Research on the Performance Management of Carbon Reduction by Local Governments from a Game Perspective—The Case of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
2.1. Research on Carbon Reduction
2.1.1. Influencing Factors of Carbon Emissions
2.1.2. Carbon Reduction Policy Research
2.2. Evolutionary Games
2.2.1. Evolutionary Game Overview
2.2.2. The Application of Evolutionary Games for Carbon Emission Reduction
2.3. Performance Management
2.3.1. Performance Management
2.3.2. Government Performance Management
3. Theoretical Basis
3.1. Stakeholder Theory
3.2. Cost–Benefit Theory
3.3. Evolutionary Game Theory
3.4. Collaborative Governance Theory
4. Methodology
5. Case Analysis of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Order
5.1. Introduction to the Event
5.2. Analysis of the Stakeholders in the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident
5.2.1. Definition of Stakeholders
5.2.2. Stakeholders’ Behavioral Strategies
- 1.
- Corporate Behavioral Strategies
- 2.
- Residents’ Behavioral Strategies
5.2.3. Analysis of the Factors Affecting Stakeholders’ Behaviors
- 1.
- Analysis of the Factors Affecting the Local Government’s Behaviors
- 2.
- Analysis of the Factors Affecting Enterprises’ Behaviors
- 3.
- Analysis of the Factors Affecting Residents’ Behaviors
6. Analysis of the Three-Party Evolutionary Game of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident
6.1. Model Assumptions and Construction
6.1.1. Tripartite Game Relationship in the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident
6.1.2. Model’s Assumptions
6.1.3. Related Variable Settings
6.1.4. Model Building
- Residents participate in the power restriction policy (Z); see Table 8 for details:
- 2.
- Residents do not participate in the power restriction policy (1 − Z); see Table 9 for details:
6.2. Model Solving and Analysis
6.2.1. Replicator Dynamics Equations
6.2.2. Evolutionarily Stable Strategies of Tripartite Subjects
- Evolutionarily Stable Strategy of the Local Government
- 2.
- Evolutionarily Stable Strategies of Enterprises
- 3.
- Evolutionarily Stable Strategies of Residents
6.2.3. Replicator Dynamics Equilibrium Point Judgement
6.3. Analysis of the Conditions to Be Satisfied by Tripartite Collaborative Governance
6.4. Policy Analysis and Performance Optimization Suggestions
6.4.1. Analysis of Policy Implementation Issues
- The role of the government itself is insufficient. This is mainly reflected in the following points: The formulation of assessment targets lacks scientific rigor and flexibility. Reasonable emission reduction targets are not set in accordance with the structural characteristics of the energy consumption and the economic development needs of different regions. The performance appraisal has lost its role in promoting the government’s governance. During policy implementation process, we are faced with the ever-changing economic and ecological environments, and it is difficult to interact with and provide feedback to multiple parties in a timely manner;
- The government’s incentives and punishments for enterprises are not strong enough. As a result, the enthusiasm of enterprises for the transformation is not high, and they are more willing to maintain the status quo, use high-energy-consuming equipment, and rush to complete overseas Christmas orders;
- There is a lack of measures to encourage and guide residents to participate. Residents lack access to government policy implementation processes and performance information. Residents play different roles at this time. They not only are the beneficiaries of energy conservation and emission reduction but also bear the inconveniences caused by this policy in life and work. There are needs for policy guidance and supervision and feedback mechanisms from local governments to identify needs and actively participate in collaborative governance.
6.4.2. Government Performance Optimization Suggestions
- The government should improve the performance management mechanism of the energy conservation and emission reduction governance and maintain the normalization of the supervision and accountability. It should provide continuous upward feedback channels to increase the enthusiasm of local governments to participate in the construction of a circular economy. In terms of the assessment’s time dimension, it is necessary to establish a dynamic assessment model or increase the frequency of assessments to be consistent with the assessments’ objectives. Frequent interactive feedback efforts generate more performance information that can help governments to identify performance deficiencies by comparing the governments’ own current and past records, as well as their own records with those of peer governments. Such comparisons can help to alert management teams of the need to catch up [86].In addition, a system for using performance appraisal results needs to be further established. For example, in the first stage of an unqualified assessment, the responsible department should be required to submit a causal analysis and an improvement plan. In the second stage of an unqualified assessment, when submitting the improvement plan, the higher-level government should consider adjusting the target content and resource allocation [87] to drive the achievement of performance goals. Of course, in performance appraisal accountability, it is necessary to prevent adverse selection caused by excessive control and subsequent punishment to prevent similar cases from happening again;
- Enterprises’ behaviors for maintaining the status quo of production cannot be left to chance, nor can a one-size-fits-all power cut be carried out. To design a top-level management mechanism, the high-energy-consuming industry is divided based on the characteristics of the industry, graded power restriction, and peak power restrictions. At the same time, government performance goals, responsible persons, budget expenditures, contributions to goals, and performance evaluation results are disclosed and updated to allow companies to understand the progress in achieving various strategic goals and carrying out specific government projects. Companies can use this information to predict the government’s behavior and make behavioral decisions that are beneficial to them;
- Public services provided by the government require the active participation of citizens, especially those who directly use the services [88]. Local residents are one of the direct victims and managers of carbon emissions. The management of carbon emissions from production activities requires strong supervision by residents, while reducing carbon emissions from daily consumption requires residents to adhere to a green lifestyle, and the government’s correction of the policy implementation process requires effective supervision by residents. By stimulating public participation in governance, corporate social responsibility and public awareness can be enhanced, supervision costs can be effectively reduced, and the power of the public can be maximized [12].
7. Conclusions
7.1. Summary
7.2. Limitations and Prospects
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Maamoun, N. The Kyoto protocol: Empirical evidence of a hidden success. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2019, 95, 227–256. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Villar-Rubio, E.; Huete-Morales, M.D. Market instruments for a sustainable economy: Environmental fiscal policy and manifest divergences. Rev. Policy Res. 2017, 34, 255–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Galán-Valdivieso, F.; Villar-Rubio, E.; Huete-Morales, M.D. The erratic behavior of the EU ETS on the path towards consolidation and price stability. Int. Environ. Agreem. Politics Law Econ. 2018, 18, 689–706. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, C. The EU–China energy cooperation: Toward a reciprocal partnership? Asia Eur. J. 2021, 19, 259–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Suetyi, L.; Zhiqin, S. How China views the EU in global energy governance: A norm exporter, a partner or an outsider? Comp. Eur. Politics 2017, 15, 80–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, H.; Chen, Z.; Sun, Y. Structural contradictions and countermeasures of the power system under the background of “dual carbon”. Macroecon. Manag. 2023, 7, 77–85. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Nectar, G. China Turns off the Lights in ‘Christmas Town’ as Officials Race to Meet Energy Targets. CNN. 2020. Available online: https://edition.cnn.com/2020/12/25/business/china-power-shortage-intl-hnk-dst/index.html (accessed on 14 November 2023).
- Li, X. Evolutionary game analysis of green building development dynamic system under government regulation: From the perspective of the contractor. Math. Probl. Eng. 2022, 2022, 1987229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yan, Y.; Cheng, Q.; Huang, M.; Lin, Q.; Lin, W. Government environmental regulation and corporate ESG performance: Evidence from natural resource accountability audits in China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2023, 20, 447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Neshkova, M.I.; Guo, H. Public participation and organizational performance: Evidence from state agencies. J. Public Adm. Res. Theory 2012, 22, 267–288. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heikkila, T.; Isett, K.R. Citizen involvement and performance management in special-purpose governments. Public Adm. Rev. 2007, 67, 238–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, X.; Liu, Z.; Wuyun, T. Environmental value and pro-environmental behavior among young adults: The mediating role of risk perception and moral anger. Front. Psychol. 2022, 13, 771421. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ruan, H.; Qiu, L.; Chen, J.; Liu, S.; Ma, Z. Government trust, environmental pollution perception, and environmental governance satisfaction. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 9929. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Yin, H.; Huang, Y.; Wang, K. How do environmental concerns and governance performance affect public environmental participation: A case study of waste sorting in Urban China. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2021, 18, 9947. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Zhu, J.; Lu, C.; Wei, Z. Perception of air pollution and the evaluation of local government’s environmental governance: An empirical study on China. Atmosphere 2023, 14, 212. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qian, P.; Ma, C.H. Spatio-temporal dynamics of carbon emission of energy consumption in China. J. Southwest Univ. (Nat. Sci.) 2019, 41, 93–100. [Google Scholar]
- Kong, H.; Shi, L.; Da, D.; Li, Z.; Tang, D.; Xing, W. Simulation of China’s carbon emission based on influencing factors. Energies 2022, 15, 3272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Duan, H.; Zhang, G.; Fan, Y.; Wang, S. Role of endogenous energy efficiency improvement in global climate change mitigation. Energy Effic. 2017, 10, 459–473. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, X.; Yang, Y.; Li, Y. Does public participation reduce regional carbon emission? Atmosphere 2023, 14, 165. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shuai, C.; Shen, L.; Jiao, L.; Wu, Y.; Tan, Y. Identifying key impact factors on carbon emission: Evidences from panel and time-series data of 125 countries from 1990 to 2011. Appl. Energy 2017, 187, 310–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Duro, J.A.; Teixidó-Figueras, J.; Padilla, E. Empirics of the International Inequality in CO2 Emissions Intensity: Explanatory Factors According to Complementary Decomposition Methodologies. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2016, 63, 57–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yu, Y.; Zhang, N.; Kim, J.D. Impact of urbanization on energy demand: An empirical study of the Yangtze River Economic Belt in China. Energy Policy 2020, 139, 111354. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gong, W.; Zhang, H.; Wang, C.; Wu, B.; Yuan, Y.; Fan, S. Analysis of urban carbon emission efficiency and influencing factors in the Yellow River Basin. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2023, 30, 14641–14655. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, W.; de Jong, M.; de Bruijne, M.; Mu, R. Mix and match: Configuring different types of policy instruments to develop successful low carbon cities in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 282, 125399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xie, R.; Hu, G.; Zhang, Y.; Liu, Y. Provincial transfers of enabled carbon emissions in China: A supply-side perspective. Energy Policy 2017, 107, 688–697. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, W.; Lei, Y.; Feng, K.; Wu, S.; Li, L. Provincial emission accounting for CO2 mitigation in China: Insights from production, consumption and income perspectives. Appl. Energy 2019, 255, 113754. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Y.; Chen, L.; Huang, C. A tripartite evolutionary game and simulation analysis of transportation carbon emission reduction across regions under government reward and punishment mechanism. Sustainability 2022, 14, 10562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shi, M.; Wang, Y. Do green transfer payments contribute to carbon emission reduction? Sustainability 2023, 15, 4021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, N.; Deng, M.; Mou, H.; Tang, D.; Fang, Z.; Zhou, Q.; Cheng, C.; Wang, Y. Government participation in supply chain low-carbon technology R&D and green marketing strategy optimization. Sustainability 2022, 14, 8342. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Weng, X.; Yuan, C.; Hu, Q.; Xu, Y. Evolutionary game and simulation analysis on quality supervision of low-carbon renovation of high-carbon emission enterprises under the reward and punishment mechanism. Front. Environ. Sci. 2023, 11, 1126275. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Wang, J.; Dong, Z. Interactions and Co-governance policies of stakeholders in the carbon emission reduction. Sustainability 2022, 14, 5891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wen, F.; Sun, Z.; Luo, Y. Population structure and local carbon emission reduction: Evidence from Guangdong, China. Sustainability 2023, 15, 4079. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, Z.; Sun, Y. How to treat gossip in internet public carbon emission reduction projects? Sustainability 2022, 14, 12809. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Von Neumann, J.; Morgenstern, O. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 1944. [Google Scholar]
- Smith, J.M.; Price, G.R. The logic of animal conflict. Nature 1973, 246, 15–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huang, T.; Liu, Z.; Zhao, T. Evolutionary game analysis of responding to the EU’s carbon border adjustment mechanism. Energies 2022, 15, 427. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yu, N.; Chen, J.; Cheng, L. Evolutionary game analysis of carbon emission reduction between government and enterprises under carbon quota trading policy. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 8565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Sun, R.; Liu, T.; Chen, X.; Yao, L. A biomass-coal co-firing based bi-level optimal approach for carbon emission reduction in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2021, 278, 123318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, X.; Bai, Y.; Ding, L.; Wang, L. Tripartite evolutionary game theory approach for low-carbon power grid technology cooperation with government intervention. IEEE Access 2020, 8, 47357–47369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sun, H.; Gao, G.; Li, Z. Evolutionary game analysis of enterprise carbon emission regulation based on prospect theory. Soft Comput. 2022, 26, 13357–13368. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, J.; Meng, W.; Huang, B.; Li, Y. Factors influencing intergovernmental cooperation on emission reduction in chengdu-chongqing urban agglomeration: An evolutionary game theory perspective. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2022, 19, 14848. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, X.; Liu, P.; Wei, Q. Analysis on evolutionary stability strategies of carbon emission of logistics enterprises based on carbon tax. Math. Probl. Eng. 2021, 2021, 9941243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Taylor, F.W. The Principles of Scientific Management. History of Economic Thought Books; Happer & Brothers Publishers: New York, NY, USA, 1911. [Google Scholar]
- Fayol, H. General and Industrial Management; Martino Publishing: New Yok, NY, USA, 1954. [Google Scholar]
- Griffin, R.W. Management, 2nd ed.; Houghton Mifflin: Boston, MA, USA, 1987. [Google Scholar]
- Pressman, J.L.; Wildavsky, A. Implementation: How Great Expectations in Washington Are Dashed in Oakland; Or, Why It’s Amazing That Federal Programs Work at All, This Being a Saga of the Economic Development Administration as Told by Two Sympathetic Observers Who Seek to Build Morals on a Foundation; University of California Press: Berkeley, CA, USA, 1984. [Google Scholar]
- Hood, C. A public management for all seasons? Public Adm. 1991, 69, 3–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nofianti, L.; Suseno, N.S. Factors affecting implementation of good government governance (GGG) and their implications towards performance accountability. Procedia-Soc. Behav. Sci. 2014, 164, 98–105. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, F.; Qi, Y. Research on the performance evaluation index system construction and countermeasure of low-carbon economic development in China. IOP Conf. Ser. Earth Environ. Sci. 2020, 440, 042058. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, X.J. Research on comprehensive evaluation index system of performance auditing of governmental ecological environment. Appl. Ecol. Environ. Res. 2019, 6, 14359–14374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Freeman, R.E. Strategic Management: A Stakeholder Approach; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Frederick, W.C.; Davis, K.; Post, J.E. Business and Society: Corporate Strategy, Public Policy, Ethics; McGraw-Hill Companies: New York, NY, USA, 1988. [Google Scholar]
- Charkham, J.P. Corporate governance: Lessons from abroad. Eur. Bus. J. 1992, 4, 8–17. [Google Scholar]
- Mitchell, R.K.; Agle, B.R.; Wood, D.J. Toward a theory of stakeholder identification and salience: Defining the principle of who and what really counts. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1997, 22, 853–886. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smith, A. The Wealth of Nations [1776]; Vintage Books: New York, NY, USA, 1937. [Google Scholar]
- Nash, J. Non-cooperative games. Ann. Math. 1951, 54, 286–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Taylor, P.D.; Jonker, L.B. Evolutionary stable strategies and game dynamics. Math. Biosci. 1978, 40, 145–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ansell, C.; Gash, A. Collaborative governance in theory and practice. J. Public Adm. Res. Theory 2008, 18, 543–571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wood, D.J.; Gray, B. Toward a comprehensive theory of collaboration. J. Appl. Behav. Sci. 1991, 27, 139–162. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, S.; Lee, S. Adaptive governance and decentralization: Evidence from regulation of the sharing economy in multi-level governance. Gov. Inf. Q. 2018, 35, 299–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Koliba, C.J.; Meek, J.W.; Zia, A.; Mills, R.W. Governance Networks in Public Administration and Public Policy; Routledge: London, UK, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Brown, T.L.; Potoski, M.; Van Slyke, D.M. Managing public service contracts: Aligning values, institutions, and markets. Public Adm. Rev. 2006, 66, 323–331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, C.; Liu, S.; Fang, Z.; Xie, N. The relation between Chinese economic development and energy consumption in the different periods. Energy Policy 2010, 38, 5189–5198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, Y.; Yu, Z.; Zhang, J. Research on carbon emission differences decomposition and spatial heterogeneity pattern of China’s eight economic regions. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 29976–29992. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, Y.; Xu, X. Carbon emission efficiency measurement and influencing factor analysis of nine provinces in the Yellow River basin: Based on SBM-DDF model and Tobit-CCD model. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 33263–33280. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Chen, H.; Long, R.; Sun, Q.; Jiang, S.; Liu, B. Has the sustainable development planning policy promoted the green transformation in China’s resource-based cities? Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2022, 180, 106181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Martínez, M.A.; Cámara, Á. Environmental changes produced by household consumption. Energies 2021, 14, 5730. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fan, Z.; Lei, Y.; Wu, S. Research on the changing trend of the carbon footprint of residents’ consumption in Beijing. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2019, 26, 4078–4090. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Observer Network. There Is No Shortage of Electricity in Zhejiang. In Order to Ensure the Emission Reduction Target, Power Is Limited, Which Affects the Operations of Some Enterprises. Available online: https://user.guancha.cn/main/content?id=432411.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese).
- Zhejiang Provincial People’s Government. Zhejiang Province’s “Thirteenth Five-Year Plan” Energy Saving and Emission Reduction Comprehensive Work Plan. Available online: https://www.zj.gov.cn/art/2022/6/30/art_1229621094_2409847.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Zhejiang Provincial Development and Reform Commission. Zhejiang Province Further Strengthens Energy “Dual Control” Implementation Plan to Promote High-Quality Development (2018–2020). Available online: https://fzggw.zj.gov.cn/art/2018/10/19/art_1229123351_581187.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Notice from the Zhejiang Provincial Development and Reform Commission. Provincial Development and Reform Commission and Provincial Energy Bureau on Issuing the Implementation Plan for the “Double Control” Assessment Work of the Municipal People’s Government of Zhejiang Province’s “Thirteenth Five-Year Plan” Energy Consumption Total Volume and Intensity. Available online: https://fzggw.zj.gov.cn/art/2018/1/5/art_1599544_30220003.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Zhejiang Provincial Development and Reform Commission. Announcement on the Responsibility Assessment Results of the Energy “Dual Control” Targets of Districts and Cities in 2016. Available online: https://fzggw.zj.gov.cn/art/2017/9/18/art_1599544_30219895.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Zhejiang Provincial Development and Reform Commission. Announcement on the Responsibility Assessment Results of the Energy “Dual Control” Targets of Districts and Cities in 2017. Available online: https://fzggw.zj.gov.cn/art/2018/4/20/art_1599544_30219679.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Zhejiang Provincial Development and Reform Commission. Announcement on the Responsibility Assessment Results of the Energy “Dual Control” Targets of Districts and Cities in 2018. Available online: https://fzggw.zj.gov.cn/art/2019/5/9/art_1621019_34124914.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Zhejiang Provincial Development and Reform Commission. Announcement on the Responsibility Assessment Results of the Energy “Dual Control” Targets of Districts and Cities in 2019. Available online: https://fzggw.zj.gov.cn/art/2020/7/31/art_1621019_53836786.html (accessed on 14 November 2023). (In Chinese)
- Liu, Z.; Yang, Y.; Wu, J. Participatory management, goal ambiguity, and gaming behaviors in performance management: Evidence from township government cadres in mainland China. Public Perform. Manag. Rev. 2021, 44, 58–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Behn, R.D. Why measure performance? Different purposes require different measures. Public Adm. Rev. 2003, 63, 586–606. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Becker, G.S. Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education; University of Chicago Press: Chicago, IL, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Li, B.; Barker, K.; Sansavini, G. Measuring Community and Multi-Industry Impacts of Cascading Failures in Power Systems. IEEE Syst. J. 2018, 12, 3585–3596. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alford, J. Defining the client in the public sector: A social-exchange perspective. Public Adm. Rev. 2002, 62, 337–346. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Friedman, D. Evolutionary games in economics. Econometrica 1991, 59, 637–666. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Axelrod, R.; Hamilton, W.D. The evolution of cooperation. Science 1981, 211, 1390–1396. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Lyapunov, A.M. The general problem of the stability of motion. Int. J. Control 1992, 55, 531–534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, L. Performance feedback, government goal-setting and aspiration level adaptation: Evidence from chinese provinces. Public Adm. 2016, 94, 452–471. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kroll, A.; Moynihan, D.P. Tools of control? Comparing congressional and presidential performance management reforms. Public Adm. Rev. 2021, 81, 599–609. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Whitaker, G.P. Coproduction: Citizen participation in service delivery. Public Adm. Rev. 1980, 40, 240–246. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Feeney, M.K.; Porumbescu, G. The limits of social media for public administration research and practice. Public Adm. Rev. 2021, 81, 787–792. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, L. Performance management and citizen satisfaction with the government: Evidence from chinese municipalities. Public Adm. 2017, 95, 39–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Categories of Indicators | Indicator Content | Score |
---|---|---|
Total energy consumption and intensity of “dual control” target indicators (40 points) | Annual energy consumption intensity reduction indicator | 10 |
“Thirteenth Five-Year Plan” energy consumption intensity reduction progress indicator | 15 | |
Annual total energy consumption control index | 5 | |
“Thirteenth Five-Year Plan” total energy consumption control progress indicators | 10 | |
Energy-saving measure implementation indicators (60 points) | Target responsibility | 9 |
Structural adjustment | 7 | |
Energy savings in key areas | 21 | |
Key projects | 2 | |
Technology promotion | 2 | |
Support policy | 6 | |
Market mechanism | 4 | |
Supervised check | 3 | |
Energy-saving management and service | 6 |
Principal | Role Classifications |
---|---|
Local government | Decision makers, motivators, and regulators |
Enterprises | Producers and emitters |
Residents | Consumers, emitters, and supervisors |
Strategy Type | Specific Measure | Strategic Impact |
---|---|---|
“Active power restriction” strategy | Actively introduce energy conservation and emission reduction policies | Strengthen the supervision of enterprise production behavior and support the development of environmentally friendly technologies, such as energy conservation and emission reduction; residents will feel the improvement in the air quality and get a better living experience |
“Passive power restriction” strategy | Take no action | No impact on businesses and residents |
Strategy Type | Specific Measure |
---|---|
“Active green transformation” strategy | Enterprises increase resources and invest in green technology, actively promote energy-saving transformation and upgrading, and continue to adopt environmentally friendly green production methods. |
The “status quo” strategy | Enterprises will passively respond to the government’s call, maintain the status quo, and continue to use the traditional production model. |
Strategy Type | Specific Performance |
---|---|
Engagement strategy | Residents actively respond to and support energy-saving policies, conduct the real-time supervision of corporate production behaviors, consciously consume environmentally friendly green products, and reduce carbon emissions from the source. |
Do not engage strategy | Residents do not participate in the supervision and feedback mechanisms of the corporate behavior and policy implementation and choose traditional products with relatively low prices for consumption. |
Subject Behavior | Costs and Benefits | Specific Costs and Benefits | Explanation |
---|---|---|---|
Local governments actively curtail electricity | Costs | Implementation costs | Refer to the costs paid by local governments to formulate, implement, and revise relevant carbon reduction policies and systems and to maintain the better operation of the regulatory system |
Loss of economic benefits | The impact on the local economy due to an active power restriction, such as the decline in added industrial value and the decrease in tax revenue due to the economic slowdown | ||
Loss of social benefits | Social instability caused by the migration of the permanent population and the reduction in public safety due to an unstable power supply | ||
Government support for enterprises | Government incentives for enterprises to actively reduce carbon emissions, such as green technology subsidies and preferential tax policies | ||
Benefits | Environmental benefits | Environmental benefits for actively limiting power to alleviate the pressure of the dual control assessment of energy consumption | |
Government punishment for enterprises | Enterprises maintain the status quo and reduce carbon emissions. If detected by the local government, companies will be fined, and these fines will become a part of the government’s revenue. | ||
Local governments eliminate power limits | Costs | Environmental loss | Refers to the adverse impact on the environment caused by the emission of greenhouse gases; to mitigate this adverse impact, a part of the economic cost must be consumed. |
Performance loss | The failure of the dual control index of the energy consumption leads to a negative performance appraisal. | ||
Income | Economic benefits | Refer to the direct implementation costs paid by local governments relative to the active implementation of the power restriction policy; cost savings can be achieved when the policy is passively implemented. |
Serial Number | Parameter Symbol | Meaning |
---|---|---|
1 | R0 | Basic benefits for the government when the government passively curtails electricity, enterprises maintain the status quo, and residents do not participate. |
2 | R1 | Environmental benefits from aggressive government curtailment. |
3 | R2 | Enterprises actively carry out a green transformation, with additional environmental benefits for the government. |
4 | R3 | Fines for businesses that maintain the status quo. |
5 | C1 | Enforcement costs of the government’s aggressive curtailment of electricity consumption. |
6 | C2 | Economic losses caused by aggressive government power restrictions. |
7 | C3 | Government support for enterprises with an active green transformation. |
8 | C4 | The government actively curtails power, and the power supply is unstable, resulting in the loss of social benefits. |
9 | W0 | Basic income of enterprises when the government passively curtails electricity, enterprises maintain the status quo, and residents do not participate. |
10 | W1 | Businesses that carry out a positive green transition gain additional reputational benefits when residents engage. |
11 | W2 | Economic benefits for enterprises with an active green transformation when the government actively curtails electricity. |
12 | K1 | Transition costs for companies actively carrying out a green transition. |
13 | K2 | Maintaining the status quo and the economic losses of enterprises in the event of aggressive government curtailments. |
14 | S0 | Basic income of residents when the government passively curtails electricity, enterprises maintain the status quo, and residents do not participate. |
15 | S1 | Environmental gains for residents when the government actively curtails electricity. |
16 | S2 | Enterprises actively carry out a green transformation, with residents reaping environmental benefits. |
17 | S3 | Social benefits obtained by residents who choose to participate in the government’s active power restriction. |
18 | L1 | Residents’ supervisory feedback cost incurred when they choose to participate when the government actively curtails the power. |
19 | L2 | Cost of supervision and feedback for residents who choose to participate when enterprises maintain the status quo. |
20 | L3 | Economic losses suffered by residents during the government’s aggressive power restrictions. |
Local Government | Enterprises | |
---|---|---|
Enterprises Actively Carry Out a Green Transformation (y) | Enterprises Maintain the Status Quo (1 − y) | |
The government actively curtails electricity (x). | R0 + R1 + R2 − C1 − C2 − C3 − C4 W0 + W1 + W2 + C3 − K1 S0 + S1 + S2 + S3 − L1 − L3 | R0 + R1 + R3 − C1 − C2 − C4 W0 − R3 − K2 S0 + S1 + S3 − L1 − L2 − L3 |
The government eliminates the power limit (1 − x). | R0 + R2 − C3 W0 + W1 + C3 − K1 S0 + S2 | R0 W0 S0− L2 |
Local Government | Enterprises | |
---|---|---|
Enterprises Actively Carry Out a Green Transformation (y) | Enterprises Maintain the Status Quo (1 − y) | |
The government actively curtails electricity (x). | R0 + R1 + R2 − C1 − C2 − C3 W0 + W2 + C3 − K1 S0 + S1 + S2 − L3 | R0 + R1 + R3 − C1 − C2 W0 − R3 − K2 S0 + S1 − L3 |
The government eliminates the power limit (1 − x). | R0 + R2 − C3 W0 − K1 + C3 S0 + S2 | R0 W0 S0 |
Equilibrium Point | Eigenvalues | ||
---|---|---|---|
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Xiong, F.; Su, Y.; Wu, J. Research on the Performance Management of Carbon Reduction by Local Governments from a Game Perspective—The Case of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident. Sustainability 2024, 16, 2318. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16062318
Xiong F, Su Y, Wu J. Research on the Performance Management of Carbon Reduction by Local Governments from a Game Perspective—The Case of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident. Sustainability. 2024; 16(6):2318. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16062318
Chicago/Turabian StyleXiong, Feng, Yue Su, and Jingyue Wu. 2024. "Research on the Performance Management of Carbon Reduction by Local Governments from a Game Perspective—The Case of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident" Sustainability 16, no. 6: 2318. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16062318
APA StyleXiong, F., Su, Y., & Wu, J. (2024). Research on the Performance Management of Carbon Reduction by Local Governments from a Game Perspective—The Case of the Zhejiang Power Restriction Incident. Sustainability, 16(6), 2318. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16062318