Uncertainties Influencing Transportation System Performances
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Risk and Uncertainty
2.1. Conceptual Clarifications
2.2. Uncertainties in the Dynamics of Transportation System Performance
- Events with exogenous sources (e.g., some inconsistency of size and structure of tasks/transport demand) and endogenous causes (e.g., deviations from the scheduled operation to ensure the expected performance of the transportation system); these are related to short periods and do not involve decisions on a considerable extension of or reduction in the resources of the transportation system.
- Events leading to severe changes in the components of the transportation system; these could occur over longer time horizons, due, for example, to significant technological progress and/or the dynamics of the territorial system that determine important changes in transport demand (for a particular mode of transport or the whole system).
- All components and activities of the territorial system, and, consequently, they can impact the transportation system—these changes define systemic socio-economic uncertainties, or
- Only the transportation system as a whole or only specific modes of transport—these types of change define non-systemic socio-economic uncertainties and are recorded on long time horizons, in solid correlation with the lifetime of the material resources of the transportation system.
3. Materials and Methods
3.1. Holistic Examination of Technical Infrastructures
- Economic risks—are generated because technical networks require significant investments and are components of a competitive system subject to intense strategic pressures (financial and economic).
- Social risks—are caused by the fact that: (i) technical networks are used in ways that vary spatiotemporally, depending on the beneficiary requests, and (ii) employee actions can temporarily affect the system’s operation and, consequently, network performances.
- Technical risks—start from the dependencies between the different types of networks, technical degradation of the equipment, or technological failures.
- Political risks—are caused by flow detour due to political conflicts.
- Human risks—are caused by possible acts of sabotage or terrorism.
- Organizational risks—are assigned to dysfunctions caused by lack of information, professional deficiencies, delays in decision-making, etc.
3.2. Including Sensitive Aspects in the Evaluation of Traffic Infrastructure Investment Projects
- Legitimacy—i.e., clarifying to policymakers the importance of strict compliance to the results of sophisticated calculations of the effectiveness and efficiency of traffic infrastructure investments. It remains questionable to what extent CBA results are implemented in decision-making. Usually, socio-economic evaluations of projects cannot substitute political decisions.
- Credibility—refers to the ability to eliminate nonconfidence regarding the correctness of the traffic infrastructure investment assessments, considering the not unanimous opinions on the used discount rate.
- Acceptability—refers to one of the fundamental hypotheses for computing the surplus as an algebraic sum of the surpluses of all those affected by the project. At least two issues need to be addressed: the first refers to spatial equity and the second to social equity.
- Considering risk and uncertainty—noting that recent methodologies for public investment substantiation distinguish between risks specific to a project and uncertainties related to exogenous project events, which are incorporated into the discount rate.
- Budget insufficiency—is a systemic and fundamental problem. Public power cannot finance all of the projects recommended by economic assessments. Lack of confidence in calculations indicating overvalued discounted benefits or major risks may cause non-financing. However, budgetary financial resources are not limited to investments in traffic infrastructure but apply to all public investments. Decapitalization generated by large investments in traffic infrastructure can inhibit investment in other economic sectors.
- Differentiated discount rates depending on the type of investment project are generally not recommended. The above examples show that differentiated values are applied only in France (although the uncertainties in the investment project benefits and costs also essentially depend on the project type) [27].
4. Results
4.1. Examination of Major Changes in the Socio-Economic Environment
4.2. Investment Strategies Affected by Uncertainties in Traffic Dynamics, Size, and Structure
- increasing the speed of trains by modernizing the single-track infrastructure;
- changing the traction system;
- doubling of portions (partial) of a single line;
- total doubling of the line over the entire envisaged section.
- S1: I–II–III–IV
- S2: I–II–IV
- S3: I–III–IV
- S4: I–IV.
5. Discussion
- Changes in the system of activities that generate transport demands cannot be identified only based on GDP variation.
- The quasi-continuous decline in railway activity (especially in some Eastern European countries) could be considered a major shock, caused by radical changes in socio-economic life structure and dimensions. No timely and correctly oriented solutions have been found.
- Road transport (as well as air transport), being much more flexible, proved to show a better and faster adaptation. Consequently, road transport share has considerably increased in the land transport market. Undoubtedly, the gained position also results from an insufficiently regulated modal competition, an unpredictable market, and non-performant management at all railway administration levels (regardless of the organizational metamorphosis and the consultancy services).
- The traffic forecast for a railway section is often uncertain. In the case of a mixed-use conventional railway line (for freight and passenger trains), the uncertainty is generated by the difficult prediction of both the number of freight trains and the number of passenger trains over a longer time horizon and the number of investment measures. The analysis of the combination of an uncertain needed number of trains over the T horizon and several investment measures (with technical logic) also includes the uncertainty related to the methodological CBA parameters as well as the risk of lower or higher traffic flows due to the lack of accurate predictions of general socio-economic variation.
- Moreover, the decision on the most appropriate moments for additional capacity deployment is even more ambiguous because of the necessity for rare interventions into infrastructure (i.e., works on transport infrastructure generate negative social and environmental impacts during implementation). The question of which option is the best—(i) more frequent intervention in infrastructure for smaller additional capacity deployment or, on the contrary, (ii) rare interventions for larger additional capacity, even if this will be unused for a longer time—has no certain response.
- Even if decision-making models under the risk and uncertainty conditions were elaborated, ambiguity, especially regarding the strategies of large investment in the long term, is not completely eliminated, and more research is needed toward this aim.
6. Conclusions
- Transportation system performances depend on the functional characteristics of its components, the implemented technology, and the size, structure, and spatiotemporal attributes of the demands generated by the socio-economic activities of the territorial system. In the short term, the variation of demands addressed to the system involves operational and tactical management actions aiming to meet the beneficiary requirements with the most judicious use of system resources. In the medium and long term, the estimated dynamics of the demands addressed to the system involve strategic management actions aiming to adapt the system resources to the estimated tasks.
- All operational, tactical, and strategical decisions for any complex technical system, such as transportation systems, are affected by indetermination (categorized as uncertainties and risks). Therefore, decision-makers cannot affirm that their decisions, in the perceived concrete circumstances, are the optimum ones.
- Uncertainties, unforeseen random events (indicated as “unknown unknowns”), are: (i) methodological—differentiated or non-systemic—and (ii) socio-economic—undifferentiated or systemic. There is always a certain level of uncertainty in the operation and design of any transportation system or modal subsystem. Uncertainty increases as the complexity of the system increases. The more interacting parts a system includes, the more its complexity increases. The unitary approach to technical infrastructure confirms the existence of greater uncertainty encountered in developing the aggregate of the general technical infrastructure and each modal transport infrastructure.
- Appropriate differentiation must be made in assigning the responsibility for the negative consequences of exogenous and endogenous risks. The risks, which also impact transportation system performances, are random events but in a known probabilistic sense (“known unknowns”). They are generated inside or outside the system. In the case of exogenous risks, the magnitude of the consequences is interpreted as the individual and collective responsibility of those involved in design, construction, and administration, while in the case of endogenous events (anthropogenic type), both the probability of adverse events and their consequences are assigned to a wide, diverse range of stakeholders in the technical, economic, social, political, and organizational domains. Such responsibility in case of uncertainties cannot be dissociated.
- Both uncertainties and risks affect transportation system performances over time. Therefore, reports include average values over longer periods but do not include uncertainty and risk effects.
- Avoiding uncertainty should not be confused with avoiding risk. Uncertainty, as opposed to risk, is not linked to probability. It is the situation in which anything can happen. The decision-maker is completely unaware of the future. As soon as uncertainty is expressed as a risk, it stops being a source of concern. The decision-maker can include it in the analysis, considering the negative consequences of the event in a probabilistic way.
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Raicu, S. Transportation Systems; AGIR Press: Bucharest, Romania, 2007. (In Romanian) [Google Scholar]
- Gilboa, I. Theory of Decision under Uncertainty, 1st ed.; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2009. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ulansky, V.; Raza, A. Generalization of minimax and maximin criteria in a game against nature for the case of a partial a priori uncertainty. Heliyon 2021, 7, e07498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Hayhurst, G. A criterion for decision-making when supplied with extra, imperfect information as to the opponent’s intentions. Oper. Res. Q. 1973, 24, 117–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Knight, F.H. Risk, Uncertainty and Profit; Reprint of 1921 Edition; Martino Fine Books: Mansfield Centre, CT, USA, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Walker, W.E.; Marchau, V.A.W.J. Dynamic adaptive policymaking for the sustainable city: The case of automated taxis. Int. J. Transp. Sci. Technol. 2017, 6, 1–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Marchau, V.A.W.J.; Walker, W.E.; van Wee, G.P. Dynamic adaptive transport policies for handling deep uncertainty. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Chang. 2010, 77, 940–950. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Walker, W.E.; Rahman, S.; Cave, J. Adaptive policies, policy analysis, and policy-making. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2001, 128, 282–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ghiani, G.; Laporte, G.; Musmanno, R. Introduction to Logistics Systems Management, 2nd ed.; Wiley: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Raicu, R.; Raicu, S. Transport demand, transport and traffic flow—Key elements of city logistics. In Logistics Systems for Sustainable Cities; Taniguchi, E., Thompson, R.G., Eds.; Emerald Group Publishing Limited: Bingley, UK, 2004; pp. 37–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cutter, S.L. The changing context of hazard extremes: Events, impacts, and consequences. J. Extrem. Events 2016, 3, 1671005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cantillo, V.; Macea, L.F.; Jaller, M. Assessing vulnerability of transportation networks for disaster response operations. Netw. Spat. Econ. 2019, 19, 243–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Papilloud, T.; Keiler, M. Vulnerability patterns of road network to extreme floods based on accessibility measures. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2021, 100, 103045. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jenelius, E.; Mattsson, L.-G. Road network vulnerability analysis: Conceptualization, implementation and application. Comput. Environ. Urban Syst. 2015, 49, 136–147. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cutter, S.L.; Barnes, L.; Berry, M.; Burton, C.; Evans, E.; Tate, E.; Webb, J. A place-based model for understanding community resilience to natural disasters. Glob. Environ. Chang. 2008, 18, 598–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Maravas, A.; Pantouvakis, J.-P. Guidelines for modelling time and cost uncertainty in project and programme management. Procedia-Soc. Behav. Sci. 2013, 74, 203–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- European Commission, Directorate-General for Regional and Urban Policy. Guide to Cost-Benefit Analysis of Investment Projects Economic Appraisal Tool for Cohesion Policy 2014–2020; Publications Office: Luxembourg, 2015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Padalkar, M.; Gopinath, S. Are complexity and uncertainty distinct concepts in project management? A taxonomical examination from literature. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2016, 34, 688–700. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- López, F.J.R.; Cacheda, J.M.C.; Marchán, S.S. Criteria for optimizing a road network. Transp. Res. Procedia 2021, 58, 119–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Raicu, S.; Costescu, D. Mobility. Traffic Infrastructures; AGIR Press: Bucharest, Romania, 2020. (In Romanian) [Google Scholar]
- Donais, F.M.; Abi-Zeid, I.; Waygood, E.O.D.; Lavoie, R. A review of cost–benefit analysis and multicriteria decision analysis from the perspective of sustainable transport in project evaluation. EURO J. Decis. Process. 2019, 7, 327–358. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Annema, J.A.; Frenken, K.; Koopmans, C.; Kroesen, M. Relating cost-benefit analysis results with transport project decisions in the Netherlands. Lett. Spat. Resour. Sci. 2017, 10, 109–127. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Maurice, J.; Crozet, Y.; Abraham, C.; Gaudry, M.; Ivaldi, M.; Vibes, C.; Gollier, C.; Andrieu, L.; De Palma, A.; Picard, N.; et al. Le calcul économique dans le processus de choix collectif des investissements de transport. In Collection Méthodes et Approches; Brun, G., Ed.; Economica: Paris, France, 2007. [Google Scholar]
- Klibanoff, P.; Marinacci, M.; Mukerji, S. A smooth model of decision making under ambiguity. Econometrica 2005, 73, 1849–1892. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Klibanoff, P.; Marinacci, M.; Mukerji, S. On the smooth ambiguity model: A reply. Econometrica 2012, 80, 1303–1321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cubitt, R.; van de Kuilen, G.; Mukerji, S. The strength of sensitivity to ambiguity. Theory Decis. 2018, 85, 275–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Adapting Transport to Climate Change and Extreme Weather: Implications for Infrastructure Owners and Network Managers; ITF Research Reports; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2016. [CrossRef]
- Farber, D.A. Gambling over growth: Economic uncertainty, discounting, and regulatory policy. J. Leg. Stud. 2015, 44, S509–S528. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gollier, C. Discounting and growth. Am. Econ. Rev. 2014, 104, 534–537. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Traeger, C.P. Discounting under Uncertainty: Disentangling the Weitzman and the Gollier Effect; CUDARE Working Paper No. 1121; University of California, Berkeley: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gollier, C.; Weitzman, M.L. How should the distant future be discounted when discount rates are uncertain? Econ. Lett. 2010, 107, 350–353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gollier, C.; Hammitt, J.K. The long-run discount rate controversy. Annu. Rev. Resour. Econ. 2014, 6, 273–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Kumar, A.; Ramesh, A. An MCDM framework for assessment of social sustainability indicators of the freight transport industry under uncertainty. A multi-company perspective. J. Enterp. Inf. Manag. 2020, 33, 1023–1058. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Armitage, S. Discount rates for long-term projects: The cost of capital and social discount rate compared. Eur. J. Financ. 2017, 23, 60–79. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Weitzman, M.L. Rare Disasters, Tail-Hedged Investments, and Risk-Adjusted Discount Rates; NBER Working Paper No. w18496; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hultkrantz, L.; Krüger, N.; Mantalos, P. Risk-Adjusted Long Term Social Rates of Discount for Transportation Infrastructure Investment; Working Papers 14/2012; Örebro University School of Business: Örebro, Sweden, 2012; Available online: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/244488 (accessed on 4 April 2022).
- ITF. ITF Transport Outlook 2021; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Terrill, M.; Batrouney, H. Unfreezing Discount Rates: Transport Infrastructure for Tomorrow; Grattan Institute Report No. 2018-03; Grattan Institute: Carlton, VIC, Australia, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Arrow, K.J.; Cropper, M.L.; Gollier, C.; Groom, B.; Heal, G.M.; Newell, R.G.; Nordhaus, W.D.; Pindyck, R.S.; Pizer, W.A.; Portney, P.R.; et al. Should governments use a declining discount rate in project analysis? Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2014, 8, 145–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Arrow, K.; Cropper, M.; Gollier, C.; Groom, B.; Heal, G.; Newell, R.; Nordhaus, W.; Pindyck, R.; Pizer, W.; Portney, P.; et al. Determining benefits and costs for future generations. Science 2013, 341, 349–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Goldmann, K. Time-declining risk-adjusted social discount rates for transport infrastructure planning. Transportation 2019, 46, 17–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cropper, M.L.; Freeman, M.C.; Groom, B.; Pizer, W.A. Declining discount rates. Am. Econ. Rev. 2014, 104, 538–543. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Weitzman, M.L. On the “environmental” discount rate. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1994, 26, 200–209. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Quinet, E. Factoring Sustainable Development into Project Appraisal: A French View; International Transport Forum Discussion Papers 2013/31; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Polasky, S.; Dampha, N.K. Discounting and global environmental change. Annu. Rev. Environ. Resour. 2021, 46, 691–717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kumar, A.; Anbanandam, R. Environmentally responsible freight transport service providers’ assessment under data-driven information uncertainty. J. Enterp. Inf. Manag. 2021, 34, 506–542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Coyle, D. GDP: A Brief but Affectionate History—Revised and Expanded Edition; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Romanian National Institute of Statistics. Available online: https://insse.ro/cms/ro/tags/comunicat-evolutia-pib (accessed on 4 April 2022).
- Eurostat. National Accounts and GDP. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.php?title=National_accounts_and_GDP (accessed on 4 April 2022).
- Romanian National Railway Company (CFR). Railway Strategy. Available online: http://www.cfr.ro/index.php/ct-menu-item-3/ct-menu-item-55/strategia-de-dezvoltare-a-infrastructurii-feroviare (accessed on 5 April 2022).
- Eurostat. Transport Data. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/transport/data/main-tables (accessed on 5 April 2022).
- Armand, L.; Drancourt, M. Plaidoyer Pour l’Avenir; Calmann Levy: Paris, France, 1962. [Google Scholar]
- European Commission. Directorate-General for Mobility and Transport. White Paper on Transport: Roadmap to a Single European Transport Area: Towards a Competitive and Resource Efficient Transport System; Publications Office: Luxembourg, 2011; Available online: https://data.europa.eu/doi/10.2832/30955 (accessed on 4 April 2022).
- European Commission. Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, The Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions Empty. ‘Fit for 55′: Delivering the EU’s 2030 Climate Target on the Way to Climate Neutrality; European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2021. [Google Scholar]
- Giocoli, N. From Wald to savage: Homo economicus becomes a Bayesian statistician. J. Hist. Behav. Sci. 2013, 49, 63–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Gaspars-Wieloch, H. Modifications of the Hurwicz’s decision rule. Cent. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2014, 22, 779–794. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chinnakum, W.; Ramos, L.B.; Iyiola, O.; Kreinovich, V. Decision making under interval uncertainty: Toward (somewhat) more convincing justifications for Hurwicz optimism-pessimism approach. Asian J. Econ. Bank. 2021, 5, 32–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Decision Variant, Si | Np(k) | Np(1) | Np(2) | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Ng(j) | Ng(1) | Ng(2) | Ng(3) | Ng(1) | Ng(2) | Ng(3) | ||
S1 | 319.9 | 292.9 | 250.0 | 324.0 | 296.5 | 258.1 | 324.0 | |
S2 | 325.6 | 293.4 | 254.2 | 327.4 | 295.6 | 257.9 | 327.4 | |
S3 | 329.2 | 292.3 | 259.2 | 331.9 | 293.6 | 262.9 | 331.9 | |
S4 | 342.0 | 307.6 | 262.4 | 340.3 | 307.5 | 274.1 | -* |
Decision Variant, Si | Np(k) | Np(1) | Np(2) | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Ng(j) | Ng(1) | Ng(2) | Ng(3) | Ng(1) | Ng(2) | Ng(3) | ||
S1 | 0.00 | 0.60 | 0.00 | 0.00 | 2.90 | 0.20 | 2.90 | |
S2 | 5.70 | 1.11 | 4.20 | 3.40 | 2.00 | 0.00 | 5.70 | |
S3 | 9.30 | 0.00 | 9.20 | 7.90 | 0.00 | 5.00 | 9.30 |
Decision Variant, Si | Np(k) | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Ng(j) | α = 0.0 | α = 0.2 | α = 0.3 | α = 0.5 | α≠ 1.0 | |||
S1 | 324.0 | 250.0 | 250.0 | 264.8 | 272.2 | 287.0 | 324.0 | |
S2 | 327.4 | 254.2 | 254.2 | 268.8 | 276.2 | 290.8 | 327.4 | |
S3 | 331.9 | 259.2 | 259.2 | 273.7 | 281.0 | 295.6 | 331.9 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Raicu, S.; Popa, M.; Costescu, D. Uncertainties Influencing Transportation System Performances. Sustainability 2022, 14, 7660. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14137660
Raicu S, Popa M, Costescu D. Uncertainties Influencing Transportation System Performances. Sustainability. 2022; 14(13):7660. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14137660
Chicago/Turabian StyleRaicu, Serban, Mihaela Popa, and Dorinela Costescu. 2022. "Uncertainties Influencing Transportation System Performances" Sustainability 14, no. 13: 7660. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14137660
APA StyleRaicu, S., Popa, M., & Costescu, D. (2022). Uncertainties Influencing Transportation System Performances. Sustainability, 14(13), 7660. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14137660