1. Introduction
As one of the most important modes of transportation, air transport has significantly contributed to the convenient travel of passengers and cargo. Air transport has played a significant role in fostering economic and cultural exchanges between regions, making airports key hubs for global resource allocation. However, while airports foster economic and cultural exchanges between regions, they also lead to issues, such as resource waste and environmental pollution. The fundamental reason for these issues is that the goal of airport development is to maximize economic benefits. This development strategy is no longer able to meet the green development requirements of the air transport industry [
1]. According to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change (IPCC), aviation has contributed 13% of greenhouse gas emissions over the past five decades, significantly increasing the global surface temperatures [
2]. To promote the green development of the aviation industry, the International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) convened the Report of The High-Level Meeting on The Feasibility of A Long-Term Aspirational Goal for International Aviation CO
2 Emissions Reductions (HLM-LTAG) in 2022 [
3]. This meeting aims to achieve the aspirational goal of net-zero carbon emissions from international aviation by 2050, with an annual fuel efficiency improvement of 2%. Although aviation emissions primarily originate from fuel combustion in aircraft during the take-off, landing, and cruise phases, airport operations still contribute approximately 15% of total aviation emissions [
4]. The greening of airports plays a crucial role in the sustainability initiatives of the aviation industry. Consequently, the Civil Aviation Administration of China (CAAC) has formulated the Guidelines for Green Airport Planning [
5], proposing the construction of green airports that are “resource-saving, environmentally friendly, operationally efficient, and people-centered” throughout their life cycle. This involves transforming airport development from focusing on economic efficiency to being oriented towards sustainable development.
A green airport should be characterized by energy conservation, environmental protection, strong social public welfare, and robust sustainability. However, due to the large investment required, the difficulty of evaluation, and the long payback period, it is challenging for airports to undertake green development and construction independently. They also struggle to bear the risk of green transition while experiencing a loss of revenue [
6]. Therefore, the green transition in airport development necessitates the synergistic cooperation of multiple stakeholders. In the initial stage of the green transition, government departments should monitor and evaluate green airport development and provide policy support and subsidies [
7]. As the green transition process progresses, effectively evaluating green development at airports becomes crucial for measuring the transition’s success. To reduce the workload and optimize the functions of the government departments while ensuring the efficiency of the green transition in airport development, the evaluation function for green development should be gradually transferred to third-party organizations. These organizations should develop professional evaluation standards to assess the green development level of airports based on the requirements set forth by government departments [
8]. Therefore, the green transition in airport development is a collaborative process involving airport authorities, third-party organizations, and government departments to achieve the goal of constructing the green airport. In this process, the strategic choices of the three participants directly determine the dynamics and effectiveness of the green transition in airport development [
9].
However, the airport authorities’ willingness to invest in green construction will be hindered due to the information asymmetry in government departments, insufficient reward and punishment mechanisms, and the high evaluation costs of third-party organizations. They may even engage in rent-seeking behavior with third-party organizations driven by their interests, impeding the green transition in airport development [
10]. Existing research on the green transition primarily focuses on the influencing factors of airport development, constructing index systems to comprehensively analyze the level of green development at airports and its evolution trend [
11], and proposes improvement measures for green transition from the perspectives of green development policy [
12] and green technology innovation [
13,
14]. However, these studies have yet to fully consider the impact of the stakeholders’ interests on the green transition in airport development. They need more exploration into the mechanisms by which the strategic choices of each stakeholder affect green airport development, making it difficult to propose actionable strategies for green transition in airport development. With the joint participation of airport authorities, third-party organizations, and government departments, the green transition process of airport development manifests as a strategic game among the three participants. Evolutionary game theory can integrate the interests and strategic evolution of participants to reveal the conditions for achieving dynamic equilibrium through the game [
15]. Therefore, to ensure the smooth progress of green transition in airport development, it is necessary to explore the evolutionary game mechanism between airport authorities and third-party organizations under the leadership of the government departments. Building on this foundation, this paper focuses on the following issues.
(1) In the context of the three-party evolutionary game, what is the stage development trend of the green transition path in airport development? How do the input costs of each party influence the evolutionary game process among the three stakeholders?
(2) In the process of green transition in airport development, should the government departments establish stringent regulations and a system of rewards and penalties?
(3) Is rent-seeking behavior by airport authorities and third-party organizations under government supervision desirable? What are the implications for the long-term goals of airport greening?
This paper constructs a tripartite evolutionary game model for the green transition in airport development by analyzing the interests of airport authorities, third-party organizations, and government departments. The green development characteristics of airports are explored by combining the evolutionary stabilization strategies of various parties and exploring the evolutionary mechanism of green transition in airport development. It fills the gap in existing research, which lacks an analysis of the green development process of airports under the influence of relevant stakeholders from a dynamic perspective, and introduces a new approach to exploring the green transition path in airport development through a tripartite evolutionary game perspective. The rest of the paper is structured as follows:
Section 2 summarizes the current state of research and the effectiveness of efforts towards the green transition in airport development.
Section 3 details the modeling process, and solves the evolutionary game model and explores methods for segmenting the stages of green transition in airport development.
Section 4 employs MATLAB software to numerically model and simulate the green transition path of airport development.
Section 5 summarizes the findings of this paper and offers targeted recommendations for promoting green transition in airport development.
2. Literature Review
In recent years, as the volume of civil aviation has grown rapidly, airports have emerged as significant energy consumers and polluters within the global aviation network. The green transition in airport development has become a prominent issue in sustainable development, as it is essential for constructing green airports and achieving pollution and carbon reduction.
The concept of a “green airport” was first introduced by the U.S.-based Clean Airports Partnership (CAP) in 2005 as part of the Green Airport Initiative (GAI) program. It focuses on seven dimensions of an airport’s environmental footprint and produces an environmental report with specific recommendations for the airport’s green development [
16]. Building on this, the CAAC, in conjunction with the development plan of Chinese airports, summarizes the connotation of a green airport into four aspects: resource-saving, environmentally friendly, operationally efficient, and human-centered [
17]. This aims to provide specific implementation goals and directions for the green transition in airport development. Liang [
18], Wang [
19], and Hu et al. [
20] supplemented and refined the concept of green development of airports by combining real-life cases. They revealed the close relationship between the green transition process of airport development and the sustainability elements of society, economy, environment, and airport operation.
In the green transition in airport development, the quantitative analysis of the level of green development is a prerequisite for developing staged measures and for digitizing and standardizing the green transition process. In recent years, countries worldwide have launched their own green building design and evaluation standards, with the U.S. Leadership in Energy and Environmental Design (LEED) being a prominent example [
21]. China has also successively promulgated standards and specifications, such as the Code for The Green Performance Assessment of Four Characteristic-Airports [
22] and the Green Airport Evaluation Guidelines [
23], to guide the green transition in airport development. Meanwhile, Airports Council International (ACI) has established the Green Airport Recognition (GAR) and Airport Carbon Accreditation (ACA) programs to measure the achievements of airports’ green transition efforts through the classification of environmental themes and certification levels [
24]. Additionally, the comprehensive evaluation and analysis method has been widely used in existing studies assessing the level of green airport development. Li et al. [
25], Wan et al. [
26], and Ramakrishnan et al. [
27] constructed evaluation criteria for green airport development capability by considering various influencing factors. They utilized the gray correlation assessment, the BoD model, and the decision tree method to assess the level of green airport development.
However, the airport greening industry began later than in other industries, and its development foundation is relatively weak. With the civil aviation transportation market’s huge demand potential, energy consumption and pollution emissions at airports will continue to exhibit a rigid growth trend. Therefore, some scholars have conducted research on green transition measures for airport development. Li et al. [
7] used a combination of expert interviews and questionnaires to analyze the main influencing factors of green airport development. They proposed policy recommendations to promote green transition in airport development, focusing on airspace system reform and the coverage of APU alternative facilities. Falk et al. [
28] explored the factors influencing carbon emission reduction at various airports in Europe and provided insights for policymakers on energy conservation and technological advancements. These insights aim to promote carbon emission reduction in the aviation industry and optimize the airport green construction. Some scholars have applied green innovative technologies to terminals [
29], aircraft [
30], and ground equipment [
31] to reduce pollution and carbon emissions at airports. These efforts target both pollution sources and pathways to mitigate resistance to the green transition in airport development.
In summary, existing research addressing the green transition needs of airport development has yielded certain results. It primarily focuses on enhancing the concept of green airport development, quantifying the level of development, and proposing green transition measures and suggestions from the perspectives of green development policies and green innovation technologies. Additionally, national efforts to build green airports are beginning to bear fruit. According to data released by ACI [
32], from 2009 to 2023, a total of 564 airports in 88 countries/regions have obtained ACA certification, with 66 airports achieving advanced carbon emission management levels. These efforts have resulted in a cumulative reduction of 2613 tons of carbon dioxide emissions and have led to the development of numerous energy-saving and environmentally friendly buildings.
However, the construction of green airports continues to face pressures and challenges. Issues such as a weak momentum for green transition, insufficient capacity for independent innovation, imperfect organizational structures, and inadequate constraints and incentives remain prominent [
33]. Therefore, to establish a new pattern of green development through the synergistic participation of airport entities and industry associations under government leadership, it is essential to study the evolutionary game relationships among airport authorities, third-party organizations, and government departments. Evolutionary game theory originally explained the behavior of interspecies struggles during biological evolution [
34]. Subsequently, the application of evolutionary game theory gradually extended to economics, sociology, and statistical physics to analyze the factors influencing the formation of cluster behavior [
35,
36,
37]. As research deepens, some scholars combine evolutionary game theory with complex network theory [
38], cybernetics [
39], and dynamical systems theory [
40] to analyze network games, random games, and repeated game behaviors in cluster evolution, yielding rich and insightful research results. Evolutionary game studies have also been widely applied in the field of green transportation development. Deng et al. [
41] conducted a tripartite evolutionary game study on the strategic choices of the government, ports, and transportation enterprises to provide theoretical references for the construction of green ports. Zhang et al. [
42] constructed a three-party stochastic evolutionary game model involving the administration, major airlines, and minor airlines. They provided guidance for policymakers to effectively regulate airlines’ carbon emission reduction through three different regulatory paths. Building on this, the scholars further analyze four scenarios of tripartite evolutionary stabilization strategies influenced by carbon quota and carbon tax prices, and make recommendations on the implementation of carbon emission reductions [
43].
Overall, there are still some shortcomings in the existing studies, mainly in the following aspects: (1) In terms of research subjects, the focus is relatively narrow, lacking a comprehensive consideration of the multiple stakeholders involved in the green transition in airport development. (2) In terms of research ideas, most existing studies are limited to static viewpoints and lack a dynamic analysis of the green transition process of airport development. (3) In terms of research methodology, most studies focus on either quantitative analysis of the green transition process or qualitative research on guiding policies. Even studies exploring carbon emission reduction measures through evolutionary game theory are typically limited to the perspective of airlines and other relevant corporate entities. These studies often fail to propose effective green transition measures for airports themselves and lack comprehensive and practical research on the governance system of green airports.
To address the shortcomings and deficiencies in existing research, this paper constructs an evolutionary game model involving airport authorities, third-party organizations, and government departments. It explores the green transition path of airport development through tripartite participation, aiming to meet the challenges of green transition in airport development.
4. Results
4.1. Study Area
Guangzhou Baiyun International Airport (hereinafter referred to as “CAN”) is one of the three major gateway hub airports in China, consistently ranking at the top in terms of production scale. The rapid development of CAN has raised several green development issues related to resources, the environment, and operations. To enhance the green operation management system and support the development of green airport infrastructure at CAN, this study employs CAN as a case study to conduct a simulation analysis of the tripartite evolutionary game.
To verify the evolutionary stability of equilibrium points and evaluate the impact of tripartite game parameters on the green transition in airport development, this paper assigns model parameters based on the real scenario of CAN and uses MATLAB 2019a for the simulation. The specific variable values and sources are shown in
Table 4.
4.2. Stability Validation of Strategies for Green Transition in Airport Development
In the early stages of green transition in airport development, high transition costs and evaluation difficulties often lead airport authorities and third-party organizations to adopt negative strategies due to the low input–output ratio of green performance. During this period, the regulatory mechanisms of government departments are crucial for ensuring the smooth progress of the green transition. With the promotion of green concepts and the optimization of green innovation technologies, advancing the green airport development has brought objective economic benefits to airport authorities and third-party organizations. This incentivizes them to actively undertake investment, construction, and evaluation work for green airport development. Consequently, the regulatory role of government departments should gradually weaken, forming a green development framework where airport authorities and third-party organizations are the main forces. Therefore,
is the optimal state for the green transition in airport development. This paper first uses
as an example to explore its evolution process. Under the parameter conditions of
Table 4, the initial probability of each participant’s selection strategy is set to
. According to Equation (4), the evolutionary equations are simulated. The evolution time is set to 50, and the probability changes of strategy selection for each subject are shown in
Figure 5a.
According to
Figure 5a, when the initial strategy choice of each participant is
, it will not take the initiative to change its strategy. However, when the strategic choices of the airport authorities and those of the third-party organizations change slightly, the evolution is shown in
Figure 5b, when x mutates from 1 to 0.99, and in
Figure 5c, when y mutates from 1 to 0.99.
According to
Figure 5b,c, the equilibrium point
is unstable: with a mutation in
, the system evolves to
; with a mutation in
, the system evolves to
. Based on this, further variation in the strategic choices of the government departments is made. When
mutates from 0 to 0.01, the evolution is shown in
Figure 5d.
According to
Figure 5d, both equilibrium points
and
are unstable. In the case of fixing the initial strategy of one of the airport authorities or third-party organizations, the system’s strategy choice will reach state
, as the initial strategies of the remaining two participants generate abrupt changes.
Further, the initial values
of the strategy selection probabilities for each participant are assigned in the range of [0.1, 0.9], with an assignment interval of 0.1. The system of equations evolves 50 times, and the simulation results are shown in
Figure 6.
According to
Figure 6, regardless of how the initial strategic choices of the participants change, they return to the state
. This proves that
is the stability strategy under these conditions. That is, the airport authorities choose “Without increasing green construction investment”, the third-party organizations perform “Non-strict evaluation”, and the government departments implement “Strong regulation”. This indicates that the current tripartite evolutionary game of green transition in airport development is still in the developmental stage. According to the value of each parameter in
Table 4, government departments can benefit from the regulatory process of green airport construction. However, the airport authorities and third-party organizations are faced with the more costly strategies of “Increasing green construction investment” and “Strict evaluation”. Under the conditions of insufficient government incentive mechanisms and high rent-seeking rates by airport authorities, they will likely choose strategies that benefit from “Without increasing green construction investment” and “Non-strict evaluation”, achieving rent-seeking intentions. This will hinder the process of greening the airport.
4.3. Analysis of Factors Affecting the Green Transition in Airport Development
Based on the stability strategy under current conditions, the strategic choices of the airport authorities and third-party organizations have not yet met expectations. This is not only closely related to their cost investment in the process of green transition in airport development, but also inextricably linked to the role of the relationship between the participants of the game. Therefore, this section analyzes the impacts of changes in the main parameters on the tripartite evolutionary game process and the evolutionary path. It does so by varying the input cost of each participant, the rewards and penalties of the governmental department, and the amount of rent-seeking by the airport authorities from third-party organizations, based on the determined initial parameters.
4.3.1. The Impact of Cost Factors on the Evolution of Tripartite Strategies
The parameters (
,
), (
,
), and
are scaled separately, while keeping the other parameters fixed. Considering the reliability of the simulation, the variation in the cost parameters should not be too large. Therefore, the scaling range is set to [0.5, 2], with a scaling step of 0.1, ensuring the conditions
,
, and
are satisfied. Further, high initial willingness and low initial willingness are set as controls. The initial value of the probability of strategic choice for each participant is
under low initial willingness and
under high initial willingness. The system of replicated dynamic equations evolved 50 times, from which five typical sets of cost parameters are selected to present the simulation results, as shown in
Figure 7,
Figure 8 and
Figure 9.
According to
Figure 7, when the gap between
and
is large, the airport authorities tend to choose “Without increasing green construction investment”. As the cost gap narrows, the airport authorities make a strategy shift. The cost threshold is
, and the simulation results are consistent with Inference 1.
Figure 7 shows that under the influence of strong regulation by government departments, the lower costs of green construction investment encourage airport authorities to actively engage in green airport construction initiatives. This occurs in light of larger penalties and higher rent-seeking amounts when it chooses “Without increasing green construction investment”. However, when the cost of “Increasing green construction investment” exceeds a certain range, which cannot be compensated by the incentives and performance benefits gained from greening airports, it will seriously hamper the willingness of airport authorities to opt for green development. Thus, it is clear that appropriate green construction costs play a key role in facilitating the green transition in airport development.
According to
Figure 8, at low initial willingness, the evolutionary trend of the third-party organizations’ strategy choice under all five cost parameter scenarios converges to
. This suggests that when the willingness of government departments to choose “Strong regulation” is weak, and the rent-seeking willingness of airport authorities is strong, the gap between
and
has a relatively small impact on the evolutionary stability strategy of third-party organizations. Under the high initial willingness condition, as the gap between
and
widens, the third-party organizations’ strategic choice will shift from performing “Strict evaluation” to performing “Non-strict evaluation”. This indicates that even with strong government regulation, if the cost of performing “Strict evaluation” exceeds a certain threshold, the third-party organizations will be less inclined to conduct such evaluation when their revenue cannot cover the high evaluation costs and rent-seeking losses. The cost threshold is
, and the simulation results align with Inference 2.
Figure 9 shows that the evolutionary trend of the government departments’ strategy choices converges to
under all five cost parameter scenarios, regardless of whether the initial willingness is low or high. This indicates that when the strategic choices of the other two participants tend to be negative, government departments, faced with high governance costs, continue to impose penalties on airport authorities and third-party organizations through strong regulation, even at higher regulatory costs. Notably, as the cost of regulation increases, the government departments’ willingness to implement “Strong regulation” decreases. This is evident in the evolution curve of the strategy selection, which shows a slower convergence rate or even a pattern of initially decreasing and then increasing. The simulation results are consistent with Inference 3.
4.3.2. The Impact of Reward and Punishment Mechanisms
Keeping other parameters constant, this paper investigates the evolutionary process of tripartite strategy selection under different reward and punishment mechanisms by adjusting the reward and punishment parameters
,
, and
of the government departments. This is achieved by scaling
,
, and
based on their existing parameter values, with a scaling range of [0.1, 5] and a scaling step of 0.1. In conjunction with
Table 3, the scaled arrays are screened to eliminate those that do not meet the stabilization conditions. The eligible solution sets are then simulated and analyzed, with the results presented in
Figure 10.
Figure 10 indicates that the strategy evolution of the tripartite subjects exhibits three stable states—
,
, and
—under varying reward and punishment parameters of the government department. To further analyze the impact of changes in government departments’ reward and punishment parameters on the strategy choices of the airport authorities and those of the third-party organizations, a set of parameters from each of the three stable states is selected for the simulation analysis over 50 times. The initial willingness
for each participant’s strategy selection is set to 0.5, and the simulation results are presented in
Figure 11.
Figure 11 shows that, under the strong regulatory effect of the government departments, increasing
from 0.5 to 0.75 and changing the tripartite evolutionary steady state from
to
can be achieved by decreasing
from 0.5 to 0.05 and increasing
from 0.5 to 2.0. When
is further increased to 1.5, the transition of the tripartite evolutionary stabilization strategy from
to
can be achieved by reducing
to 0.2.
On the one hand, as shown in
Figure 11a, when
increases from 0.5 to 0.75, as government subsidies decrease, airport authorities, facing higher green transition costs, are more likely to refrain from increasing their green construction investment and instead resort to rent-seeking to capture the performance benefits of green development. When
increases to 1.5, faced with high penalties and rent-seeking costs for choosing “Without increasing green construction investment”, the airport authorities will shift their development strategy to obtain incentive subsidies and green performance benefits from the government departments by increasing their green construction investment. However, due to the low subsidy from the government departments, the airport authorities’ willingness to shift their strategy is weak. This is evidenced by
remaining essentially constant at the beginning of the evolution and gradually tending towards 1 as
increases.
On the other hand, as shown in
Figure 11b, when both
and
increase, the evolutionary stability strategy of the third-party organizations shifts from performing “Non-strict evaluation” to performing “Strict evaluation”. However, the willingness of government departments to implement “Strong regulation” is slow to shift due to the large subsidy
. With the reduction in subsidy, the willingness of third-party organizations to perform “Strict evaluation” diminishes. However, with the stronger penalty from the government departments (
), as the government departments’ willingness to choose “Strong regulation” strengthens, the third-party organizations still tend to perform “Strict evaluation”. This is indicated by
initially decreasing and then increasing in the evolution curve.
4.3.3. The Impact of Rent-Seeking Amounts
Keeping other parameters constant, the evolution of tripartite strategy choices under different rent-seeking costs is explored by adjusting the rent-seeking amount
of the airport authorities. This is achieved by scaling
based on the existing parameter values within the range [0.1, 5], with a scaling step of 0.1. In conjunction with
Table 3, the scaled arrays are screened to eliminate those that do not meet the stabilization conditions. The eligible solution sets are then simulated and analyzed, with the results presented in
Figure 12a. Three sets of parameters are selected for simulation analysis over 50 times, with the results presented in
Figure 12b.
Figure 12a indicates that the strategy evolution of the tripartite subjects exhibits two stable states,
and
, under varying rent-seeking costs.
Figure 12b shows that as the rent-seeking cost gradually exceeds the threshold value, the airport authorities’ evolutionary stability strategy shifts from “Without increasing green construction investment” to “Increasing green construction investment”. According to Proposition 1, the threshold of the rent-seeking cost is
. The evolutionary results suggest that, under strong regulatory willingness from the government departments, an increase in rent-seeking costs encourages a positive shift in the strategic choices of airport authorities but discourages third-party organizations from performing “Strict evaluation”. It is worth noting that, during the initial stage of the evolution, the willingness of airport authorities to make the strategic transition is weak due to the high cost of “Increasing green construction investment”. It is shown that when
,
decreases initially and then increases along the evolutionary curve.
4.4. Discussion
This paper addresses the complex interactions among the multiple participants involved in the green transition of airport development. It constructs a tripartite evolutionary game model involving airport authorities, third-party organizations, and government departments. Using CAN as an example, the green transition path of airport development is analyzed through numerical simulation, using the computer simulation software MATLAB. The following main discussions are drawn from the simulation results.
(1) Based on the analysis of the evolutionary stability points, under certain conditions, the five equilibrium points , , , , and can function as the evolutionary stability strategies of the system. This understanding forms the basis for dividing the green transition process in airport development into three stages: the initial stage, the development stage, and the maturity stage. The empirical analysis of CAN demonstrates that the strategy choice in the tripartite evolutionary game is stable at , indicating that the green transition of CAN is still in the development stage. The government departments implement “Strong regulation” for airport authorities and third-party organizations to realize the urgent vision of achieving green development. However, due to the high costs of green transition and imperfect reward systems and punishment mechanisms, the airport authorities and third-party organizations tend to adopt negative strategies and engage in rent-seeking behavior.
(2) The cost factors for each participant significantly impact the evolution of the system. The smaller the cost gap between positive and negative strategies for each participant, the greater their initiative to promote the green transition in airport development. When the cost gap falls below a certain threshold, airport authorities and third-party organizations can shift from a negative to a positive strategy. This shift is more pronounced with high initial willingness. It is worth noting that, regardless of low or high initial willingness, the government departments tend to choose “Strong regulation” at both the lowest and highest acceptable simulation costs. This suggests that strong government regulation plays a crucial role in the green transition of airport development.
(3) The interactions among the various participants are crucial for a successful green transition in airport development. A shift in the equilibrium strategy of the three-way game from to can be achieved when the third-party organizations increase the rent-seeking costs for the airport authorities. However, increased rent-seeking costs further reduce the likelihood that third-party organizations will adopt an aggressive strategy. A shift in the equilibrium strategy of the tripartite evolutionary game from to and can be achieved when the government departments adjust the incentives and penalties for airport authorities and third-party organizations. However, the magnitude of the adjustment should be kept within reasonable limits. If the reward and punishment are too small, they will reduce the motivation for airport authorities and third-party organizations to pursue a green transition. Suppose the reward and punishment are too strong. In that case, they will create a passive regulatory situation for airport authorities and third-party organizations, preventing government departments from disengaging from the need for strong regulation.
5. Conclusions and Recommendations
Given the shortcomings of existing research, which lacks a comprehensive consideration of the multi-party interests involved in the green transition of airport development, this paper proposes a three-party evolutionary game model for the green transition of airport development. It examines the behavioral strategies and influencing factors of all parties involved in green development through simulation. Compared to the lack of consideration of multiple stakeholders and their dynamic evolution process in the green transition of airport development in existing research, the main findings of this study are as follows:
(1) In the context of the three-way evolutionary game, the green transition process of airport development can be divided into three stages based on the stabilization strategy: the initial stage, the development stage, and the maturity stage. In this process, the input cost of each game participant plays a crucial role in determining their evolutionary strategy. When the input cost exceeds a certain threshold, the strategy of each participant shifts from a positive to a negative approach. Exploring the method of dividing the stages of the green transition path in airport development holds significant research value for analyzing the dynamic process of the green transition in airport development.
(2) This study investigates the impact of government reward and punishment mechanisms on the green transition path of airport development through simulation analysis. The results indicate that during the green transition process of airport development, strong regulatory mechanisms implemented by government departments play a crucial role in advancing the stages of green transition. However, adjustments to the reward and punishment mechanisms should not be too excessive to avoid negatively impacting the willingness of all parties to adopt positive strategies.
(3) By studying the impact of rent-seeking by airport authorities on the green transition path of airport development, it is evident that, under strong government regulatory mechanisms, rent-seeking behavior by airport authorities from third-party agencies is undesirable. Although an increase in rent-seeking may prompt airport authorities to adopt a positive strategy, it undermines the willingness of third-party agencies to conduct rigorous evaluations, which is detrimental to the long-term green development of airports.
Based on the above discussions, this paper proposes the following policy recommendations to effectively promote green transition in airport development.
(1) As the focal point and landing ground for green development, the effective implementation of green construction by airport authorities is crucial in promoting green transition in airport development. Therefore, with subsidies from government departments, the airport authorities should appropriately increase their investment in green construction and rationalize their plans for projects such as automation renovation, energy saving, and emission reduction. Additionally, by encouraging the integration of research on green innovation technologies into airport development, resource utilization can be improved, the cost of green development can be reduced, and the resistance to green transition can be weakened.
(2) Third-party organizations play a crucial role in standardizing the construction of green airports and promoting their green transition. It is imperative that these organizations conduct comprehensive research on evaluation methods for green airports. By reducing evaluation costs and improving evaluation efficiency, they can also analyze the outstanding problems facing green airport development. This allows for targeted rectification based on the evaluation scores of different guideline and indicator layers, ultimately enhancing the efficiency of the green transition in airport development.
(3) Effective regulatory mechanisms in the government departments are crucial for the green transition in airport development. Therefore, the government departments should establish reasonable incentives and penalties to motivate airport authorities and third-party organizations to engage in green development and construction, thereby preventing both parties from pursuing rent-seeking behavior while choosing negative strategies. Additionally, as the airport authorities and third-party organizations are ideally the driving forces behind green airport development, the government departments can delegate some supervisory responsibilities to third-party organizations during the mature stage of green development. This approach will ease regulatory pressure on the government departments, reduce regulatory costs, and provide stronger policy support for green airport development.
(4) This paper classifies the green transition of airport development into three stages—initiation, development, and maturity—based on the results of the tripartite evolutionary stabilization strategy. Each stage displays distinct green development characteristics due to variations in the tripartite strategies chosen. In the initial stage, all three parties typically adopt negative strategies. Therefore, government departments should introduce preliminary policy guidelines to encourage green investments by airports and provide necessary support and incentives. In the development stage, government departments implement stringent regulatory measures. Emphasis should be placed on enhancing the application of environmental protection measures by airport authorities and ensuring rigorous evaluations by third-party organizations, while also working to reduce the costs associated with green development. In the mature stage, the regulatory responsibilities of government departments should be gradually reduced while ensuring the effective collaboration between airport authorities and third-party organizations, thereby establishing a green development model driven primarily by airport authorities and third-party organizations.
Additionally, to simplify the model, this study considers the three relevant stakeholders as homogeneous entities, which may affect the generalizability and applicability of the findings. On one hand, differences in goals, strategies, and power dynamics among stakeholders in the real world can result in some stakeholders having more resources or stronger capabilities, allowing them to dominate the evolutionary game process and be less influenced by the strategic choices of the other two parties. On the other hand, in airports at varying levels of development or within different cultural and regulatory environments, contextual factors influence the strategic choices and implementation strengths of the various actors in the green transition process, which in turn affect policymaking at different stages of development. Therefore, future research could incorporate the heterogeneity among relevant stakeholders and develop an evolutionary game model where stakeholders’ strategic choices are influenced by their specific goals and constraints. This approach would more accurately capture the dynamic interactions of each stakeholder and offer policymakers more targeted recommendations.