1. Introduction
With the rapid advancement of global urbanization, the shortage of natural resources and energy has become increasingly evident, posing severe threats to sustainable development and public welfare on regional and global scales [
1]. The most direct manifestation of rapid urbanization in land use is the increase in demand for land resources due to the continuous expansion of urban boundaries, thus increasing the pressure on arable land protection. China is in a phase of rapid urbanization and inevitably faces this global problem, as well as many others brought about by rapid urbanization.
Since the reform and opening in 1978, rapid urbanization and industrialization have brought China’s increasing economic development and speedy improvement of people’s living standards. At the same time, these transformations have also affected rural human-land relations [
2]. According to the latest sample data from China’s Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development, the country’s rural resident population decreased by 219 million from 2000 to 2016, while the idle rate of homesteads was 18.10% in 2019 [
3]. This inefficient use and waste of rural homestead resources, caused mainly by the transfer of farmers to urban areas, has seriously impeded the development of rural areas in China [
4,
5]. In response, China has been reforming the rural homestead system since 2015. The reform of the rural homestead system is an integral part of the reform of China’s rural land system, aiming to optimize the use and management of rural homesteads through policy adjustments to improve land use efficiency and promote rural economic and social development. Since then, every year, the No. 1 document of the central government focuses on the deployment of the reform of the homesteads system. One of the critical breakthroughs is the proposal to explore the “three rights of ownership, eligibility, and use” of homesteads in 2018. On the basis of the implementation of the collective ownership of the homesteads and the guarantee of the qualification right of the homesteads farmers, the use right of the homesteads is moderately liberalized, i.e., the farmers adopt the methods of self-employment, leasing, shareholding, and withdrawing to revitalize the idle homesteads and the house on the ground in the rural areas. Farmers are the main decision-making body in transferring the right to use the homesteads, but farmers are also the basic unit of rural economic and social activities. The formation mechanism of the farmers’ will to revitalize the idle homesteads is the key to revitalizing the idle homesteads [
6,
7].
At the same time, farmer differentiation during urbanization also warrants attention. Institutional policy liberalization and the drive for agricultural transformation have led to farmer differentiation, evolving from purely agricultural households to the agricultural transfer population and new urban residents [
8]. As the agricultural transfer population shifts from the part-time status of half-farming and half-employing between urban and rural areas to fully engaging in non-farming industries, the level of agricultural household differentiation of this group is also increasing [
8]. Therefore, to narrow the gap in salary and compensation, public services and even cultural values faced by farmers with different levels of differentiation and raising the level of differentiation of farmers to obtain more development opportunities and enjoy better public services have become the main goals of this group. Farmers with different levels of differentiation differ in their ability to make a living and their subjective perception of the value of land, thus resulting in different degrees of land dependence. Therefore, when studying the formation mechanism of farmers’ intention to revitalize idle homesteads (hereafter referred to as “revitalize intention”), farmers’ differentiation level should be fully considered. Existing studies show that countries like the United States and most post-industrial countries have good practical experience in guiding farmers to reuse rural residential land, and it explores the influence of locational elements, ecological changes, and other factors on the reuse of rural residential land [
9,
10]. Reusing rural residential land has become an effective way to address idle and inefficiently used rural residential land due to the rural population’s movement to the city. As a critical stakeholder, farmers’ intention to revitalize is influenced by their factors (education level, social capital, and primary source of income) and external factors (government planning policies, landscape planning, and agricultural food production programs) [
11,
12,
13,
14]. The property rights of rural land in Western countries are transparent and dominated by private ownership, and there is no concept like the homesteads. Specifically, the land in the rural areas of the United States is privately owned. Farmers who buy land need to pay land taxes every year, but this does not affect the permanence of the property rights; this system ensures that the property can be passed on to future generations, realizing the true meaning of permanent property ownership. China’s rural homesteads are a unique product under the dual structure; the village collective owns its property rights, and farmers only have the right to qualify (the right of eligibility is a specific right enjoyed by farmers based on their membership of a rural collective economic organization) and the right to use. Compared with Western countries, reforming China’s idle rural homesteads is more challenging and complex [
2]. In China, the homestead is one of the core elements of the rural land system, which provides farmers with housing and agricultural production land and is an essential basis for guaranteeing farmers’ challenging production and life. Therefore, the revitalization intention of farmers as the revitalization subject and direct stakeholder of idle homesteads is fundamental.
Previous studies often treated farmers as a homogeneous whole. They verified the influence of factors such as livelihood capital, the number of homesteads, and locational resources on their intention to revitalize from single perspectives of internal psychology or external situations [
15,
16]. Only a few scholars have noted the differentiated effects of farmer differentiation on revitalization intention, distinguishing farmer differentiation into horizontal occupational differentiation and vertical economic differentiation, thereby clarifying the direct impact of farmer differentiation on homestead exit intention [
17]. With the deepening of the homestead system reform, the scope of the reform has gradually broadened, from farmers’ withdrawal from idle homesteads to revitalizing idle homesteads. However, there are fewer quantitative analyses of the mechanism of the differentiation of farmers on the intention to revitalize. Specifically, there are the following shortcomings in the existing research: First, most current research focuses on the withdrawal of homesteads. However, with the further deepening of the reform of the homesteads system, the focus of the reform has gradually shifted from farmers’ withdrawal from the idle homesteads to the revitalization of the idle homesteads. Second, the criteria for the differentiation of farmers are often judged solely based on income sources, neglecting its social connotations and affecting the credibility and persuasiveness of empirical conclusions. Third, there is a lack of exploration of the overall and multi-dimensional relationship between farmer differentiation and the intention to revitalize homesteads from the dual perspectives of internal cognition and external context.
The formation of farmers’ revitalization intention is a multi-linked and complex systematic project, and the existing research has neglected the intrinsic dimensions of farmers’ differentiation and explored the influence of a particular factor on farmers’ revitalization intention only from a single perspective, such as the internal psychology or external context, which makes the research more fragmented. Therefore, this study systematically explores the overall and multi-dimensional relationship between farmer differentiation and revitalization intention from the dual perspectives of internal cognition and external context and, at the same time, analyzes the role of farmers’ cognition in the relationship between the two.
Based on the above background, we consider farmer differentiation as a second-order factor consisting of wealth capital differentiation and reputation capital differentiation. Based on social stratification theory and Stimulus–Organism–Response theory (S-O-R), we improve the TPB and construct an analysis framework of “farmer differentiation (FD)–farmer cognition (FC)–revitalization intention (RI)”. SEM was further used to validate the 881 data samples collected from farmers in Shaanxi Province. Based on using exploratory factor analysis to clarify the dimensions of the concept of FD, we systematically explored the relationship between the FD and RI from a multi-dimensional perspective. At the same time, we analyzed the role of the FC in the relationship between the two, intending to provide a theoretical basis and empirical evidence for enhancing the intention to revitalize the idle homesteads of farmers.
This study defines the intrinsic dimensions of farmer differentiation. It expands the existing binary research framework of “farmer cognition (FC)–revitalization intention (RI)” to construct the research framework of “farmer differentiation (FD)–farmer cognition (FC)–revitalization intention (RI)”. Then, we embed wealth capital differentiation, reputation capital differentiation, behavioral attitudes, subjective norms, perceived behavioral control, homestead dependence, and revitalization intention in this research framework to analyze the effects of farm household differentiation on its willingness to revitalize and the mediating effect of farmers’ cognition. The study’s results help expand the theoretical research on the relationship between the farmer’s differentiation and revitalization intention and provide theoretical support and a decision-making basis for the government to carry out revitalization work.
The remainder of the article is as follows:
Section 2 constructs the theoretical framework and proposes the research hypotheses;
Section 3 introduces the data sources and empirical methods;
Section 4 presents the empirical results;
Section 5 discusses the results; and
Section 6 gives the study’s conclusions and policy recommendations.
6. Conclusions and Implications
6.1. Conclusions
Our main findings are: (1) FD is multi-dimensional, including two sub-dimensions: WCD and RCD. (2) The logical relationship of “FC→RI” in TPB has been verified in the study of RI, and the inhibitory effect of HD on RI is worthy of attention. (3) Expanding the logical relationship of “FD–FC–RI” in TPB has been confirmed; in addition to the direct positive impact of WCD and RCD on RI, WCD can indirectly affect RI through FC sub-dimensions BA, SN, PBA, and HD. At the same time, the chain mediating role of WCD and FC sub-dimensions in the influence of RCD on RI should not be ignored. These findings suggest that the ETPB not only increases the theory’s explanatory power but also expands its explanatory scope. It also provides the theoretical basis and empirical evidence for policymakers. In addition, more extended models can be developed for rural land consolidation and reuse in other countries based on this conceptual framework.
6.2. Implications
- (1)
Based on the logical relationship of “FC → RI”.
Policymakers can enhance FC from the following four aspects:
First, regarding BA, on the one hand, the government can explore successful cases of revitalization, benchmark farmers, increase publicity efforts, and broaden publicity channels to cultivate farmers’ confidence in the prospects of revitalizing homesteads. On the other hand, it is necessary to regulate the relevant laws and regulations on homestead revitalization strictly, focus on the difficulties of homestead revitalization, and enhance farmers’ confidence in the prospects of homestead revitalization.
Second, regarding SN, the government can increase the support of significant others, especially friends and relatives, by increasing incentives for homestead revitalization, reducing the pitfalls of homestead revitalization, and protecting the legal rights of farmers. For example, the village collective economic organization-led revitalization expanded the proportion of farmer benefits.
Third, regarding PBC, the government can enhance farmers’ ability to bear the risks of revitalization by focusing on strengthening farmers’ understanding of policies and employment training, improving the rural social security system, and improving the communication and dispute coordination mechanisms of the main parties involved in revitalization.
Fourth, regarding the HD, the government should focus on farmers’ property dependence on homesteads, appropriately raise the standard of subsidies within the scope of conditions or increase the proportion of the distribution of homestead revitalization proceeds to farmers so that they can share more of the fruits of reform and development.
- (2)
Based on the logical relationship of “FD→FC→RI”.
FD will be the future trend of rural social development in the context of urbanization; the ability of farmers in the commodity market and the status of social interaction will continue to produce differences. In this case, farmers with different levels of differentiation will have different perceptions of the revitalization of homesteads, so the more deeply differentiated farmers are more willing to revitalize unused homesteads. For example, deeply differentiated farmers are less land-dependent and have more resources and social status, so the more deeply differentiated farmers are more willing to revitalize unused homesteads. Therefore, in addition to guiding farmers to form a proactive cognition on the revitalization of idle homesteads, governments should also start by improving the level of farmer differentiation:
First, to help farmers accumulate wealth capital, the government should give more policy encouragement and financial support to rural areas and farmers. For example, it could reduce interest rate subsidies and other ways to enhance the entrepreneurial capacity of farmers, attract investment to attract social capital to develop rural industries to enhance rural infrastructure, and provide free education for children, health insurance, housing subsidies, and retirement benefits for the agricultural transfer population and for farmers who have been citizens, etc.
Second, to increase farmers’ reputation capital, the government should promote reforms to equalize public services, such as providing vocational and technical training for farmers to improve their off-farm employability, breaking down barriers to social welfare entitlement, and providing equalized social services for farmers to enhance the sense of belonging of migrant farmers and agricultural migrants, etc.
The marginal contributions of this study include (1) following the pace of reform to pay attention to the intention of farmers to revitalize idle homesteads. (2) Theoretically explore the internal dimensions of FD based on the social stratification theory and verify it by EFA. (3) Expanding TPB by using the social stratification theory and the SOR theory to construct the analytical framework of “FD–FC–RI”, which provides a detailed analysis of the overall and multi-dimensional relationship between the FD and RI.
However, our study has the following potential limitations: First, this study uses cross-sectional data, which only focuses on the static relationship between variables. Second, although intention can determine behavior to a certain extent, behavioral intention cannot fully represent behavior. Third, in addition to the differentiation of farmer, there may also be other social and economic variables that have an impact on the intention of farms to revitalize and their behavior. Examples include family life cycles and generational differences. Future research can use panel data and a broader research framework to conduct in-depth research on farmers’ intentional behavior to revitalize.