as an exogenous variable. Since laws and regulations promoting the development of renewable energy were formulated in 2006, all scenarios have included the renewable energy, excluding the BAU scenario. The National Development and Reform Commission (2014) announced that a carbon market would probably be launched during 2016–2020 [34]. Considering the stage and uncertainty of this policy implementation, it is estimated that emission trading will be established throughout the country in 2016. A carbon tax is to be collected by 2020. When the national emission trading market is started in 2016, CERs transactions will be conducted freely on a global scale. In this study, carbon tax rate is designed as a constant, and always remains at 5 $/t. The “E”, “T”, and “C” in the end of scenario names mean renewable energy, emission trading and carbon tax, respectively. For example, the emission trading policy will be taken into account in the CM40ET, CM40ECT, CM50ET and CM50ECT scenarios. Detailed information about all scenarios is shown in Table 3.
Table 3. CO2 emission reduction measures in all scenarios.
Table 3. CO2 emission reduction measures in all scenarios.
ScenarioReduction level (%)Renewable energyEmission tradingCarbon tax
0%40%50%
BAU+
CM40+
CM50+
CM40E++
CM50E++
CM40ET+++
CM40EC+++
CM50ET+++
CM50EC+++
CM40ETC++++
CM50ETC++++
Note: “+” indicates the given scenario containing the appropriate policy and “−” indicates that corresponding measure is not considered.

3. Simulation Results

Our model allows us to assess the impacts of emission mitigation measures on macroeconomics, sector output, energy system and carbon prices. The results of each scenario are presented under the background of three alternative mitigation policies to support the exploration of China’s future mitigation strategy.

3.1. Carbon Intensity

3.1.1. Carbon Intensity in This Model

China’s sky-rocketing energy consumption causes high emissions. The current situation shows that emission mitigation is relatively difficult. Nevertheless, China’s government has made an ambiguous commitment to lower emissions per unit of GDP from 40% to 45% compared with those in 2005. Over the past five years, the total CO2 emissions have increased from 5170 million tons in 2005 to 8332 million tons in 2010, a 61.16% rise. In terms of emissions for GDP per unit from 2005 to 2010, they only dropped from 1.36 to 1.29 tons per 1000 US dollars (t/1000 USD, a 5.14% drop) meaning that there are enormous pressures in achieving reduction targets.
Results of CO2 emission intensity during 2020–2050 are illustrated in Figure 3. It is shown that CO2 emission intensity changes significantly after the deployment of renewable energy, a drop of 33.33% in CM40E and 36.43% in CM50E by 2020, respectively, compared with 1.36 t/1000 USD in 2005. On the basis of renewable energy, emission trading will reduce emission intensity by 43.31% in CM40ET and 46.53% in CM50ET by 2020, which obviously shows a high probability of achieving China’s CO2 emission mitigation target commitments made in Copenhagen.
The CO2 emissions in the BAU scenario remain on a downward trend, but the value in 2050 is apparently higher than that in other scenarios. The carbon intensity is less than 0.70 t/1000 USD in the scenarios with renewable energy and emission trading, which means that the targets proposed in Copenhagen are achievable. It is apparent that the carbon tax overwhelmingly contributes to lower carbon emissions when implemented. However, the effect of emission trading measures on emission intensity reduction obviously surpasses that of the carbon tax. Besides, the impacts of carbon tax on reducing emission intensity work in the short term, for example, the annual average rate of decrease of emission intensity is 1.1%–1.4% in CM40EC, CM40ETC, CM50EC, and CM50ETC during 2020–2030, while it is only 0.2%–0.5% during 2030–2050. In the short run, energy intensive enterprises have to reduce their production to fulfill the emission reductions in the face of the absolute increase in production costs because fixed costs remain constant and the introduction of new technology or switching to other production may be unrealistic. Therefore, the emission reduction and carbon intensity drop are obvious. However, in the long run, introduced low carbon technology and turning over to other sector makes the carbon tax less efficient. Moreover, energy efficient enterprises lack any motivation to reduce emissions because they pay lower carbon taxes. Hence, the carbon intensity would not sink rapidly in the long term.
Figure 3. CO2 emission intensity from 2020 to 2050.
Figure 3. CO2 emission intensity from 2020 to 2050.
Energies 08 03529 g003
In contrast, the emission intensity in scenarios without a carbon tax falls steadily during the research period. The estimated value of emission intensity falls to 0.54 t/1000 USD in CM40ET and 0.52 t/1000 USD in CM50ET, respectively, by 2050. The CM50ECT scenario sees roughly the same effect as CM50ET.

3.1.2. Renewable Energy Subsidies and Carbon Intensity

In the early stages, the development of renewable energy is faced with immense difficulties due to the high costs. Given that renewable energy plays a key role in the development of any national energy strategy, most advanced countries and regions have established appropriate capital subsidy mechanisms. As the largest developing country, China has adopted effective measures to support the development of renewable energy, mainly including renewable energy feed-in tariffs. The continuing financial support for promoting the development of renewable energy will unquestionably increase the government’s financial burden. The tariff subsidies are estimated to be 16.7 billion dollars in 2015 and 25.3 billion dollars in 2020. Tariff subsidies are predictably eliminated based on the renewable energy development trend. Nevertheless, a sober assessment is needed to establish the best specific time to cancel subsidies.
In this study, diverse temporal patterns are used to assess the impacts when the government removes its tariff subsidies at different times. It is assumed that subsidies are removed in 2015, 2020 and 2025, respectively. It shows a marked comparison of carbon intensity in 2050 after removing the tariff subsidies at different times. Results reveal that the early cancellation of subsidies in 2015 curbs carbon intensity reduction in the future, while the abolition of subsidies in 2025 makes little difference. The following reasons may provide a general understanding of this phenomenon. Although the cost of renewable energy is higher than that of fossil energy, renewable energy is the major means to reduce the emissions before 2015. Over the ten years, the development cost of renewable energy has dropped by more than 50%, in particular, the cost of photovoltaic power generation has decreased by 15% every year. The renewable electricity will be cheaper after 2015, which could be acceptable for some enterprises. However, the thermal power generation cost in China is likely to rise because of the increasing coal price. Moreover, in order to achieve the mitigation goals, enterprises are bound to use renewable energy even if it is more expensive because it is still cheaper than the introduction of new technology.
By comparing the scenario of removing subsidies in 2020 with that in 2025, it is found that the margin of carbon intensity reduction in all reduction measures is less than 0.2 t/1000 USD. In other words, the result coincides with experts’ predictions that after 2020, the removal of subsidies is relatively appropriate at least from the perspective of reducing carbon emissions.

3.1.3. Limited Emission Trading and Carbon Intensity

Free emission trading implies that no trade credit and scope will be captive. However, emission trading may be restricted to a certain level. China’s enterprises will be in trouble in free emission trading with other countries, such as the EU, stemming from the gap of production technology. China’s enterprises are always at a disadvantage in market competition due to their technical level. In order to protect domestic firms, limited emission trading may play an important role in accelerating the development of native industries. Therefore, it is significant to explore the impacts of trade constraints on activity level and mitigation.
After a comprehensive analysis and calculation, results convincingly indicate the inappropriate expectations. For protectionist reasons, 50% of the trade is merely restricted to domestic sources but this is unable to produce the desired effect, and worse still, it prevents sectors from raising the level of output. Protectionism prevents enthusiasm for innovation, but is conducive to production technology development. The decline in GDP reaches 1.3% compared with that in the free trade level, unwilling to address this aspect, which means sector activity will be undoubtedly affected, partly due to the technical gap. Surprisingly, carbon emission intensity is not affected much by the carbon taxes deployed in the CM40ETC and CM50ETC scenarios, compared with the average increase of 0.15 t/1000 USD in other scenarios. Obviously, the emission trading for limiting the amount of the transaction does not lower the carbon emission intensity as expected, and instead it causes some adverse effects on economic development and technological progress.

3.1.4. Increasing Carbon Tax and Carbon Intensity

In this study, the carbon tax rate is held at 5 $/t for simplicity sake, however, it is changeable in the practical economic and social context based on the government policies. Therefore, in this section, the carbon tax rate is assumed to increase from 2 $/t to 10 $/t within a decade, after which it remains unchanged and consistent with the current policy direction. The output in the industrial sector accounts for a large proportion of the GDP. As expected, a carbon tax inevitably has an adverse impact on the activity level in the industrial sector. However, the effects of carbon tax can be significantly reduced if a lower tax rate is followed initially in accordance with the deployment of government norms. In addition, the increase of marginal abatement costs is less pronounced. A lower carbon tax serves as a guide in improving the production technology and energy efficiency to some extent. With the increase of tax rate, enterprises will shoulder the pressure of reducing the energy consumption per unit of output to meet the cost increases due to energy consumption.
Simulation results indicate CO2 emission intensity changes with the carbon tax rate gradually increasing from 2 $/t to 10 $/t according to the hypothesis. Compared with fixed rates, incrementing the tax rate contributes to a more substantial reduction in carbon emissions and the consequential drop in carbon intensity. From a practical point of view, higher carbon tax indeed can greatly reduce carbon emissions instead of carbon intensity. Based on the simulation results, emission intensity will see a big decline in CM50EC and CM50ETC, reducing to 0.51 t/1000 USD in CM50ETC, a drop of 0.2 t/1000 USD, however, a higher carbon tax rate has a huge impact on China’s GDP. At the carbon tax rate of 10 $/t, the GDP loss in CM40EC and CM50EC reaches 3.47% and 5.06%, respectively.

3.2. CO2 Mitigation and CO2 Prices

CO2 prices are changeable with the increase of imposed CO2 emission constraints, as presented in Table 4. In the CM40 and CM50 scenarios, it is assumed that carbon emissions per unit of GDP are reduced by 40% and 50%. The CO2 prices in 2050 are consistent with emissions reduction.
Table 4. Carbon prices and the corresponding CO2 mitigation.
Table 4. Carbon prices and the corresponding CO2 mitigation.
ScenariosCO2 mitigation (%)Carbon prices USD/t-CO2
CM404051.6
CM505067.9
CM40E56.698.1
CM50E59.6118.2
CM40ET61.0143.4
CM40EC61.892.8
CM50ET58.8138.4
CM50EC60.7100.8
CM40ETC57.984.75
CM50ETC60.5110.2
This occurs in the scenarios with renewable energy policies, i.e., the CM40E and CM50E, in which CO2 prices are much higher than those in the CM40 and CM50 scenarios. The reason is that higher emission reduction constraints result in higher cost of CO2 mitigation procedures and high carbon prices. The CO2 price is the most significant driving force of emission reduction. Therefore, higher prices help to drive more CO2 emission reduction.
Emission trading results in high CO2 prices and encourages more emission reductions. Emission trading brings about the highest CO2 prices in the CM40ET and CM50ET scenarios. In the CM40ET scenario, the carbon emission reduction level is higher than that in the CM50ET, but with nearly the same CO2 price. The key reason is that the relationship between the CERs supply and its price roughly shows an inverted U-shaped curve. When the CERs price is lower, the price increase will result in more CERs supply. The price of CERs is unlikely to go up unboundedly. Too high a CERs price is uneconomic or unacceptable for enterprises. In this case, the enterprises prefer to pay the penalty for uncompleted emissions reduction rather than take the initiative in mitigating the emissions. When all enterprises achieve their optimal reductions based on profit function, they lose the desire to cut the emissions unless the CERs prices fall. If not, mitigation target could not be achieved. Therefore, only a depressed CERs price would drive more emissions reduction. Therefore, it is possible that a certain price corresponds to two different emission reduction scenarios.
It can be seen that the carbon price in CM40E and CM50E is higher than that in CM40 and CM50. Generally, more renewable energy should reduce the demand for carbon permits and reduce their price. However, renewable energy availability promotes the output growth in sectors compared with mandatory emission reductions. The emissions increase due to production expansion is more than the decrease due to the use of renewable energy. In fact, the CO2 emissions in the scenarios with renewable energy are relatively higher than in the mandatory reduction scenario, which would drive the rise of carbon price.

3.3. Macroeconomic Impacts

Deployment of emission mitigation policies will inevitably exert a far-reaching influence on Chinese macroeconomic operation. Mandatory carbon emission reduction requirements are equivalent to imposing carbon emission constraints on the macroeconomics. As a result, economic operation costs will increase, and economic agents will make necessary adjustments to concepts, technologies, business models and even consumption patterns. Affected by this mechanism, the government as organizers and managers have assigned emission limits to the enterprises. This would limit how much CO2 can be emitted in production activities. The enterprises will be penalized for excessive emissions, which may severely disrupt production. Therefore, enterprises are bound to adjust their production plans or introduce low-carbon technology to meet the emission targets, which would raise the product price as likely as not. Besides, the decrease of fossil energy consumption is probably inevitable due to the law of conservation of carbon. The energy consumers must spend time to understand and find alternative energy sources. In this study, we focus on the direct influence on the yield of all sectors. By definition, the GDP would be calculated according to the output level and fixed base year price. Reasonable mechanism of emission reduction is helpful for promoting technological innovation and industrial upgrading, and attracting more investments, which contributes to the improvement of the trading environment, particularly for developing countries.
GDP is deemed to be changeable in line with the implementation of mitigation policies, which is usually used as the indicator of evaluating the economic impacts. Table 5 shows the effect of mitigation policies on GDP growth under the corresponding targets. Compared with the BAU scenario, cumulative GDP loss in 2020 is relatively mild in the CM40 and CM50 scenarios, i.e., 2.54% in CM40 and 3.52% in CM50, respectively. Higher GDP loss in CM50 shows that when a higher mitigation target is set, the loss of GDP will increase greatly due to the rapid expansion of marginal abatement costs. However, economic costs are relatively lower in the short run under the emission reduction scenario, which is ascribed to constant progress in technology and the improvement of labor productivity. However, GDP in CM40 and CM50 shows a considerably different growth rate in 2050. The loss of cumulative GDP is 3.61% in CM40, while a larger loss of 6.91% occurs in CM50, indicating that mandatory emission reductions will have substantial influence in the long run. This is probably due to an unreasonable adjustment of industry structure caused by exceeding emission reductions that makes economic growth flabby.
Table 5. GDP losses due to CO2 mitigation policies (%).
Table 5. GDP losses due to CO2 mitigation policies (%).
YearEmission reduction scenarios
CM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
2010−0.83−1.53−1.22−1.47−1.22−1.47−1.22−1.47−1.22−1.47
2015−1.53−2.01−1.65−1.83−1.65−1.83−1.65−1.83−1.65−1.83
2020−2.54−3.52−2.11−2.12−1.82−1.92−2.11−2.12−1.82−1.92
2025−2.73−3.85−2.23−2.36−1.87−2.16−2.48−3.11−2.19−2.54
2030−3.25−4.50−2.36−2.58−1.95−2.35−2.81−3.54−2.37−2.82
2040−3.42−5.42−2.49−2.71−2.11−2.51−2.96−4.07−2.52−3.10
2050−3.61−6.91−2.57−2.79−2.23−2.60−3.09−4.85−2.63−3.41
Note: The value of GDP is estimated based on commodity prices in 2005.
Expansion of renewable energy use plays an absolutely critical role in cutting emissions during the period from 2010 to 2020. However, it would have an adverse effect on GDP growth. As shown in Table 5, the measurable cumulative reduction of GDP is about 1.53% in CM40E, and 2.79% in CM50E by 2050. This is mainly because developing renewable energy sources is more costly than fossil energy in the short run. Moreover, the government will invest much in developing it. All these efforts increase the economic operation costs. However, in the long run, the costs will fall because of technology maturity and renewable energy will become as cheap as fossil energy. The relatively abundant energy decreases the cost of activity level, and consequently, boosts the economy.
Emission trading, expected to be fully implemented in 2016, significantly promotes economic growth. Table 5 shows that from 2015, the GDP cumulative loss compared with the BAU scenario has been continuously declining as time goes on. However, from 2018 in CM40ET and 2033 in CM50ET, GDP starts to exceed the BAU scenario, ultimately up to 1.85% in CM40ET and 1.04% in CM50ET compared to the BAU scenario by 2050. This gives rise to accumulative total GDP growth of 1.44% in CM40ET and 0.98% in CM50ET. Compared with CM40E and CM50E, the GDP loss in CM40ET and CM50ET is also lower. Under emission trading policy, CERs would be regarded as a kind of good to trade. According to the assumption and the definition of GDP, the GDP would increase compared with the scenarios without emission trading and this situation will continue.
A carbon tax means increasing the revenue for the government, which is stored before serving as production subsidies in various sectors. A carbon tax adversely affects the GDP in the short-term, leading to a large gap of 0.9% in CM40EC compared with CM40E in 2025. Energy costs in all sectors would increase if a carbon tax is introduced, which lowers the activity level in sectors and suppresses GDP growth. The analysis shows that the trend of GDP growth rates with carbon tax in the scenarios of 50% CO2 mitigation is similar to that in CM40EC, the difference is that the GDP loss in CM50EC is much greater. In addition, the negative impacts of carbon tax on GDP decline in the long run. Table 5 shows that in CM40EC, CM50EC, CM40ETC and CM50ETC, the GDP loss continues to decline from 2020 to 2050, which shows that the impact of a carbon tax weakens gradually. Carbon taxes have an adverse impact on industrial structure optimization, which impedes economic development. Especially in the short term, the impact of carbon tax on economic growth is heavy. In the long run, the enterprises have enough time to decide where the money is going and then manufacture and expand the activity level. As a result, the impact of carbon tax is weakened. Comparatively speaking, emission trading have a positive impact which constantly drives GDP growth. On the contrary, the impact of carbon tax is negative and is significant in the short term.
We prefer to lower the GDP loss as much as possible when carrying out mitigation measures. In 2050, a GDP loss above 3% is seen in CM40, CM50, CM40EC, CM50EC and CM50ETC. However, in the scenario of BAU, GDP growth is assumed to be 3.05% in 2050. The above scenarios probably result in economy stagnation or negative growth and are unreasonable. A lower GDP loss is enjoyed in CM40E, CM40ET and CM40ETC. For this reason the above three policy combinations are acceptable.
Table 6. Change of activity level in various scenarios in 2050 compared with BAU (%).
Table 6. Change of activity level in various scenarios in 2050 compared with BAU (%).
SectorsScenarios
CM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
Agriculture0.853.891.024.211.254.311.064.361.054.19
Mineral mining−0.42−2.63−0.38−2.44−0.34−2.01−0.42−2.65−0.39−2.43
Foods and Tobacco0.815.260.965.321.006.470.995.380.945.61
Textiles and clothing0.42.230.512.650.673.210.522.450.532.64
Wood and furniture0.351.980.432.330.652.860.472.450.482.41
Paper products−0.08−0.64−0.06−0.54−0.05−0.45−0.08−0.62−0.07−0.56
Chemical−0.32−1.85−0.25−1.52−0.18−1.34−0.32−1.79−0.27−1.63
Cement−0.93−3.05−0.76−2.54−0.72−2.43−0.88−3.11−0.82−2.78
Non-metallic Mineral Products−0.30−1.67−0.22−1.54−0.16−1.41−0.28−1.98−0.25−1.65
Iron and steel−1.06−4.66−0.94−3.59−0.88−3.31−1.26−4.58−1.04−4.04
Nonferrous products−0.56−2.06−0.43−1.68−0.39−1.56−0.55−2.31−0.48−1.90
Water production0.220.860.321.020.361.250.391.080.321.05
Machinery−0.35−2.34−0.32−2.14−0.26−2.04−0.35−2.38−0.32−2.23
Other manufacturing0.120.960.150.980.181.250.890.150.340.84
Construction0.02−0.050.05−0.030.080.010.03−0.050.05−0.03
Transportation−0.21−0.65−0.16−0.47−0.16−0.36−0.12−0.42−0.16−0.48
Service sector0.20.780.351.140.461.450.381.320.351.17

3.4. Non-Energy Sector Output Impacts

The integrated policy of promoting emission reductions has different impacts at the sectoral level. With the mitigation measures being introduced, energy intensive enterprises will be faced with increased costs and shrinking profits [35]. Energy costs increases have an important impact on activity levels. The activity level in energy-intensive sectors, such as steelmaking, and cement production shall suffer the most (Table 6). For instance, the output in the steel sector drops by 1.06% and 4.66% in the CM40 and CM50 scenarios, respectively, suffering severely from mandatory emission reductions, followed by the cement sector with a decline in output by 0.93% in CM40 and 3.05% in CM50, respectively. The decrease of activity level means that CO2 emissions from production will fall consequently.
The carbon tax increases enterprises’ production costs due to the raising prices of fossil energy, which suppresses the activity level. The feed-in subsidies make renewable energy competitive in the energy market. Renewable energy becomes an significant force to drive the fossil energy price drop. Consequently, the production costs in all sectors will decline due to the deployment of renewable energy sources. The decline of production costs helps increase production, in particular for the energy-intensive industries such as the power, steel, chemical and transport sectors because the expenditures on energy use account for a large part of their total costs [15,36]. Under an emission trading mechanism, enterprises don’t need to follow the specified emissions limits strictly and pay heavy penalties for excessive emissions. The emissions gap would be offset by purchasing CERs at lower cost. Compared with the mandatory emission reduction scenario, the production costs will fall when emissions exceed the limits. The enterprises can rearrange their production schedules and expand the production to obtain greater profits, therefore, emission trading would improve the activity level.
Nevertheless, Table 6 shows that mitigation measures cannot significantly alleviate the decline in output level. First, the implementation of a carbon tax increases the production costs both in the short term and long term, in particular to energy intensive sectors. The increased costs with hamper the production expansion. Second, renewable energy is more favored than fossil energy. Due to government feed-in tariff subsidies, the price of renewable electricity will be reduced which will make renewable energy highly competitive. However, given the assumption of subsidy removal in 2020, this high competitiveness would decrease. In addition renewable energy is in short supply and cannot fully meet the demand. Consequently, the motivation for energy intensive sectors is limited. Third, under a carbon trading mechanism, enterprises need to purchase CERs in the carbon market which increases their total production costs. Although the enterprises are able to meet emission reduction quotas, they cannot expand their production unconditionally due to the emission limits and only do so if the government forecasts their output and allocates reasonable emissions. Unfortunately, the carbon trading would then become meaningless.
Energy efficient sectors, including the service, agriculture and food industry shall enjoy a drastic increase. The energy costs accounts for a small share of costs in energy efficient sectors and the impact of energy cost changes on output is limited. On the contrary, the introduction of new technology improves production efficiency. The most striking discovery is that the output levels in energy efficient sectors go up in pace with the rise in emission reductions For example, the output of service production increases the most under any scenario, in particular, in CM40ETC (3.11%) and CM50ETC (4.59%). Even so, only a small amount of the increase in emissions comes from service, foods and agriculture sectors.

3.5. Fossil Energy Supply and Final Consumption

The impacts of carbon abatement on fossil energy supply in all the scenarios in 2050 are illustrated in Figure 4. Despite the mitigation measures, coal supply by 2030 is expected to suffer a blow, which is due to the fact that coal combustion releases more CO2 than other fossil energies.
Figure 4. Change of fossil energy supply in the varied scenarios compared with BAU in 2050.
Figure 4. Change of fossil energy supply in the varied scenarios compared with BAU in 2050.
Energies 08 03529 g004
Coal supply will be 3158 million tonnes coal equivalent (Mtce) in CM40ETC and 2960 Mtce in CM50ETC, accounting for 45.2% and 43.2% respectively in the total energy supply in 2050, while oil production will be almost unaffected, i.e., a slight drop of 0.78% in CM50, whose share will roughly remain unchanged in all scenarios. Limited resources and production capacities result in China’s heavy dependence on imported counterparts. The share of oil consumption remains steady, but oil consumption will severely depend on imports in 2050, with a degree of dependence of up to 80%, which is bound to increase energy security risks. China’s renewable energy development of wind, solar, and non-traditional biomass will replace fossil energy use. Meanwhile, renewable electricity generation increases significantly with the decreasing cost of renewable electricity. Renewable electricity in both the CM40 and CM50 scenarios sees relatively moderate increases, which indicates binding emission reduction commitments promote renewable electricity development to a certain extent (Figure 5). Current emission reduction policies result in significant growth in renewable electricity generation. Furthermore, the total and renewable electricity in general are higher under the CO2 emission reduction target of 50% than that at 40%. It is strongly noticeable that renewable electricity increases by approximately six times in CM50ET and the total electricity generation reaches 2584.52 Mtce, including 555.80 Mtce in thermal power, 730.02 Mtce in hydro power, 848.70 Mtce in nuclear power and 450.00 Mtce in renewable power, respectively. In contrast to CM40ET, the renewable energy contribution grows faster than that in CM40EC and the same situation occurs in CM50EC and CM50ET. In addition, the contributions of nuclear and hydro power in the scenarios with emission trading increase significantly that with a carbon tax. In comparison, emission trading is more efficient than a carbon tax in term of promote renewable energy development.
Figure 5. The total electricity generation mix through 2050.
Figure 5. The total electricity generation mix through 2050.
Energies 08 03529 g005
Figure 6 and Figure 7 show the total primary energy consumption by sector and by type in 2050. Primary energy consumption decreases dramatically in all countermeasure scenarios. Compared with the BAU scenario, primary energy consumption sees a decrease of 3.01% and 5.50% in CM40 and CM50 respectively. A substantial fall in primary energy consumption is observed in the scenario with emission reduction measures, whose trend is more obvious when a higher emission reduction proportion is adopted. For instance, in the scenario, the renewable and emission trading and the primary energy consumption drop significantly by 17.35% in CM40ET, 37.12% in CM40ETC, 27.13% in CM50ET, and 41.61% in CM50ETC, respectively. Meanwhile, the total primary energy consumption reduces to 4835.20 Mtce in CM40ETC and 4490 Mtce in CM50ETC, in which the share of non-fossil energy is 29.19% and 32.33%, respectively. The primary energy structure in the CM40 and CM50 scenarios is not significantly different from that in the BAU scenario, implying that compulsory emission reduction measures do not improve the energy mix. The oil and natural gas consumption remain rather stable in CM40 and CM50, while the consumption in all countermeasure scenarios declines by 10%–40%. Coal consumption experiences dramatic decreases with the amount being 44.45% and 46.67% of BAU’s level in CM40ETC and CM50ETC. Cumulative energy savings is estimated to be 27,625 Mtce in CM50ETC and 15,301 Mtce in CM50ETC from 2020 to 2050.
Figure 6. The total energy consumption by fuel types through 2050.
Figure 6. The total energy consumption by fuel types through 2050.
Energies 08 03529 g006
Figure 7. The total energy consumption by sector through 2050.
Figure 7. The total energy consumption by sector through 2050.
Energies 08 03529 g007
In the countermeasure scenarios, the energy use in energy-intensive sectors declines significantly. It is visible that manufacturing, whose energy consumption decreases by 31.5% in CM40ETC and 35.2% in CM50ETC, respectively, is the highest energy consuming sector which suffers the greatest decline. The energy consumption in the service sector increases from 18%–34%.

3.6. Sensitivity Analysis

The sensitivity analysis of this AIM/CGE model should be tested to identify whether the result will be heavily influenced by parameter assumption. In this study, a sensitivity analysis is conducted with respect to the elasticities between the production factors labor and capital ( σ K L ), fossil energy and electricity ( σ E ). We focus on the impacts of a 5% increase or drop from the base value on GDP and carbon intensity in CM40E and CM40ET.
Higher elasticity of σ K L means higher flexibility for producers to choose the factors of labor and capital when fulfilling their production quotas. Consequently, production cost drops away relatively, which results in higher activity levels and GDP growth. Results show that GDP loss is reduced by 4.36% from the base value. However, the carbon intensity do not change dramatically.
The σ E have a significant impact on carbon intensity and GDP. A 5% increase of σ E leads to a 11.49% drop of carbon intensity and a 5% drop of σ E leads to a 6.38% increase. Higher σ E put pressure on energy and carbon prices. Energy consumers have greater choice and flexibility to choose which kind of energy to consume. Hence, lower cost energy will be chosen, i.e., natural gas and electricity. The lower energy price stimulates production and drives GDP growth. Meanwhile, the carbon intensity will drop due to habit changes.

4. Conclusions

This study introduces the AIM/CGE model to investigate the effects of alternative mitigation policies, including renewable energy, emission trading and a carbon tax during 2010–2050. The simulation results show the effect on carbon intensity, activity level, GDP, energy system, and carbon prices in detail.
The emission reduction rate in the BAU scenario is approximately 28.68% in 2020 and 46.8% in 2050, based on the level of 2005. Absolute emission limits show negative impacts on future economic growth and activity level in energy intensive sectors. Activity level in non-energy intensive sectors increases slightly. In addition, the impact is larger when a higher emission reduction target level is set. In contrast, mitigation measures will curb CO2 emissions, promote economic growth and optimize the energy mix. More importantly, energy-intensive sectors will improve energy utilization technology as far as possible to lower their costs. The cumulative energy consumption reduction is estimated to be 27,625 Mtce in CM50ETC from 2020 to 2050. Moreover, climate policies lead to lower emissions, reduced energy intensity, and improved energy and industrial mixes. It is necessary to take all the measures into account to reduce emissions.
Among the mitigation measures, renewable energy makes a critical difference in abating emissions during the period from 2010 to 2020, reducing emissions per unit of GDP by 33.33% in CM40E and 36.43% in CM50E. After 2020, according to the hypotheses, abolishing subsidies on renewable energy will slow down the pace of development of renewable energy, which means that energy efficiency improved by renewable energy will affect the accompanying emission mitigation. Nevertheless, the renewable introduced reduces about 36% of the emissions per GDP, but still fails to meet the goals. Therefore, it is necessary to pay more attention to the development of renewable energy and the determination of the appropriate subsidy rates for renewable energy.
The emission trading introduced in 2016 will bring about high carbon prices, i.e., 143.4 USD/t in CM40ET, which encourages emissions reduction. Limited emission trading does not lower the carbon emission intensity as expected. Free emission trading must be integrated with mitigation measures to achieve the emission reduction targets. The government should try its best to plan the implementation of emission trading to avert unfair and unreasonable factors.
Carbon taxes would reduce carbon emissions, however, they does not work very well in the long term. Most noticeably, carbon taxes have a considerable negative impact on the sustainability, optimization of energy and economy system in the short term. It is necessary to give perfect rein to carbon tax by setting different tax rates.

Acknowledgments

This research was financially supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (NSFC) (71,471,061), Hebei Province Science and Technology Plan Project (14,457,694D) and the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities (2014ZP11).

Author Contributions

Wei Li designed this research and gave the whole guidance; Hao Li largely wrote the research, including data simulation, result display and analysis; Shuang Sun. collected all the data. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Appendix: Definition of Symbols Used in this Model

The variable symbols and meanings used in this study are as follows:
F i the fossil energy aggregate in i th sector
A i f the efficiency coefficient of fossil energy input in i th sector
α k , i the share coefficient of k th energy in i th sector
E C k , i the input of k th energy in i th sector
σ f , i the elasticity of substitution of various fossil energy in i th sector
c k the CO2 emissions factor of k th energy
E M i the CO2 emissions in i th sector
E L i the renewable electricity input in i th sector
A i e the efficiency coefficient of energy input in i th sector
α F , i the share coefficient of fossil energy in i th sector
σ E , i the elasticity of substitution between fossil energy and electricity in i th sector
E i the energy aggregate in i th sector
K i the capital input in i th sector
L i the labor input in i th sector
A i k l the efficiency coefficient of capital and labor input in i th sector
σ K L , i the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor in i th sector
α L , i the share coefficient of labor input in i th sector
K L i the capital-labor aggregate in i th sector
σ K L E , i the elasticity of substitution between energy and capital-labor in i th sector
α K L E , i the share coefficient of capital-labor input in i th sector
A i k l e the efficiency coefficient of capital-labor and energy input in i th sector
K L E i the capital-labor and energy aggregate in i th sector
α i , j the direct consumption coefficients of j th intermediate inputs in i th sector
X i , j the j th intermediate inputs per unit of outputs in i th sector
M i the intermediate inputs aggregate in i th sector
A i q the efficiency coefficient of output in i th sector
σ K L E M , i the elasticity of substitution between capital-labor-energy and intermediate inputs in i th sector
α K L E M , i the share coefficient of capital-labor-energy input in i th sector
Q i the output in i th sector
Y h the gross income of household sector
W i the wage rate in i th sector
r i the rate of return on capital in i th sector
H K the capital stock in household sector
K i the capital input in i th sector
T R g o v ¯ the transfer payment from government to household and enterprise
T R e n i ¯ the transfer payment from enterprise
β the share of transfer payment from government to household
γ the share of transfer payment from government to enterprise
Y g o v the gross income of government
Y e n t the gross income of enterprise
τ i the ad valorem rate of duty in i th sector
P i the product prices in i th sector
τ h the rate of individual income tax
τ e n t the rate of corporate income tax
T A R I F F tariff revenue
T A X c a r b o n the carbon tax revenue
Q C i the aggregate supply in domestic market in i th sector
A l m the scale parameter of the aggregate supply in domestic market of l th commodity
α m , l the share parameter of imported commodities of l th commodity
σ m , l the elasticity of substitution between imported commodities and domestic production of l th commodity
Q M l the imports of l th commodity
Q A M l the domestic production of l th commodity
P C l the consumer price of l th commodity
P M l the imports price of l th commodity
P A M l domestic production price of l th commodity
τ m , l the import tariffs of l th commodity
p w m l ¯ the world price of l th commodity
E X R ¯ the exchange rate
Table A1. The description of sector classifications used in this model.
Table A1. The description of sector classifications used in this model.
Non-Energy SectorsEnergy Sectors
1Agriculture1Coal mining
2Mineral mining2Extractionof petroleum
3Foods and Tobacco3Natural gas
4textiles and clothing4Coking
5Wood and furniture5Petroleum and nuclear fuel processing
6Paper products6Gas production and supply
7Chemical7Electricity
8Cement
9Non-metallic mineral products
10Iron and steel
11Nonferrous products
12Water production
13Machinery
14Other manufacturing
15Construction
16Transportation
17Service sectors
Table A2. The estimated feed-in subsidies for the renewable during the study period (Billion USD).
Table A2. The estimated feed-in subsidies for the renewable during the study period (Billion USD).
YearCM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ET
WindSolarBiomassWindSolarBiomassWindSolarBiomassWindSolarBiomass
20100.750.020.130.830.170.220.750.020.130.830.170.22
20152.420.840.312.781.250.562.420.840.312.781.250.56
20204.891.210.745.711.881.175.702.471.606.302.982.16
Table A3. The estimated revenues of carbon tax during 2020–2050 (Billion USD).
Table A3. The estimated revenues of carbon tax during 2020–2050 (Billion USD).
YearCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
20208.398.066.846.59
20259.328.987.277.14
203010.079.737.617.52
203510.7910.347.897.85
204011.4511.048.368.14
204511.9311.428.578.43
205012.3711.888.708.32
Table A4. The government receipts in all scenarios during 2010–2050 (Billion USD).
Table A4. The government receipts in all scenarios during 2010–2050 (Billion USD).
YearCM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
20101336.031315.591299.541280.431264.811246.221231.021212.921198.121180.51
20152229.652184.832148.782109.462074.652036.692003.081966.431933.981898.59
20203091.582982.762919.822857.922805.912752.032693.962636.852588.862539.16
20253766.123621.133540.383456.823392.183318.913236.603135.943067.262989.36
20304922.174700.674589.744471.324384.134281.114160.814013.513918.393807.89
20408055.887619.257429.537228.197075.686898.086693.896421.456259.636065.58
205011,091.7710,325.3310,059.979779.299561.219312.629024.868587.168361.318076.19
Table A5. Change of coal supply in 2050.
Table A5. Change of coal supply in 2050.
YearCM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
2015−5.62%−9.00%−4.90%−6.90%−4.90%−6.90%−4.90%−6.90%−4.90%−3.74%
2020−5.50%−8.56%−4.00%−6.00%−3.10%−5.60%−4.00%−6.00%−3.10%−3.04%
2025−5.00%−7.66%−3.10%−5.10%−2.60%−4.60%−2.85%−3.82%−2.53%−2.63%
2030−4.80%−6.85%−2.85%−4.40%−2.30%−3.80%−2.58%−3.30%−2.20%−2.09%
2040−4.50%−6.50%−2.68%−3.80%−2.03%−3.20%−2.36%−2.88%−1.96%−1.73%
2050−4.10%−6.25%−2.55%−3.40%−1.85%−2.70%−2.20%−2.61%−1.82%−1.44%
Table A6. Change of oill supply in 2050.
Table A6. Change of oill supply in 2050.
YearCM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
2015−0.47%−0.76%−0.41%−0.58%−0.41%−0.58%−0.41%−0.58%−0.41%−0.58%
2020−0.46%−0.72%−0.34%−0.51%−0.26%−0.47%−0.34%−0.51%−0.26%−0.47%
2025−0.42%−0.65%−0.26%−0.43%−0.22%−0.39%−0.24%−0.41%−0.21%−0.41%
2030−0.40%−0.58%−0.24%−0.37%−0.19%−0.32%−0.22%−0.35%−0.19%−0.33%
2040−0.38%−0.55%−0.23%−0.32%−0.17%−0.27%−0.20%−0.29%−0.17%−0.27%
2050−0.35%−0.53%−0.21%−0.29%−0.16%−0.23%−0.19%−0.26%−0.15%−0.22%
Table A7. Change of gas supply in 2050.
Table A7. Change of gas supply in 2050.
YearCM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
2015−3.05%−4.88%−2.66%−3.74%−2.66%−3.74%−2.66%−3.74%−2.66%−3.74%
2020−2.98%−4.64%−2.17%−3.25%−1.68%−3.04%−2.17%−3.25%−1.68%−3.04%
2025−2.71%−4.15%−1.68%−2.76%−1.41%−2.49%−1.55%−2.63%−1.37%−2.63%
2030−2.60%−3.71%−1.55%−2.39%−1.25%−2.06%−1.40%−2.22%−1.19%−2.09%
2040−2.44%−3.52%−1.45%−2.06%−1.10%−1.73%−1.28%−1.90%−1.06%−1.73%
2050−2.22%−3.39%−1.38%−1.84%−1.00%−1.46%−1.19%−1.65%−0.99%−1.44%
Table A8. CO2 emission intensity from 2020 to 2050.
Table A8. CO2 emission intensity from 2020 to 2050.
YearBAUCM40CM50CM40ECM50ECM40ETCM50ETCM40ECCM50ECCM40ETCCM50ETC
20200.920.770.680.860.820.700.680.780.750.780.73
20250.900.740.650.820.780.640.630.720.710.730.69
20300.880.710.620.780.750.600.580.670.640.690.65
20400.860.650.580.680.630.560.540.620.590.630.58
20500.830.610.540.590.550.530.520.560.540.570.54

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Yuan, H.; Zhou, P.; Zhou, D. What is low-carbon development? A conceptual analysis. Energy Procedia 2011, 5, 1706–1712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. European Union (EU). Roadmap for a Low-Carbon Economy in 2050. Available online: http://ec.europa.eu/clima/consultations/articles/0005_en.htm (accessed on 8 December 2010).
  3. Japan-U.S. Summit Meeting. Japan-U.S. Joint Message on Climate Change Negotiations. Available online: http://www.mofa.go.jp/region/n-america/us/pv0911/summit.html (accessed on 13 October 2010).
  4. National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC). National Climate Change Plan (2014–2020). Available online: http://www.sdpc.gov.cn/zcfb/zcfbtz/201411/t20141104_642612.html (accessed on 19 September 2014).
  5. Dai, H.; Masui, T.; Matsuoka, Y. Assessment of China’s climate commitment and non-fossil energy plan towards 2020 using hybrid AIM/CGE model. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 2875–2887. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Bandyopadhyay, G.; Bagheri, F.; Mann, M. Reduction of fossil fuel emissions in the USA: A holistic approach towards policy formulation. Energy Policy 2007, 35, 950–965. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Hammar, H.; Sjöström, M. Accounting for behavioral effects of increases in the carbon dioxide (CO2) tax in revenue estimation in Sweden. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 6672–6676. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Lin, B.; Li, X. The effect of carbon tax on per capita CO2 emissions. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 5137–5146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Szabó, L.; Hidalgo, I.; Ciscar, J.C.; Soria, A. CO2 emission trading within the European Union and Annex B countries: The cement industry case. Energy Policy 2006, 34, 72–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Lee, C.F.; Lin, S.J.; Lewis, C. Analysis of the impacts of combining carbon taxation and emission trading on different industry sectors. Energy Policy 2008, 36, 722–729. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Sugino, M.; Arimura, T.H.; Morgenstern, R.D. The effects of alternative carbon mitigation policies on Japanese industries. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 1254–1267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Deetman, S.; Hof, A.F.; Pfluger, B.; van Vuuren, D.P.; Girod, B.; van Ruijven, B.J. Deep greenhouse gas emission reductions in Europe: Exploring different options. Energy Policy 2013, 55, 152–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Hübler, M.; Löschel, A. The EU Decarbonisation Roadmap 2050—What way to walk? Energy Policy 2013, 55, 190–207. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Thepkhun, P.; Limmeechokchai, B.; Fujimori, S.; Masui, T.; Shrestha, R.M. Thailand’s Low-Carbon Scenario 2050: The AIM/CGE analyses of CO2 mitigation measures. Energy Policy 2013, 62, 561–572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Qi, T.; Zhang, X.; Karplus, V.J. The energy and CO2 emissions impact of renewable energy development in China. Energy Policy 2014, 68, 60–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Wang, Y.; Liang, S. Carbon dioxide mitigation target of China in 2020 and key economic sectors. Energy Policy 2013, 58, 90–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Li, Y.P.; Huang, G.H.; Li, M.W. An integrated optimization modeling approach for planning emission trading and clean-energy development under uncertainty. Renew. Energy 2014, 62, 31–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Hermeling, C.; Löschel, A.; Mennel, T. A new robustness analysis for climate policy evaluations: A CGE application for the EU 2020 targets. Energy Policy 2013, 55, 27–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Orlov, A.; Grethe, H. Carbon taxation and market structure: A CGE analysis for Russia. Energy Policy 2012, 51, 696–707. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Matsumoto, K.; Masui, T. Economic impacts to avoid dangerous climate change using the AIM/CGE model. Procedia Environ. Sci. 2010, 6, 162–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Okagawa, A.; Masui, T.; Akashi, O.; Hijioka, Y.; Matsumoto, K.; Kainuma, M. Assessment of GHG emission reduction pathways in a society without carbon capture and nuclear technologies. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, S391–S398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Xu, Y.; Masui, T. Local air pollutant emission reduction and ancillary carbon benets of SO2 control policies: Application of AIM/CGE model to China. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2009, 198, 315–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Fujimori, S.; Tu, T.T.; Masui, T.; Matsuoka, Y. AIM/CGE [Basic] Manual; National Institute for Environmental Studies: Tsukuba, Japan, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  24. China Input-Output Association (CIOA): 2005 Input-Output Table. Available online: http://www.iochina.org.cn/Download/xgxz.html (accessed on 1 January 2006).
  25. National Bureau of Statistics (NBS). China Statistical Yearbook 2010. China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2010. [Google Scholar]
  26. IPCC. IPCC Guide Lines for National Green House Gas Inventories. 2006. Available online: http://www.ipcc-nggip.iges.or.jp/public/2006gl (accessed on 1 April 2007).
  27. Peng, Z. In-Output Tables of China; China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  28. Wei, S.; Huang, Y. Keqiang economics. Western Development. 2013, 9, 22–25. [Google Scholar]
  29. Wang, K.; Wang, C.; Chen, J. Analysis of the economic impact of different Chinese climate policy options based on a CGE model incorporating endogenous technological change. Energy Policy 2013, 37, 2930–2940. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. The Central People’s Government of the People’s Republic of China. National Population Development Strategy Research Report. Available online: http://www.gov.cn/gzdt/2007-01/11/content_493677.htm (accessed on 11 January 2007).
  31. National Bureau of Statistics of China. China Statistical Yearbook; China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2008–2010. (In Chinese)
  32. National Energy Administration (NEA). Energy Development “Twelfth Five Year Plan”. Available online: http://www.nea.gov.cn/2013–01/28/c_132132808.htm (accessed on 1 January 2013).
  33. Jiang, K.; Hu, X. China’s low carbon development scenario in 2050. In 2050 China Energy and CO2 Emissions Report. Study Team of 2005 China Energy and CO2 Emissions Report; Science Press: Beijing, China, 2009. [Google Scholar]
  34. National Development and Reform Commission (NDRC). Interim Measures on Management Carbon Trading. Available online: http://www.in-en.com/finance/html/energy07360736802226927.html (accessed on 22 December 2014).
  35. Yang, Y.; Qiu, W.; He, D. The game analysis between the government and the enterprises under mandatory emission reduction mechanism. Syst. Eng. 2012, 2, 110–114. [Google Scholar]
  36. Wang, X.; Pang, J. The challenges, opportunities and recommendations for Chinese energy intensive enterprises to cope with climate change. Clim. Chang. Res. Prog. 2009, 2, 110–116. [Google Scholar]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Li, W.; Li, H.; Sun, S. China’s Low-Carbon Scenario Analysis of CO2 Mitigation Measures towards 2050 Using a Hybrid AIM/CGE Model. Energies 2015, 8, 3529-3555. https://doi.org/10.3390/en8053529

AMA Style

Li W, Li H, Sun S. China’s Low-Carbon Scenario Analysis of CO2 Mitigation Measures towards 2050 Using a Hybrid AIM/CGE Model. Energies. 2015; 8(5):3529-3555. https://doi.org/10.3390/en8053529

Chicago/Turabian Style

Li, Wei, Hao Li, and Shuang Sun. 2015. "China’s Low-Carbon Scenario Analysis of CO2 Mitigation Measures towards 2050 Using a Hybrid AIM/CGE Model" Energies 8, no. 5: 3529-3555. https://doi.org/10.3390/en8053529

APA Style

Li, W., Li, H., & Sun, S. (2015). China’s Low-Carbon Scenario Analysis of CO2 Mitigation Measures towards 2050 Using a Hybrid AIM/CGE Model. Energies, 8(5), 3529-3555. https://doi.org/10.3390/en8053529

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop