Next Article in Journal
Samothraki in Transition: A Report on a Real-World Lab to Promote the Sustainability of a Greek Island
Previous Article in Journal
The Productive, Economic, and Social Efficiency of Vineyards Using Combined Drought-Tolerant Rootstocks and Efficient Low Water Volume Deficit Irrigation Techniques under Mediterranean Semiarid Conditions
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Systems Thinking to Understand National Well-Being from a Human Capital Perspective

International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), Laxenburg 2361, Austria
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2020, 12(5), 1931; https://doi.org/10.3390/su12051931
Submission received: 10 December 2019 / Revised: 19 February 2020 / Accepted: 27 February 2020 / Published: 3 March 2020

Abstract

:
Well-being has become an important policy goal to replace gross domestic product (GDP) as an indicator of national progress. Several multidimensional metrics and indicators of well-being have been developed mostly based on the four-capital model that includes natural, economic, human and social capital. These multidimensional measures of well-being, however, are highly categorical and lack a systems perspective that focuses on underlying mechanisms of the metrics and the interconnections between them. This study aims at bringing a systems thinking approach to understanding and measuring national well-being, particularly from a human capital perspective. For this purpose, we employ a qualitative systems mapping approach and identify the direct or indirect relationships between the well-being indicators related to human capital. The results show that the human capital system is governed by several reinforcing feedback loops through economic progress, health and life expectancy, which gives a central role to human capital to enhance well-being. There are balancing loops, however, that may have adverse effects on human capital formation and well-being, for instance through migration and ageing. Future studies can focus on the other three subsystems in the four-capital model, and on quantifying the relationships between different dimensions of well-being.

1. Introduction

Well-being has recently become a focal point in the policy agenda of several national governments due in particular to its multidimensional outlook on human welfare and alignment with the United Nations (UN) sustainable development goals. Well-being, in general, refers to the state of feeling or being happy, healthy or prosperous [1]. Earlier philosophical definitions of well-being were based on welfarism, following a utilitarian view on maximizing the pleasant and minimizing the unpleasant [2]. This view was manifested in measuring national well-being in macro-economic terms, such as GDP, which has been the measure of national progress for several decades. However, the inadequacy of GDP to measure national progress and well-being has been increasingly acknowledged [3], and alternative indices based on subjective well-being or multidimensional statistical indices have been proposed [4]. The examples of such multi-dimensional measures start with the UN Human Development Index (HDI) that combines life expectancy and education level in addition to GDP [5], the 10-dimensional well-being measure of the UK’s Office for National Statistics [6], and the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Better Life Index (BLI) that combines a wide variety of metrics from economy to housing and health [7].
Alternative approaches to GDP refer to freedom and capabilities as the main sources of well-being so that individuals can realize their potential [8,9,10,11]. Following this capability-based view, the statistical measures of national well-being have become multi-dimensional and led to the four capital model, which is composed of built (economic), human, social, and natural capital as the main determinants of well-being [12]. These four capitals are further decomposed into various measurable indicators in different studies [13,14], such as air pollution as an indicator of natural capital or voter turnout as an indicator of social capital.
These multidimensional measures of well-being, however, are highly categorical. They identify and list various material and non-material aspects of well-being, yet they do not strongly consider the relationships between these aspects, or the underlying mechanisms that lead to co-development of various well-being indicators. Existing studies increasingly show statistical dependencies between different dimensions and indicators of national well-being [15]. Therefore, current understanding and measurement of well-being can strongly benefit from systems thinking, i.e., focusing on the interconnections between various dimensions of well-being and their underlying mechanisms. With systems thinking, more harmonious, effective and efficient well-being policies can be designed, which can result in gaining multiple co-benefits or avoiding unintended consequences.
The objective of this paper is to bring a systems thinking approach to understanding and measuring national well-being, particularly from a human capital perspective. For this purpose, we employ a qualitative systems mapping approach and identify the direct or indirect relationships between the OECD well-being indicators related to human capital. We derive these maps from the scientific literature on human capital to synthesize the main themes and their relationships in the available scientific knowledge.
Our choice to focus on human capital has been motivated by the central interlinking role of human capital in the existing well-being measurement frameworks such as UN HDI and OECD Better Life Index, as well its significant potential in achieving sustainable development goals [16]. Human capital is defined as “knowledge, skills, competencies and attributes embodied in individuals that facilitate the creation of personal, social and economic well-being” [17]. Human capital has been identified as a significant driver of economic growth [18], and increasingly considered as a key driver of sustainability [19]. Therefore, this study focuses on human capital due to its crucial role within the four-capital model of well-being and extends beyond the economic growth perspective on human capital. It investigates how human capital is formed, maintained and linked to the overall wellbeing of individuals and societies based on the framework of the OECD Better Life Index.
In the remainder of this paper, Section 2 first summarizes the OECD well-being indicators (Better Life Index) and motivates the choice of the OECD framework for this study. It then describes the mapping method followed to derive qualitative systems maps of human capital. Section 3 presents the results of mapping with a focus on the feedback mechanisms that explore the relationships between educational attainment, economic growth and health. Section 4 highlights the insights from these maps and their policy implications, and then discusses the limitations of this study and future research potential.

2. Materials and Methods

Defining system boundaries is a major challenge in systems mapping, especially for a complex issue like national well-being that covers a variety of aspects from human psychology to biophysical systems. The scope of this study is determined based on the OECD framework for measuring well-being, also known as the Better Life Index. This choice has been motivated by two factors. Firstly, the OECD well-being indicators are extensive, well-defined and well-quantified, covering not only the economic and tangible aspects of national well-being such as household income or employment, but also intangible aspects based on self-reported data, such as life satisfaction and social support. They enable measuring the performance of a country over time and compared to the others. Secondly, the OECD framework is well known. Many policymakers and researchers are familiar with these indicators, therefore the penetration of systems thinking to research and policymaking on well-being through this framework can be more accessible.
While the scope of this study, i.e., the breadth and depth of the maps we develop, is based on the OECD well-being indicators and their categorization, the mapping adds direct or indirect links between these indicators, hence it brings systems thinking beyond categorical thinking on well-being. This section explains these two pillars of this study, by first summarizing the OECD well-being framework, then describing the systems mapping approach we follow.

2.1. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) Well-Being Framework

The OECD indicators of national well-being reflect the capability approach [20], and relate to the outcomes achieved in the two broad domains: material living conditions and quality of life. These two domains are further divided into topics, such as income and wealth, jobs and earnings, or work-life balance, and subjective well-being. Each topic is operationalized in at least one measurable indicator, i.e., a key statistic, such as Household net wealth, Long-term unemployment rate, Working hours and (self-reported) Life satisfaction, as the “Current Well-being” indicators in the upper part of Figure 1 illustrate.
The OECD well-being framework also includes indicators of future well-being. These are called resources, since they facilitate the maintenance or enhancement of wellbeing over time. Resources are categorized with a capital-based approach, i.e., the four capital model, since their change over time is attributed to the current stocks of the capitals. Four main groups of capital are considered: natural, economic, human and social capital. Each capital is represented by a set of indicators, often overlapping with the indicators of current wellbeing [21].
For the indicators of future well-being, the OECD follows a stock-flow categorization. The indicators that relate to stocks represent a store of a resource for future well-being. The flow indicators relate to the factors that increase or deplete the stocks over time. For instance, ‘concentration of greenhouse gases in the atmosphere’ is a stock indicator of natural capital, while ‘greenhouse gas emissions per capita’ is a flow indicator that increases it. A third group of future indicators are called risk factors, which are the factors that are not directly outflows of stocks, but can lead to the depletion of stocks. This stock-flow conceptualization aligns with the quantitative and qualitative systems modelling approaches such as system dynamics.
Figure 1 visualizes the decomposition of the OECD Better Life Index as a measure of a nation’s current well-being and the future well-being indicators based on the four capitals.
The OECD indicators related to human capital cover mostly formal education, skills and health, as listed in Table 1. While the population-level educational attainment levels and skills are formulated as stocks, because they refer to the accumulation of formal education degrees and skills in a society, health-related factors such as obesity and smoking prevalence are considered as the risk factors for future human capital.

2.2. Systems Mapping Approach

Systems mapping is a primary tool of systems thinking. Based on causal loop diagrams that constitute the basis of system dynamics modelling process [22], a systems map identifies and visualizes the interconnections between system components, as well as the feedback mechanisms formed by those connections. Besides forming the conceptual basis for quantitative models, causal maps depict the multidimensionality and complexity of a problem; help to create mutual understanding of a system by its stakeholders; and aid in propagating the effects of potential interventions to the system qualitatively. Causal systems mapping has been used in a variety of studies, from sustainable consumption [23] to the acceptance of agrifood nanotechnology [24], energy efficiency and well-being in the built environment [25,26], and climate change impacts on mental health [27].
In this study, we chose systems mapping to analyze well-being because it establishes a systems thinking perspective by visually linking the key factors and indicators that drive and define well-being. In other words, systems mapping complements the current understanding of well-being, which is based on compartmentally identified drivers and risks, by adding the interlinkages and non-linearities to those. Systems maps can be derived either in participatory settings with the experts and stakeholders to represent their mental models, or can be elicited by interviewing them, or they can be based on scientific literature. In this study, we have chosen the latter in order to synthesize the academic literature and reflect the available scientific knowledge on the interlinkages between well-being indicators.
The formal methods of deriving causal maps from textual data, whether it is interview transcripts or scientific literature, are based on the grounded theory approach [28]. Based on ‘coding’, i.e., fracturing and analyzing qualitative data, the grounded theory approach enables a theory to emerge from the data, and links the causal relations underlying this theory explicitly to the data [29,30].
Existing formal coding methods of deriving causal maps from textual data [31,32,33,34] have a common framework of five core phases: (i) open coding to identify the themes in the data, (ii) the identification of individual causal relationships, (iii) visualizing these relationships in word-and-arrow diagrams, (iv) generalizing and simplifying these diagrams (axial coding) and (v) recording the links between the final causal map and the data source explicitly in a data source reference table.
The mapping approach followed in this study is based on this framework and specified by six steps, as shown in Figure 2. In Step 1, the literature search is conducted on the Scopus database with key words human capital and well-being. In other words, we retrieved the articles that include human capital and well-being in their title, abstract or keywords, published until May 2018, and chose the relevant ones based on their abstract content. Although the concept of human capital could be represented by different keywords such as human assets or human resources, we chose human capital since it prioritizes the studies that relate to the four-capital model. Step 2 is the open coding of the material to identify the themes and main concepts. Step 3 moves the coding further with identification of variables based on the themes and concepts, as well as the relationships between them. By contrast with the original five-phase framework, we compose the data source reference table in this step and use it as an input in Step 4 (Table A1). In other words, Step 3 on axial coding results in the data source reference table which lists the variables and relationships to be aggregated in Step 4. Step 4 aligns the variables identified in the previous step with the OECD indicators and adopts a common terminology. For instance, what the literature refers to as the ‘income’ of an individual is matched with ‘Average annual gross earnings per full time employee’ among the OECD indicators. In Step 5, the coding dictionary, i.e., the list of relationships aggregated and matched with the OECD framework, is transformed into causal loop diagrams. This visualization paid special attention to feedback loops and maintained the legend that corresponds to the categorization of current and future well-being indicators as stocks, flows and risks. Step 6 is merging the maps of the four capitals which is to be completed in future studies since this paper focuses only on the human capital.

3. Results

As mentioned before, human capital has four main components: (i) knowledge and skills, (ii) experience, (iii) values and norms, (iv) health [18]. The main themes and concepts identified in the literature (Step 2) coincide with these components. Furthermore, since these four components are not separable from an individual, mobilization/migration and societal ageing play an important role in the dynamics of national human capital. Another prevalent theme in the literature is the economic aspect of human capital formation. Formal education, hence knowledge, skills and experience are driven by investments, whether these investments are made by the individuals themselves, their families or governments. The feedback loops governing these investments through generations, i.e., the effect of family on an individual’s human capital, are also important drivers of dynamic change at the national-level human capital.
The maps presented in Figure 3 and Figure 4 capture these themes with respect to the relevant OECD indicators. These figures highlight the feedback loops as the drivers of dynamics and non-linearities from two main perspectives, educational attainment and health. These two perspectives represent the main themes that emerged from coding the literature, and the figures include additional factors such as economic growth, experience, and aging in addition to educational attainment and health. While these figures decompose the entire map for an easier tracking of feedback loops, the entire model of the human capital subsystem as a combination of these feedback loops and additional factors is presented in Figure A1.
Throughout these figures, an arrow represents a relationship from the cause variable to the effect variable. A positive (+) sign implies positive causality, meaning that an increase (decrease) in the cause variable would increase (decrease) the effect variable. A negative (-) sign implies negative causality, meaning that an increase (decrease) in the cause variable would decrease (increase) the effect variable. A chain of such relationships forms a feedback loop. A positive (reinforcing) loop implies that a change in any of the variables in this series would reinforce further change in the same direction. A negative (balancing) loop, however, implies that a change in any of the loop variables would balance itself by triggering a change in the opposite direction.

3.1. Human Capital from an Educational Attainment Perspective

Figure 3a depicts the positive feedback loops that go through educational attainment (See Table 1). Many of these loops emphasize the positive effect of human capital on national economic growth evidenced by empirical studies [35]. In the first loop (R1), as educational attainment increases, mean years of schooling, i.e., the average education level of a citizen, also increases. Higher education levels lead to increased labour productivity, therefore increased income [36,37]. Increasing income levels (average annual gross earnings) increase the education spending of individuals, either for themselves or for their children [16,18], which then lead to higher enrolment and subsequently higher educational attainment. Considering its definition in Table 1, educational attainment is dependent only on young adult educational attainment, since formal education is followed mostly by the young population, and the education level of the entire adult population changes as the young population’s education level changes.
R2 presents an additional path from educational attainment to labour productivity, since the education level of an individual is linked to better health practices, and productivity is affected by health [16,18]. As individuals’ health is one of the four components of their human capital, health is an important determinant of human capital also at the country level, which then leads to higher economic productivity growth [38].
Job opportunities created by economic growth increase the potential benefits of education, therefore the enrolment rates [18], leading to higher educational attainment and forming the loop R3.
As for R4, it depicts the reinforcing effect of educational attainment through skills. Mean years of schooling increase the knowledge and skills gained through formal education, hence the adult skills. Being an important component of national human capital, increasing adult skills lead to further economic growth and close the loop to educational attainment.
The last reinforcing loop (R5) is formed by an alternative path from economic productivity growth to education enrolment, because increasing economic growth increases income levels, leading to higher educational spending [16].
These positive feedback loops highlight the importance of human capital for many aspects of well-being, such as income and health. However, they are balanced by negative feedback loops shown in Figure 3b. Therefore, Figure 3a,b should be considered together in order to understand the simultaneous effect of positive and negative loops. The first one (B1) reflects a demographic balancing effect of increasing educational attainment. Job opportunities created by increasing educational attainment and economic growth also attract immigration, or lead to lower emigration [18,39]. Considering that migrants are mostly young and mobile people, immigration would increase the young population. Since young adult educational attainment is a fraction of young population, it declines with an increasing population, unless the education level linked to this increase in the population is high, too. It is important to note that this relationship captures only the effect of population increase on the educational attainment metric, and it omits the regulation of immigrant population’s education level through government policies because the policy interventions are not in the scope of this study that focuses only on the endogenous system interconnections. However, the relationship between human capital formation and migration is multi-dimensional and more complicated, with positive and negative implications for both the source and destination countries [40,41].
B2 reflects the effect of aging on human capital. Educational attainment increases health as explained in more detail in Section 3.2, and this leads to a higher life expectancy, which increases the duration of working life for individuals. This implies an aging workforce. Aging leads to higher forgetting rates due to loss of fluid mental abilities such as speed of processing, working memory, long-term memory and short-term memory [42,43]. Forgetting rate of knowledge is one of the two factors that reduce adult skills stock, hence the human capital [37]. The link from human capital to educational attainment is the series of positive links through economic productivity growth, as discussed earlier, that complete the loop. The last balancing loop (B3) pinpoints the vulnerability of human capital gained through higher education to technological progress. Most knowledge and skills gained through higher education are those that become obsolete most quickly due to technological progress. A higher means years of schooling implies more higher education graduates in a society, whose specialist knowledge and skills are more vulnerable to technological progress [37]. Therefore, the higher the mean years of schooling, the higher the obsolescence of knowledge and skills. This obsolescence reduces the adult skills stock, which signifies the average value of skills in the population and decreases even though obsolescence affects a small fraction of the adult population (adult skills refer to all technology-relevant skills required in the workforce here, not only the literacy and numeracy rates as measured in the OECD Better Life Index.). This change in adult skills in turn reduces educational attainment through economic growth, which is shortened to the bold black link in the figure.

3.2. Human Capital from a Health Perspective

With growing evidence, education reduces adult mortality and increases life expectancy [16,44]. Figure 4 provides a closer look into the health component of human capital through several of the OECD indicators. The two risks for future human capital identified by the OECD, smoking and obesity prevalence, do actually stand in positive feedback loops. The reinforcing loop R6-wise and healthy depicts that a high national human capital leads to economic growth, and further educational attainment. Highly educated people follow better health practices [18,45], reducing the smoking and obesity prevalence in the population and leading to better national health, hence higher human capital. This loop implies that these risks for human capital (e.g., smoking and obesity) may not be as high as expected, as long as higher education levels ensure better health practices. Higher income levels induced by economic growth provide more access to better nutrition, reducing obesity prevalence, and more access to health services. These relations form another reinforcing loop, R7-wealthy and heathy. It must be noted that the relationship from economic growth to access to better nutrition and health services depends on the distribution of wealth and government policies on this issue. However, since this study focuses on endogenous system relationships, such exogenous policy variables are not included in the map.
Another health-related reinforcing loop is the R8-wealthy and long-lived loop. As human capital increases, the income levels, access to health services, and life expectancy increase, too. This leads to a longer working life, and more experience in the workforce. Being one of the four main components of human capital, more experience leads to a larger human capital stock [18]. It is important to note that the other education-related factors such as health practices impact life expectancy, too, although not visualized in Figure 4, making the education level the most important determinant of life expectancy [46].
Exposure to PM2.5 air pollution is one of the current and future natural capital indicators (Figure 1) and reported to have an important effect on the health and cognitive development of children [16,47]. This link exemplifies the impact of natural capital extending to human capital, since higher levels of air pollution reduce cognitive development and affect cognitive skills at age 15.
Human capital has wider impacts extending beyond those discussed above. The entire map of the human capital subsystem derived in this study (Figure A1) captures two of these additional links. Firstly, education has a well-documented effect on population growth through fertility and infant mortality rates. On the one hand, increasing female education in the young population decreases fertility rates all over the world [48,49,50], hence impeding population growth. On the other hand, higher education levels of both females and males decrease infant mortality [51], having a positive effect on the young population.
The second wider impact of human capital is on social capital. An increasing level of education is associated with a stronger sense of civic duty, leading to a higher participation in politics [52]. The positive relationship between human capital and democracy has been established also in empirical studies [53,54]. Therefore, higher political participation corresponds to higher voter turnout among the OECD well-being indicators. Still, the interconnections between human capital and other OECD indicators related to social capital should be investigated further.

4. Discussion

4.1. Policy Implications

This study contributes to understanding and measuring national well-being by initiating a systems thinking perspective on the human capital component of well-being. In addition to categorical thinking that decomposes human capital into various aspects and operational measures, systems thinking focuses on the interconnectedness of these measures. Through this interconnectedness, systems thinking highlights the opportunities for and barriers to enhancing multiple dimensions of well-being simultaneously. It helps to avoid unintended consequences that may arise from non-linearities, i.e., worsening one dimension of well-being while trying to improve another.
The systems maps derived in this study show that human capital creates many opportunities to enhance national well-being, either directly via education levels or through its effects on income and health, because it is governed mostly by positive feedback loops. This means that even a small trigger to increase education levels and human capital propagates through the system, creating many exponentially increasing benefits on well-being. Due to these exponential positive effects, such as decreased mortality, fertility, increased health or increased civic engagement, human capital is considered a key driver of not only national well-being but also sustainable development [16]. However, it must be kept in mind that these loops may run in the opposite direction and create cascading negative effects on human capital, the economy and public health. Therefore, unless their positive functioning is maintained or fostered, these positive feedback loops may be detrimental for national well-being. For instance, if the school systems do not lead to high graduation rates, hence a high educational attainment, this would lead to lower and lower schooling through the economic effects, and would further lower the human capital. Therefore, education policies should pay attention to such wider and longer-term implications of systemic feedbacks.
The balancing loops in the maps highlight the issues that require careful policies to maintain the positive effects of human capital on well-being. Although this mapping study cannot quantify their magnitude, three main risks can be listed based on these balancing loops. Firstly, national human capital creates economic growth and new job opportunities, which attract migration. Migration may cause a decline in the national human capital in return. Secondly, human capital increases life expectancy through many health benefits. Longer working lives, however, lead to ageing of the human capital in return. Lastly, while higher education increases human capital, the knowledge and skills it brings are more susceptible to obsolescence. Therefore, human capital policies should counteract these potential negative effects of migration, aging and specialized higher education. Education programs for migrants, or life-learning programs to refresh and diversify the capabilities of an ageing or highly specialized workforce could be practical policy options to reduce the impact of such negative feedback.

4.2. Limitations and Future Research

Well-being is an immensely broad concept and the systems that determine national well-being are accordingly extensive. Therefore, system delineation is of crucial importance to study well-being. In this study, we chose the indicators and framework of the OECD Better Life Index (BLI) to determine the main subsystems and components to be included in the system maps. BLI is the most extensive and multi-dimensional index, including intangible aspects of well-being such as self-reported life satisfaction in addition to many tangible aspects. Still, it does not include measures about the underlying mechanisms. For instance, while the indicator “Cognitive skills at 15” represents the quality of the school system, there is no indicator about the capacity of the schools, such as the number and qualifications of teachers. Therefore, future studies can deepen the maps by expanding to specific underlying factors.
This study focused on human capital, which is only one component of the four-capital model used to measure well-being, yet included the BLI indictors and additional variables that relate to the other capitals. For instance, average annual earning per full-time (FT) employee is an indicator in the economic capital subsystem, and closely connected to the human capital subsystem since it determines education spending. In future studies, the map of the human capital subsystem should be merged with those of the other capital maps, using such interface variables, in order to obtain the whole systems view on well-being.
Our approach to mapping the human capital system focused on endogenous relationships among the factors defined by the BLI or emerging from the literature. It did not include exogenous policy variables, interventions or regulations. The resulting map of this study can be used in future policy-oriented research, for instance in participatory settings, to identify where different policy options can be imposed on this system and how their effects would propagate throughout the system on multiple dimensions.
This study adopted a general qualitative approach to identify systemic interactions between the drivers and effects of national human capital, without focusing on any particular country. Future studies can contextualize this approach by focusing on specific countries. For instance, the relative importance of each factor can be quantified based on available national statistics or participatory studies with the experts. Moreover, statistical relations between different dimensions of well-being can be quantified based on global databases.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, S.E. and L.I.-S.; methodology, S.E.; formal analysis, S.E.; writing—original draft preparation, S.E.; writing—review and editing, S.E. and L.I.-S.; visualization, S.E.; project administration, L.I.-S. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was funded by International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA) and its National Member Organizations in Africa, the Americas, Asia, and Europe.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix

Figure A1. The entire map of the human capital subsystem.
Figure A1. The entire map of the human capital subsystem.
Sustainability 12 01931 g0a1
Table A1. Data source reference table that shows the preliminary coding of scientific articles for the variables and relationships between them. Each row shows a relationship from variable to variable 2. Whether this is a positive or negative relationship is designated by its polarity.
Table A1. Data source reference table that shows the preliminary coding of scientific articles for the variables and relationships between them. Each row shows a relationship from variable to variable 2. Whether this is a positive or negative relationship is designated by its polarity.
Variable 1Variable 2PolarityExplanationReference
EducationIncome+In Step 4, these specific factors and relationships are aggregated into ’Education spending’ and ’Job opportunities’ increasing ’Education enrolment’. Education spending and job opportunities are triggered by ’Average annual gross earnings per full-time (FT) employee’ and ’Economic productivity growth’, respectively. Becker discusses these relationships with concrete examples from women’s enrollment in higher education and its effects on the economy.Becker. 1994 [18]
Benefits from (college) educationEducation enrollment+
Cost of (college) educationEducation enrollment-
Incentives for disadvantaged groupsEducation enrollment+
IncomeBenefits from (college) education+
Investment in educationEducation enrollment+
Job opportunitiesBenefits from (college) education+
ExperienceIncome+Experience, as a component of an individual’s human capital, increases income and decreases job changes. In Step 4, job changes are not included in the final systems map of this study, while the effect of experience on income is through a longer chain.
ExperienceJob changes-
EducationHealth+Several non-monetary benefits of education are listed by Becker. In this study’s final maps, they are included as health benefits, fertility rates, and civic duty.Michael, 1972 [55], Becker, 1994 [18]
EducationSmoking-
EducationPropensity to vote+
Educationbirth control knowledge+
EducationAppreciation of art+
Parents’ spending on educationInvestment in education+These drivers of enrolment rates are aggregated into the link between income (Average annual gross earnings per FT employee), education spending and education enrolment.Becker. 1994 [18]
Government loansInvestment in education+
Parents’ incomeParents’ spending on education+
Number of children (household size)Parents’ spending on education-
EducationAdoption of technology+Represented by the link between Mean Years of Schooling and Labor productivity.
Adoption of technologyProductivity+
IncomeInvestment in health+Represented by the link between Average annual gross earnings per FT employee and Access to health services.
EducationLife expectancy+Mean years of schooling (MYS) above age 15 is a better indicator of life expectancy than income. Represented by the link between MYS, Health and life expectancy in Figure 3b.Lutz and Kebede, 2018 [46]
Human capital stock in the workforce populationEconomic productivity growth+Represented by the link between Human capital and Economic productivity growth in Figure 3a.Stonawski, 2008 [37]
Number of owners of human capitalNational human capital stock+
ExperienceIndividual human capital+We take the Experience, Adult skills, Health and MYS (as a proxy of knowledge) into account to represent these components of Human capital.Healy and Côté [56], Stonawski [37]
Knowledge+
Health+
Personality+
skills+
Adult literacy ratesNational human capital stock+These are historically considered proxies of human capital, with an output-based and education-based approach. According to the OECD framework, we take Educational attainment and Mean years of schooling as the drivers of national Human capital.Stonawski [37]
School enrolment ratios+
Educational attainment+
Average years of schooling+
Learning during formal educationIndividual human capital+We aggregate these factors into: i. Adult skills increased by knowledge and skills gained through schooling (Figure 3a) ii. Adult skills decreased by obsolescence (Figure 3b), iii. Adult skills decreased by forgetting (Figure 3b) and iv. Human capital increased by experience (Figure 4)Stonawski [37]
Acquiring knowledge during professional life+
Acquiring experience during professional life+
Obsolescence rate of knowledge-
Forgetting knowledge-
Duration of working lifeParticipating in life-long learning activities +These factors are aggregated into the effect of Life expectancy on the duration of working life, then Experience, then Human capital, since the detailed explanation of different types of skills and mental abilities are too detailed for the scope and purpose of this study.Fürnkranz-Prskawetz and Lindh [57], Stonawski [37]
Performing actions, duties and work +
ExperienceEfficiency, competence, productivity+
Fluid mental abilities of an individualAcquiring knowledge during professional life+Park, Lautenschlager [42], Stonawski [37]
Acquiring experience during professional life+
Crystallized mental abilities of an individualAcquiring knowledge during professional life+
Acquiring experience during professional life+
Technological progressObsolescence rate of knowledge+Different knowledge and skills depreciate at different paces. It is not possible to look at such differences at an aggregate level. Still, Stonawski assumes that depreciation rates of higher education levels are higher. For instance, the human capital of a tertiary education graduate depreciates 8 times faster than that of a primary education graduates does. This relationship is represented by the links between MYS, Obsolescence rate and Adult skills (Figure 3b).Park, Shin [58], Stonawski [37]
Individual human capital due to formal educationObsolescence rate of knowledge+
Memory retentionForgetting knowledge-Aggregated into the positive relationship between the Duration of working life and Forgetting rate, and the negative relationship between Forgetting and Adult skills (Figure 3b).Stonawski [37]
Duration of working lifeMemory retention-
Human CapitalLabor quality (short term productivity) More recently, further research on economic growth, represented by the so-called “new growth” models (e.g. Lucas, 1988; Romer, 1990a; Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995), has argued that investment in human capital does notjust improve labour quality at a point in time, but can also lead to technological progress and innovation, i.e., positive “externalities” that increase the productivity of other factors. Therefore, while MYS increases labor productivity, Human Capital stimulates overall economic productivity growth (Figure 3a).Boarini et al., 2012 [59]
Human CapitalTechnological progress and innovation
Mean years of schoolingIncome+Represented through the link between MYS, labor productivity and Average earnings per FT employee.Lutz [16]
Young education levelThe speed of economic growth+Not only the economic growth but also the speed of growth is affected by human capital. More specifically, education level of the young population and the secondary education attainment level (e.g., not primary education) plays a key role [35]. These specific relationships are, however, left out of the mapping in this study, because the differences between the three education levels (primary, secondary, tertiary) are beyond the scope. Lutz, Cuaresma [35]
Secondary education attainment levelThe speed of economic growth+
Education levelSense of civic duty+Following Lipset 1959 [52], empirical studies find a positive association between education and democracy [53,60], and that education is a significant and robust determinant of democracy. In this study, we mention these relationship as the links between human capital and social capital components of national well-being. However, we do not explicitly include them in the maps.Lipset [52], Lutz [16]
Sense of civic dutyPolitical interest+
Political interestPolitical participation+
Formal educationExecutive functioning and cognitive abilities+Experimental, observational and neurological studies show that education increases cognitive skills, abstract cognitive skills, reasoning, problem solving and decision making. These are also at the basis of well-established link between education and health. We represent this by the positive links from MYS to Knowledge and skills.Brinch and Galloway [61], Lutz [16]
Health Schooling (inflow of the human capital)+There is a causal effect from Human capital (stock) to Health and Income, but no simultaneous effect in the opposite direction. Income and health can only influence Schooling (flow), which changes average Human capital with a delay of several decades. Therefore, we represent these relationships with the links from Average annual earnings to education spending, then to education enrolment. (Figure 3a)Lutz [16]
Household incomeSchooling (inflow of the human capital)+
national economic growthSchooling (inflow of the human capital)+
Human capital (educational attainment)Health-related behavior+
Human capital (educational attainment)Economic productivity/income+
Environmental factors (air pollution)Cognitive development-Exemplifying the effect of depleting natural capital on human capital formation. Represented by the link between Exposure to PM2.5 air pollution, Health and Cognitive skills at age 15 (Figure 4).Grandjean and Landrigan [47], Lutz [16]
Mother’s educationChild mortality-Both within families and within communities in developing countries, mother’s education level is a stronger factor than income that affects child mortality. In this study, represented by a link between total young adult educational attainment (not only female) and mortality rates (Figure A1).Pamuk, Fuchs [51], Lutz [16]
Household incomeChild mortality-
Education levelMental activities at high ages ~Cognitive capacity+These relationships refer to another dimension of positive link between Education and Life expectancy, through higher mental activities in addition to better health practices and access to health services. They are aggregated in the links between MYS, Health and Life expectancy (Figure 3b).Lutz [16]
Mental activities at high agesLife expectancy+
HealthLabor productivity+While the Health and Labor productivity link is included directly (Figure 3a), the others are represented by the links between Health, Cognitive development and Cognitive skills at age 15 (Figure 4).
Childhood healthSchool attendance+
Childhood healthCognitive development+
Economic growthHigher educational attainment+These specific drivers of high (tertiary) education are left out since the differentiation of different education levels are not considered in this study.
Household incomeHigher education enrollment+
Education levelFertility rate-Represented by the link between Young adult educational attainment and Fertility rates (Figure A1)

References

  1. Merriam-Webster. Well-Being. 2019. Available online: https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/well-being (accessed on 7 January 2019).
  2. Crisp, R. Well-Being. In The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy; 2017; Available online: https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/fall2017/entries/well-being/. (accessed on 1 October 2019).
  3. Costanza, R.; Kubiszewski, I.; Giovannini, E.; Lovins, H.; McGlade, J.; Pickett, K.E.; Ragnarsdóttir, K.V.; Roberts, D.; De Vogli, R.; Wilkinson, R. Development: Time to leave GDP behind. Nat. News 2014, 505, 283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  4. Haavard Maridal, J.; Palich, L.; Morgan, G.; Gardner, S.; McKinney, J.; Bolbocean, C. Wellbeing indices: A comprehensive inventory of standards and a review of current comparative measures. Ecol. Econ. 2018, 149, 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. UNDP. Human Development Indices and Indicators: 2018 Statistical Update; United Nations Development Program: New York, NY, USA, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  6. Jones, R.; Randall, C. Measuring National Well-Being: Quality of Life in the UK; UK Office for National Statistics: London, UK, 2018.
  7. OECD. How’s Life? 2017: Measuring Well-Being; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2017. [Google Scholar]
  8. Sen, A. Commodities and Capabilities; North-Holland Publishing: Amsterdam, The Netherlands, 1985. [Google Scholar]
  9. Sen, A. Capability and Well-Being, In The Quality of Life; Clarendon Press: Oxford, UK, 1993; p. 30. [Google Scholar]
  10. Nussbaum, M.; Sen, A. The Quality of Life; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 1993. [Google Scholar]
  11. Anand, P.; Hunter, G.; Smith, R. Capabilities and well-being: evidence based on the Sen–Nussbaum approach to welfare. Soc. Indic. Res. 2005, 74, 9–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Vemuri, A.W.; Costanza, R. The role of human, social, built, and natural capital in explaining life satisfaction at the country level: Toward a National Well-Being Index (NWI). Ecol. Econ. 2006, 58, 119–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Costanza, R.; Daly, L.; Fioramonti, L.; Giovannini, E.; Kubiszewski, I.; Mortensen, L.F.; Pickett, K.E.; Ragnarsdottir, K.V.; De Vogli, R.; Wilkinson, R. Modelling and measuring sustainable wellbeing in connection with the UN Sustainable Development Goals. Ecol. Econ. 2016, 130, 350–355. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Zhang, S.; Liu, B.; Zhu, D.; Cheng, M. Explaining Individual Subjective Well-Being of Urban China Based on the Four-Capital Model. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3480. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Costanza, R.; Fisher, B.; Ali, S.; Beer, C.; Bond, L.; Boumans, R.; Danigelis, N.L.; Dickinson, J.; Elliott, C.; Farley, J.; et al. Quality of life: An approach integrating opportunities, human needs, and subjective well-being. Ecol. Econ. 2007, 61, 267–276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Lutz, W. Global Sustainable Development priorities 500 y after Luther: Sola schola et sanitate. Natl. Acad. Sci. 2017, 114, 6904–6913. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Keeley, B. Human Capital: How What You Know Shapes Your Life; OECD Insights: Paris, France, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  18. Becker, G.S. Human Capital Revisited. In Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, 3rd ed.; The University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 1994; pp. 15–28. [Google Scholar]
  19. Garrigos-Simon, F.; Botella-Carrubi, M.; Gonzalez-Cruz, T. Social Capital, Human Capital, and Sustainability: A Bibliometric and Visualization Analysis. Sustainability 2018, 10, 4751. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  20. Durand, M. The OECD better life initiative: How’s life? and the measurement of well-being. Rev. Income Wealth 2015, 61, 4–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. OECD. Chapter 3: Resources for Future Well-Being. In How’s Life? 2015: Measuring Well-Being; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2015. [Google Scholar]
  22. Sterman, J.D. Business Dynamics: Systems Thinking and Modeling for a Complex World; Irwin/McGraw-Hill: Boston, MA, USA, 2000; p. 982. [Google Scholar]
  23. Sedlacko, M.; Martinuzzi, A.; Røpke, I.; Videira, N.; Antunes, P. Participatory systems mapping for sustainable consumption: Discussion of a method promoting systemic insights. Ecol. Econ. 2014, 106, 33–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  24. Yawson, R.M.; Kuzma, J. Systems Mapping of Consumer Acceptance of Agrifood Nanotechnology. J. Consum. Policy 2010, 33, 299–322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Eker, S.; Zimmermann, N. Understanding the Mechanisms behind Fragmentation in the Housing Construction and Retrofit. In Proceedings of the 34th International Conference of the System Dynamics Society, Delft, The Netherlands, 17–21 July 2016. [Google Scholar]
  26. Eker, S.; Zimmermann, N.; Carnohan, S.; Davies, M. Participatory system dynamics modelling for housing, energy and wellbeing interactions. Build. Res. Inf. 2017, 46, 738–754. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Berry, H.L.; Waite, T.D.; Dear, K.B.; Capon, A.G.; Murray, V. The case for systems thinking about climate change and mental health. Nat. Clim. Chang. 2018, 8, 282–290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Strauss, A.; Corbin, J. Basics of Qualitative Research; Sage: Thousand Oaks, CA, USA, 1990; Volume 15. [Google Scholar]
  29. Luna-Reyes, L.F.; Andersen, D.L. Collecting and analyzing qualitative data for system dynamics: methods and models. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 2003, 19, 271–296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Kopainsky, B.; Luna-Reyes, L.F. Closing the loop: promoting synergies with other theory building approaches to improve system dynamics practice. Syst. Res. Behav. Sci. 2008, 25, 471–486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Kim, H.; Andersen, D.F. Building confidence in causal maps generated from purposive text data: mapping transcripts of the Federal Reserve. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 2012, 28, 311–328. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Turner, B.L.; Kim, H.; Andersen, D.F. Improving coding procedures for purposive text data: Researchable questions for qualitative system dynamics modeling. Syst. Dyn. Rev. 2013, 29, 253–263. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Yearworth, M.; White, L. The uses of qualitative data in multimethodology: Developing causal loop diagrams during the coding process. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2013, 231, 151–161. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  34. Eker, S.; Zimmermann, N. Using textual data in system dynamics model conceptualization. Systems 2016, 4, 28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  35. Lutz, W.; Cuaresma, J.C.; Sanderson, W. The Demography of Educational Attainment and Economic Growth. Science 2008, 319, 1047–1048. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  36. Boarini, R.; Comola, M.; Smith, C.; Manchin, R.; De Keulenaer, F. The determinants of subjective well-being in OECD countries—Evidence from the Gallup World Poll. What Makes for a Better Life; OECD: Paris, France, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  37. Stonawski, M. Influence of Workforce Ageing on Human Capital Formation. In IIASA Interim Report; IIASA: Laxenburg, Austria, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  38. Cuaresma, J.C.; Mishra, T. Human capital, age structure and growth fluctuations. Appl. Econ. 2011, 43, 4311–4329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Friedberg, R.M. You Can’t Take It with You? Immigrant Assimilation and the Portability of Human Capital. J. Labor Econ. 2000, 18, 221–251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  40. Lutz, W.; Kc, S. Global human capital: Integrating education and population. Science 2011, 333, 587–592. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  41. Portes, A. Migration and development: Reconciling opposite views. Ethn. Racial Stud. 2009, 32, 5–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Park, D.C.; Lautenschlager, G.; Hedden, T.; Davidson, N.S.; Smith, A.D.; Smith, P.K. Models of visuospatial and verbal memory across the adult life span. Psychol. Aging 2002, 17, 299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Skirbekk, V. Age and Individual Productivity: A Literature Survey. Vienna Yearb. Popul. Res. 2004, 2, 133–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  44. Caselli, G.; Drefahl, S.; Wegner-Siegmundt, C.; Luy, M. Future Mortality in Low Mortality Countries. In World Population and Human Capital in the Twenty-First Century; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  45. Currie, J. Healthy, wealthy, and wise: Socioeconomic status, poor health in childhood, and human capital development. J. Econ. Lit. 2009, 47, 87–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  46. Lutz, W.; Kebede, E. Education and Health: Redrawing the Preston Curve. Popul. Dev. Rev. 2018, 44, 343–361. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Grandjean, P.; Landrigan, P.J. Neurobehavioural effects of developmental toxicity. Lancet Neurol. 2014, 13, 330–338. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  48. Skirbekk, V. Fertility trends by social status. Demogr. Res. 2008, 18, 145–180. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Fuchs, R.; Goujon, A. Future Fertility in High Fertility Countries; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  50. Abel, G.J.; Barakat, B.; Samir, K.C.; Lutz, W. Meeting the Sustainable Development Goals leads to lower world population growth. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2016, 113, 14294–14299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  51. Pamuk, E.R.; Fuchs, R.; Lutz, W. Comparing relative effects of education and economic resources on infant mortality in developing countries. Popul. Dev. Rev. 2011, 37, 637–664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  52. Lipset, S.M. Some social requisites of democracy: Economic development and political legitimacy. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 1959, 53, 69–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Glaeser, E.L.; Ponzetto, G.A.; Shleifer, A. Why does democracy need education? J. Econ. Growth 2007, 12, 77–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  54. Barro, R.J. Democracy and growth. J. Econ. Growth 1996, 1, 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Michael, R.T. The Effect of Education on Efficiency in Consumption; National Bureau of Economic Research: New York, NY, USA, 1972; pp. 3–6. [Google Scholar]
  56. Healy, T.; Côté, S. The Well-Being of Nations: The Role of Human and Social Capital. Education and Skills; OECD: Paris, France, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  57. Fürnkranz-Prskawetz, A.; Lindh, T. The Impact of Ageing on Innovation and Productivity Growth in Europe; Vienna Institute of Demography, Austrian Academy of Sciences: Vienna, Austria, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  58. Park, G.; Shin, J.; Park, Y. Measurement of depreciation rate of technological knowledge: Technology cycle time approach. J. Sci. Ind. Res. 2006, 65, 121–127. [Google Scholar]
  59. Boarini, R.; Comola, M.; Smith, C.; Manchin, R.; De Keulenaer, F. What Makes for a Better Life? The Determinants of Subjective Well-Being in OECD Countries–Evidence from the Gallup World Poll; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  60. Lutz, W.; Cuaresma, J.C.; Abbasi-Shavazi, M.J. Demography, education, and democracy: Global trends and the case of Iran. Popul. Dev. Rev. 2010, 36, 253–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Brinch, C.N.; Galloway, T.A. Schooling in adolescence raises IQ scores. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2012, 109, 425–430. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
Figure 1. Decomposition of the OECD well-being measures framework. The upper part of the figure shows the current well-being indicators, whereas the lower part decomposes the future well-being. The green rectangles depict the current well-being indicators, while yellow boxes refer to the stocks for future well-being. The flow indicators of the four capitals are marked by pentagons and special risks by red ovals. The future indicators with green rim are also an indicator of current well-being, i.e., they are among both future and current well-being indicators.
Figure 1. Decomposition of the OECD well-being measures framework. The upper part of the figure shows the current well-being indicators, whereas the lower part decomposes the future well-being. The green rectangles depict the current well-being indicators, while yellow boxes refer to the stocks for future well-being. The flow indicators of the four capitals are marked by pentagons and special risks by red ovals. The future indicators with green rim are also an indicator of current well-being, i.e., they are among both future and current well-being indicators.
Sustainability 12 01931 g001
Figure 2. Overview of the systems mapping approach.
Figure 2. Overview of the systems mapping approach.
Sustainability 12 01931 g002
Figure 3. Map of the human capital subsystem related to educational attainment. (a) Positive (reinforcing) feedback loops, (b) negative (balancing) feedback loops. The green boxes refer to the indicators of current well-being, yellow boxes are for future indicators, and yellow boxes with green rim represent both current and future indicators.
Figure 3. Map of the human capital subsystem related to educational attainment. (a) Positive (reinforcing) feedback loops, (b) negative (balancing) feedback loops. The green boxes refer to the indicators of current well-being, yellow boxes are for future indicators, and yellow boxes with green rim represent both current and future indicators.
Sustainability 12 01931 g003
Figure 4. Map of the human capital subsystem related to health. The red circles represent the ‘risks’ for future well-being.
Figure 4. Map of the human capital subsystem related to health. The red circles represent the ‘risks’ for future well-being.
Sustainability 12 01931 g004
Table 1. The Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) indicators (Better Life Index) related to human capital and their definitions.
Table 1. The Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) indicators (Better Life Index) related to human capital and their definitions.
IndicatorCategoryDefinition
Educational attainmentStockPercentage of people aged 25–64 with at least an upper secondary education
Adult skillsStockMean proficiency in literacy and numeracy of the population aged 16–65
Cognitive skills at age 15StockMean score for reading, mathematics and science of 15-year-old students
Young adult educational attainmentStockPercentage of population aged 25–34 who have attained at least an upper secondary education
Life expectancy at birthStockNumber of years that a newborn can expect to live
Smoking prevalenceRiskPercentage of people aged 15 and over who report smoking every day
Obesity prevalenceRiskPercentage of the population aged 15 and older diagnosed with obesity
Long-term unemploymentRiskPercentage of the labour force unemployed for one year or more

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Eker, S.; Ilmola-Sheppard, L. Systems Thinking to Understand National Well-Being from a Human Capital Perspective. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1931. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12051931

AMA Style

Eker S, Ilmola-Sheppard L. Systems Thinking to Understand National Well-Being from a Human Capital Perspective. Sustainability. 2020; 12(5):1931. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12051931

Chicago/Turabian Style

Eker, Sibel, and Leena Ilmola-Sheppard. 2020. "Systems Thinking to Understand National Well-Being from a Human Capital Perspective" Sustainability 12, no. 5: 1931. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12051931

APA Style

Eker, S., & Ilmola-Sheppard, L. (2020). Systems Thinking to Understand National Well-Being from a Human Capital Perspective. Sustainability, 12(5), 1931. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12051931

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop