Households’ Willingness to Contribute to Irrigation Infrastructure in Rural China: The Role of Lineage and Outmigration
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Materials and Methods
2.1. A Model of Willingness to Participate in Irrigation Infrastructure Provision
2.2. Research Design—Survey
3. Results: Descriptive Statistics
3.1 Willingness to Participate in the Provision of Small-Scale Irrigation Infrastructures
3.1.1. SLNT and WPPSI
3.1.2. Hakka People and WPPSI
3.1.3. Place of Residence and WPPSI
3.1.4. Independent Variables Description
4. Results: Regression Analysis
4.1. Regression Analysis for the Sample
Significant Results across Models
4.2. Robustness Test
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Qin, H.; Liao, T.F. Labor out-migration and agricultural change in rural China: A systematic review and meta-analysis. J. Rural Stud. 2016, 47, 533–541. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Rudel, T.K. The commons and development: Unanswered sociological questions. Int. J. Commons 2011, 5, 303–318. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shou, H. Between the Formal and Informal: Institutions and Village Governance in Rural China. China Int. J. 2015, 13, 24–44. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, Y.; Chen, C.; Araral, E. The Effects of Migration on Collective Action in the Commons: Evidence from Rural China. World Dev. 2016, 88, 79–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aarnoudse, E.; Bluemling, B.; Wester, P.; Qu, W. The role of collective groundwater institutions in the implementation of direct groundwater regulation measures in Minqin County, China. Hydrogeol. J. 2012, 20, 1213–1221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, P.; Ravenscroft, N. Collective action in China’s recent collective forestry property rights reform. Land Use Policy 2016, 59, 402–411. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bluffstone, R.A.; Somanathan, E.; Jha, P.; Luintel, H.; Bista, R.; Paudel, N.S.; Adhikari, B. Does Collective Action Sequester Carbon? The Case of the Nepal Community Forestry Program. World Dev. 2018, 101, 133–141. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bisung, E.; Elliott, S.J.; Schuster-Wallace, C.J.; Karanja, D.M.; Bernard, A. Social capital, collective action and access to water in rural Kenya. Soc. Sci. Med. 2014, 119, 147–154. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chaudhry, A.M. Improving on-farm water use efficiency: Role of collective action in irrigation management. Water Resour. Econ. 2017, 22, 4–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. Constituting Social Capital and Collective Action. J. Theor. Politics 1994, 6, 527–562. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, L.; Luo, R.; Liu, C.; Rozelle, S. Investing in rural china: Tracking china’s commitment to modernization. Chin. Econ. 2014, 39, 57–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- CPC (Central Committee of the Communist Party of China) and the State Council. Decision of the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China and the State Council on Winning the Tough Battle against Poverty. 2015. Available online: http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/2015-12/07/content_5020963.htm (accessed on 27 May 2019).
- Matarrita-Cascante, D.; Brennan, M.A. Conceptualizing community development in the twenty-first century. Community Dev. 2012, 43, 293–305. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, S. Township Governance and Institutionalization in China. Series on Contemporary China; World Scientific Publishing: London, UK, 2014; Volume 32. [Google Scholar]
- Pesqué-Cela, V.; Tao, R.; Liu, Y.; Sun, L. Challenging, complementing or assuming ‘the Mandate of Heaven’? Political distrust and the rise of self-governing social organizations in rural China. J. Comp. Econ. 2009, 37, 151–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lieberthal, K. Governing China—From Revolution through Reform, 2nd ed; W.W. Norton & Company: New York, NY, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Tsai, L.L. Cadres, Temple and Lineage Institutions, and Governance in Rural China. China J. 2002, 48, 1–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bluemling, B.; Pahl-Wostl, C.; Yang, H.; Mosler, H.J. Implications of stakeholder constellations for the implementation of irrigation rules at jointly used wells-cases from the North China Plain, China. Soc. Nat. Resour. 2010, 23, 557–572. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Thøgersen, S. Organizing Rural China: Political and Academic Discourses. In Organizing Rural China—Rural China Organizing; Bislev, A., Thøgersen, S., Eds.; Lexington Books: Plymouth, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Pan, Y. Born with the Right Surname? Lineage Networks and Political and Economic Opportunities in Rural China; Working Paper; Louisiana State University: Baton Rouge, LA, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Tsai, L.L. Solidary groups, informal accountability, and local public goods provision in rural China. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 2007, 101, 355–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Peng, Y. Lineage Networks, Rural Entrepreneurs, and Max Weber; Keister, L.A., Ed.; Emerald Group Publishing Limited: Bingley, UK, 2005; pp. 327–355. [Google Scholar]
- Freedman, M. Lineage Organization in Southeastern China; University Athlone Press: London, UK, 1965. [Google Scholar]
- Duara, P. Culture, Power, and the State: Rural North China, 1900–1942; Stanford University Press: Stanford, CA, USA, 1991. [Google Scholar]
- Szonyi, M. Lineages and the Making of Contemporary China Modern Chinese Religion II: 1850-2015 (2 Vols); BRILL: Leiden, The Netherlands, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Zhu, L.; Cai, Y. Institutions and Provision of Public Goods in Rural China: An Empirical Study Based on Villages in Guangdong Province. China Rev. 2016, 16, 55–83. [Google Scholar]
- Chen, J.; Huhe, N. Informal Accountability, Socially Embedded Officials, and Public Goods Provision in Rural China: The Role of Lineage Groups. J. Chin. Political Sci. 2013, 18, 101–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xu, Y.; Yao, Y. Informal institutions, collective action, and public investment in rural china. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 2015, 109, 371–391. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beyene, F. Inter clan cooperation in a risky pastoral ecology: Some lessons from eastern Ethiopia. Hum. Ecol. 2010, 38, 555–565. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Brown, H.C.P.; Lassoie, J.P. Institutional choice and local legitimacy in community-based forest management: Lessons from Cameroon. Environ. Conserv. 2010, 37, 261–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, N. Secularization, sacralization and the reproduction of sacred space: Exploring the industrial use of ancestral temples in rural Wenzhou, China. Soc. Cult. Geogr. 2017, 18, 530–552. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lu, Y.; Tao, R. Organizational structure and collective action: Lineage networks, semiautonomous civic associations, and collective resistance in rural China. Am. J. Sociol. 2017, 122, 1726–1774. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chai, Y.; Zeng, Y. Social capital, institutional change, and adaptive governance of the 50-year-old Wang hilltop pond irrigation system in Guangdong, China. Int. J. Commons 2018, 12, 191–216. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Narisong, H.; Jie, C.; Tang, M. Social trust and grassroots governance in rural China. Soc. Sci. Res. 2015, 53, 351–363. [Google Scholar]
- He, Q.; Pan, Y.; Sarangi, S. Lineage-based Heterogeneity and Cooperative Behavior in Rural China. J. Comp. Econ. 2018, 46, 248–269. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Israel, A. Issues for Infrastructure Management in the 1990s. Available online: http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/414461468181451572/pdf/multi0page.pdf (accessed on 30 June 2019).
- Hudson, W.R.; Haas, R.C.G.; Uddin, W. Infrastructure Management: Integrating Design, Construction, Maintenance, Rehabilitation and Renovation; McGraw-Hill: New York, NY, USA, 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Fei, X.; Hamilton, G.G.; Wang, Z. From the Soil, the Foundations of Chinese Society: A Translation of Fei Xiaotong’s Xiangtu Zhongguo, with an Introduction and Epilogue; University of California Press: Berkeley, CA, USA, 1992. [Google Scholar]
- Rosemont, H.; Ames, R.T. The Chinese Classic of Family Reverence: A Philosophical Translation of the Xiaojing; University of Hawaii Press: Honolulu, HI, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Peng, Y. Kinship Networks and Entrepreneurs in China’s Transitional Economy. Am. J. Sociol. 2004, 109, 1045–1074. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chen, N. Governing rural culture: Agency, space and the re-production of ancestral temples in contemporary China. J. Rural Stud. 2016, 47, 141–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, T.; Zhao, X. Do Kinship Networks Strengthen Private Property? Evidence from Rural China. J. Empir. Leg. Stud. 2014, 11, 505–540. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jicha, K.A. Individual-Level Predictors of Social Capital and Participation in Collective Action on the Island of Carriacou, Grenada. Ph.D. Thesis, North Carolina State University, Raleigh, NC, USA, 2011. [Google Scholar]
- Jina, C.; Zhong, T. Factor mobility, household resource endowments and agricultural technology adoption: Literature review and theoretical explanation. J. Jiangxi Univ. Financ. Econ. 2013, 4, 68–77. [Google Scholar]
- Xiangzhi, K.; Songhai, F.; Xiaopeng, P.; Jiujie, M. Analysis of the Effect of Household Endowments on the Agricultural Technology Adoption Decision in West China. Econ. Res. J. 2004, 12, 85–95. [Google Scholar]
- Feng, S.; Heerink, N. Are farm households’ land renting and migration decisions inter-related in rural China? NJAS Wagening. J. Life Sci. 2008, 55, 345–362. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Peng, Y. When Formal Laws and Informal Norms Collide: Lineage Networks versus Birth Control Policy in China. Am. J. Sociol. 2010, 116, 770–805. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
Item | Category | Quantity | Percentage | Item | Category | Quantity | Percentage |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gender | Male | 129 | 84.87 | Education level | Primary school and below | 32 | 21.05 |
Female | 23 | 15.13 | Junior middle high school | 58 | 38.16 | ||
Age | Age 16–20 | 1 | 0.6 | Technical secondary/high school | 46 | 30.26 | |
Age 21–40 | 76 | 50 | College | 14 | 9.21 | ||
Age 41–60 | 60 | 39.47 | Master/PhD | 2 | 1.32 | ||
Over the age of 60 | 15 | 9.8 | Period of living in village | Under 20 years | 14 | 9.21 | |
Political status | Party member | 44 | 28.95 | 20–39 years | 68 | 44.74 | |
Communist Youth League member | 5 | 3.29 | 40–59 years | 53 | 34.87 | ||
General public | 103 | 67.76 | Over 60 years | 17 | 11.18 | ||
Place of residence | Living in village | 122 | 80.26 | Household labor (number) | 0–1 | 8 | 5.26 |
Living in cities and towns | 30 | 19.74 | 2–3 | 116 | 76.32 | ||
4–7 | 28 | 18.42 | |||||
Total number | 152 | Total number | 152 |
Item | Category | Totally Unwilling←——————→Perfectly Willing | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 1 > , ≤ 2 | 2 > , ≤ 3 | 3 > , ≤ 4 | 4 > , < 5 | 5 | ||
Proportion | Proportion | Proportion | Proportion | Proportion | Proportion | ||
SLNT | With ancestral temple or genealogy * | 0 | 0 | 7.59 | 25.32 | 36.71 | 30.38 |
No ancestral temple or genealogy | 5.48 | 0 | 23.29 | 35.62 | 20.55 | 15.07 | |
Department of people | Hakka | 0 | 0 | 6.82 | 27.27 | 56.82 | 9.09 |
Non-Hakka | 3.70 | 0 | 18.52 | 31.48 | 17.59 | 28.70 | |
Place of residence | Village | 1.82 | 0 | 17.27 | 30.00 | 23.64 | 27.27 |
Cities and towns | 4.76 | 0 | 9.52 | 30.95 | 42.86 | 11.90 | |
Total | 2.63 | 0 | 15.13 | 30.26 | 28.95 | 23.03 |
Variable | Index | Variable Definitions | Means | Standard Deviation | Minimum Value | Maximum Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Dependent variable | ||||||
WPPSI | sample of households’ WPPSI(y) | The average continuous variable value of five-point Likert scale | 4.061 | 0.893 | 1 | 5 |
Independent variable | ||||||
SLNT | Head of households’ lineage with ancestral temple or genealogy (x1) | Yes = 1, No = 0 | 0.519 | 0.501 | 0 | 1 |
Social capital endowment | Family members living in cities and towns (x2) | Yes = 1, No = 0 | 0.276 | 0.449 | 0 | 1 |
Hakka (x3) | Yes = 1, No = 0 | 0.289 | 0.455 | 0 | 1 | |
Period the head of household living in the village (x4) | Reported value of the respondents (year) | 38.336 | 17.258 | 2 | 94 | |
political status (x5) | Party members = 1 Communist Youth League members = 2 The masses = 3 Others = 4 | 2.408 | 0.930 | 1 | 4 | |
Relationship with the villager (x6) | Good, very harmonious = 5, Well = 4, In general, neither good nor bad = 3, Poor relationship, not very good = 2 Very poor, large friction, hostile state = 1 | 3.099 | 1.603 | 1 | 5 | |
Economic resources endowments | Income (x7) CNY (Chinese Yuan) | Logarithmic (yuan/year household) respondents’ reported values | 47341.6 | 114514.7 | 0 | 1015000 |
House size (x8) | Logarithmic (square meter) respondents’ reported values | 193.449 | 130.004 | 0 | 810 | |
House structure (x9) | Reinforced concrete structures = 5, Brick structure = 4, Wood and brick structure = 3, Stone/wood/cottage, adobe houses, shacks = 2, Others = 1 | 3.152 | 1.186 | 1 | 5 | |
Family labor endowments | Family labor force (x10) | Reported value of the respondents (number of people) | 2.730 | 1.196 | 1 | 7 |
Traffic location endowment | Distance from the main road (x11) | Reported value of the respondents (kilometer) | 2.391 | 3.509 | 0 | 20 |
Family education endowments | Education level of the head of household (x12) | Primary school and below = 1, Junior middle school = 2, Technical secondary/high school = 3, College = 4, Mastker/PhD = 5 | 2.322 | 0.987 | 1 | 5 |
Agricultural land endowment | Land area (x13) | Reported value of the respondents(mu) | 2.946 | 2.371 | 0 | 11 |
Individual characteristics | Age (x14) | Reported value of the respondents(age) | 41.281 | 13.314 | 16 | 94 |
Independent Variable | Dependent Variable: WPPSI | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 | Model 2 | Model 3 | Model 4 | Model 5 | Model 6 | |
With ancestral temple or genealogy (x1) | 0.8065 *** (0.20609) | 0.8832 *** (0.23576) | 0.8296 *** (0.21104) | 0.8649 *** (0.23247) | ||
Family members living in cities and towns (x2) | 0.0776 (0.28651) | −0.1340 0.27701 | −0.1432 (0.27531) | |||
Hakka (x3) | 0.3067 (0.00936) | −0.1544 (0.29473) | −0.1639 (0.29412) | |||
Period the head of household living in the village (x4) | 0.0150 (0.00888) | 0.0161 (0.00975) | 0.0163 (0.00996) | 0.0135 (0.00923) | 0.0138 (0.00917) | 0.0146 (0.00895) |
Political status (x5) | 0.1251 (0.11268) | 0.1359 (0.11935) | 0.1310 (0.11772) | 0.1235 (0.11336) | 0.1223 (0.11288) | 0.1262 (0.11319) |
Relationship with community members (x6) | 0.1375 (0.08403) | 0.2046 * 0.09016 | 0.1915 * (0.08819) | 0.1494 *** (0.08618) | 0.1454 (0.08546) | 0.1423 (0.08485) |
Income (x7) | −3.16e-07 (7.77e-07) | 5.89e-08 (8.51e-07) | −1.03e-07 (8.33e-07) | −1.34e-07 (8.18e-07) | −2.11e-07 (8.03e-07) | −2.27e-07 7.95e-07 |
House size (x8) | −0.0004 (0.00096) | −0.0009 (0.00102) | −0.0008 (0.00100) | −0.0004 (0.00097) | −0.0004 (0.00096) | −0.0004 0.00097 |
House structure (x9) | −0.0779 (0.10792) | −0.1086 (0.11519) | −0.1197 (0.11431) | −0.0680 (0.10934) | −0.0759 (0.10803) | −0.0693 (0.10929) |
Family labor force (x10) | −0.2394 * (0.10332) | −0.1898 * (0.11192) | −0.2339 * (0.11680) | −0.2065 * (0.11338) | −0.2274 * (0.10581) | −0.2163 * 0.11156 |
Distance from the main road (x11) | −0.0487 (0.02986) | −0.0514 (0.03181) | −0.0479 (0.03149) | −0.0494 (0.03014) | −0.0479 (0.02991) | −0.0503 (0.03009) |
Education level of the head of household (x12) | −0.2075 (0.13346) | −0.1426 (0.14217) | −0.1719 (0.14166) | −0.1828 (0.13802) | −0.1955 (0.13542) | −0.1933 (0.13633) |
Land area (x13) | 0.0899 (0.06449) | 0.1262 (0.06852) | 0.1270 * (0.06729) | 0.0845 (0.06530) | 0.0874 (0.06472) | 0.0868 (0.06511) |
Age (14) | −0.0071 (0.01154) | −0.0026 (0.01223) | −0.0052 (0.01231) | 0.0056 (0.01179) | −0.0067 (0.01157) | −0.0059 (0.01178) |
Constant term | 4.1267 *** (0.76976) | 3.8480 *** 0.81293 | 4.1365 *** (0.84616) | 3.9622 *** (0.81530) | 4.0944 *** (0.77259) | 3.9844 *** (0.81361) |
Sample size | 152 | 152 | 152 | 152 | 152 | 152 |
Independent Variable | Dependent Variable: WPPSI | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Model 1 Living in Villages | Model 2 Living in Cities and Towns | Model 3 Party Members | Model 4 Non-Party Members | Model 5 Higher Than Technical Secondary/High School | Model 6 Lower than Technical Secondary/High School | |
With ancestral temple or genealogy (x1) | 0.8269 ** (0.26360) | 1.6526 ** (0.59067) | 1.3841 ** 0.46376 | 0.8200 ** (0.25286) | 0.9221 * (0.41056) | 1.6111 *** 0.35253 |
Family members living in cities and towns (x2) | −1.6845 * 0.69941 | 0.3118 (0.33247) | −0.6779 (0.42649) | 0.3538 0.45379 | ||
Hakka (x3) | −0.5341 (0.37332) | −0.1537 (0.54805) | 0.2554 (0.66278) | −0.4395 (0.29908) | 1.0826 * 0.52212 | −1.336 ** 0.42160 |
Period the head of household living in the village (x4) | 0.0070 (0.01179) | 0.0578 (0.02656) | −0.0008 (0.02132) | 0.0289 ** (0.01041) | 0.0135 (0.01593) | 0.0164 0.01204 |
Political status (x5) | 0.1265 (0.13719) | 0.2004 (0.21353) | −0.1049 (0.18351) | 0.1529 0.17193 | ||
Relationship with community members (x6) | 0.1439 (0.10365) | 0.2502 (0.25097) | 0.3402 (0.18116) | −0.0043 (0.09564) | 0.0923 (0.15669) | 0.1405 0.10429 |
Income (x7) | 6.42e-06 (5.61e-06) | −7.95e-07 (8.33e-07) | 6.38e-06 (7.44e-06) | −4.32e-08 (6.79e-07) | −2.23e-06 (3.53e-06) | −2.98e-07 8.44e-07 |
House size (x8) | −0.0014 (0.00127) | 0.0016 (0.00212) | −0.0006 (0.00206) | 0.0007 (0.00105) | −0.0014 (0.00169) | −0.0006 0.00130 |
House structure (x9) | −0.0079 (0.13662) | −0.1670 (0.20278) | 0.2165 (0.25878) | −0.1784 (0.10810) | −0.0357 (0.172890) | −0.0069 0.13835 |
Family labor force (x10) | −0.3014 * (0.13480) | 0.1465 (0.23636) | −0.2982 (0.21056) | −0.1985 (0.12176) | −0.2629 (0.23578) | −0.2196 0.13413 |
Distance from the main road (x11) | −0.0337 (0.03893) | −0.1656 * (0.07362) | 0.0418 (0.07613) | −0.0581 * (0.02777) | −0.0063 (0.04898) | −0.0937 * 0.04267 |
Education level of the head of household (x12) | −0.2143 (0.16726) | 0.0158 (0.31487) | −0.4340 (0.26426) | −0.4845 ** (0.16359) | ||
Land area (x13) | 0.1469 (0.07714) | −0.1103 (0.14307) | 0.1362 (0.13637) | 0.1523 * (0.06754) | 0.0898 (0.09826) | 0.0551 0.09065 |
Age (14) | 0.0016 (0.01391) | −0.0175 (0.02794) | −0.0089 (0.02945) | −0.02455 * (0.01223) | 0.0097 (0.02663) | −0.0003 0.01456 |
Constant term | 3.9604 *** (0.92873) | 0.9667 (2.2273) | 2.7966 (1.52027) | 6.0492 *** (1.04041) | 4.0359 (2.27554) | 2.6560 ** (0.871713) |
Sample size | 110 | 42 | 48 | 104 | 62 | 90 |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Yang, Y.; Wang, F. Households’ Willingness to Contribute to Irrigation Infrastructure in Rural China: The Role of Lineage and Outmigration. Water 2020, 12, 1852. https://doi.org/10.3390/w12071852
Yang Y, Wang F. Households’ Willingness to Contribute to Irrigation Infrastructure in Rural China: The Role of Lineage and Outmigration. Water. 2020; 12(7):1852. https://doi.org/10.3390/w12071852
Chicago/Turabian StyleYang, Yu, and Fang Wang. 2020. "Households’ Willingness to Contribute to Irrigation Infrastructure in Rural China: The Role of Lineage and Outmigration" Water 12, no. 7: 1852. https://doi.org/10.3390/w12071852
APA StyleYang, Y., & Wang, F. (2020). Households’ Willingness to Contribute to Irrigation Infrastructure in Rural China: The Role of Lineage and Outmigration. Water, 12(7), 1852. https://doi.org/10.3390/w12071852