1. Introduction
The progressive move towards market-oriented agriculture instigates a virtuous cycle helping leapfrog productivity and farmers’ income which, in turn, contribute to poverty reduction, food security, improved urban-rural linkages, and economic growth [
1,
2]. In this transformation, profit maximization drives input and production decisions and reinforces a vertical and well-integrated linkage between input and output markets [
3]. Nonetheless, out of 575 million total farms worldwide, 475 million farms own less than 2-hectares of land and produce for auto-consumption [
4,
5]. Like other developing countries, the dominance of small farmers in Pakistan coupled with the failure of formal credit institutions affects smallholder farmers’ production decision(s), triggers disintegration between rural and urban markets, and widens the productivity, income, and food security gap [
6,
7]. Only 16% of smallholders obtain institutional credit in Pakistan, whereas 31% directly depend on commercial sector banks and microfinance lending institutions. Almost 71% of smallholder farmer’s depend on market intermediaries for credit, input and other operational services [
8]. Although market intermediaries—village-level brokers, assemblers and local traders—are the financial powerhouse that offers credit services to overcome these snags, their role is often regarded as that of parasites [
9,
10]. These agents take advantage of their provided services, farmers’ low social status and weak bargaining power, and grab a significant share of benefits accrued from the sale of crops, leaving farmers to sell their produce in village-level unregulated markets at low price [
11,
12,
13]. This further reduces the farmers’ commercialization scope and weakens the degree of integration between urban and rural markets [
1]. Hence, most of the farmers get trapped in a vicious circle of poverty characterized, inter alia, by low productivity, on the one hand, and the existence of an oligopsony or monopsony type market structure, on the other hand, yielding low economic returns [
3,
14].
Agricultural credit is the fuel of broader agribusiness and boosts the farmers’ commercial activities through increased market participation in rural and urban-centered markets [
15]. Limited access to agricultural financial services, including insurance, credit, and savings, tends to mar farmers’ commercial activities, income, and market participation [
16,
17,
18]. Like other developing countries, due to credit constraints, the high cost of lending money and high credit dependence on market intermediaries, only 23% of the smallholder farmers sell their produce in regulated urban markets. Similarly, only 34% of rice farmers made their way to such output markets and obtained a fair price [
8]. To usher broader commercial agriculture and economic trajectory and meet the agenda of financial inclusion and broader urban-rural integration, Pakistan has fostered institutional financial markets by launching an E-Credit scheme to provide interest-free agriculture credit [
19]. Objectively, this scheme was initiated to protect smallholders and tenant farmers from informal money lenders’ exploitation, reduce the production cost, improve productivity, income, market participation, and outreach of digital and formal financial services. Thus, with such development objectives, total agricultural credit increased from Rupees 248,120 Million in 2010 to Rupees 704,448 Million in 2018. Under this scheme, 314,000 farmers amongst 149,271 rice growers in specialized production and export areas have been facilitated so far [
8]. This scheme was implemented to improve financial capacity building and the commercial and entrepreneurial capabilities of farmers. Importantly, in the wake of enormous potential opportunities and economic benefits arising along with the China-Pakistan Economic Corridor (CPEC), the resulting improved regional integration might not be possible to achieve without a plausible agriculture credit policy [
20,
21]. However, considering many challenges, inter alia, there is a dire need to ’balance increasing productivity, farmers’ income, and commercialization to ensure sufficient food supply while reducing the exploitative nature of the credit market and informal money lenders.
Understanding the extent and drivers of the move towards smallholder commercialization has significant scope for coherent policymaking. Many studies show that agriculture credit provision affects farmers’ market participation and urban-rural linkages [
22,
23,
24,
25]. Mariyono [
26] documents that agriculture credit participation fulfills the need for operating capital and enforces high-level agriculture commercialization. Contrary, recent evidence based on randomized designs reveals that microcredits fail to produce high-returns due to the high cost of lending [
27,
28,
29], thereby resulting in a decline in smallholder farmers’ market participation and urban-rural integration. Linh et al. [
27] reviewed previous literature on agriculture credit impact, and whilst positive results are common, they noted considerable variability within these results that should be treated with caution when overcoming econometric challenges. Likewise, Pham and Lensink [
28] underpin that, in terms of access, formal and informal agriculture credit are entirely different, and thus imply that they are unrelated and independent in their impacts on the level of market participation. Indeed, existing studies provide inconclusive and inconsistent findings regarding the effect of agriculture credit on the level of market participation, mainly due to several variations: decision to borrow, institutional and non-institutional sources of agriculture credit, size of the amount, and the interest rate charged [
27,
28,
29,
30]. Further, no research has studied the impact of interest-free agriculture credit on smallholder market participation and urban-rural linkages in a developing country context. Yet it remains unanswered whether the provision of interest-free agriculture credit might work as a lever to 1) lower short-run credit constraints, 2) impact production decisions by employing more factors), particularly land, and 3) foster smallholder farmer’s market participation, both in the case of six-month loans or crop loans (short-term) and one-year loans, and urban-rural linkages. Moreover, studying the impact of interest-free agriculture credit, particularly in a developing country, is a new avenue for linking small farmers to urban food value chains that might be a promising tool for rural poverty alleviation. Policymakers also need to ensure ’value for money’ by going beyond the overall interventions’—interest-free credit—ripple effects and represent it as a worthy investment. Given these factors, estimating the impact of interest-free agriculture credit is prudent to ensure an unbiased outcome that robustly addresses the plethora of confounding factor(s), endogeneity, and self-selection bias, measurement error, and other related econometric challenges [
31,
32,
33].
In a nutshell, investigating the effect of interest-free agriculture credit is a novel gauge that is important for many reasons: (a) a good policy lever to reduce imperfections in credit markets, (b) a robust instrument for changing cash-strapped farmers’ interest in employing factors of production adequately, when studying the transition from subsistence to commercialized systems, (c) distinguish between the level of market participation caused by formal (interest charged), informal and interest-free agriculture credit, and (d) envisioning a well-integrated vertical linkage between input and output markets, urban-rural integration, productivity, and income to avoid surplus production and, therefore, the burden of agriculture subsidies. In this regard, we used an Instrumental Variable (IV) approach to draw on positive goals. First, we examine the effect of interest-free agriculture credit on farmers’ level of market participation and urban-rural integration. Second, we establish and compare various indexes to explore the extent of market participation, market-orientation, agriculture commercialization, and integration into the cash economy. Lastly, we measure the impact of credit participation on productivity and farmers’ income.
The next section of the study is the conceptual framework.
Section 3 represents detailed information on interventions, data, and empirical measures used.
Section 4 reports results and discussion on these results. Subsequently, concluding remarks, limitations and future research directions are examined.
2. Conceptual Framework
Investing in agriculture, particularly among smallholders in developing countries, might be a plausible lever to foster urban-rural linkages, reduce rural poverty and reach sustainable development [
14]. Timmer [
34] endorses that investment in agriculture is a fundamental commercialization tool that ushers in productivity, rural transformation, and economic diversification. Investing in agriculture-based economies—like Pakistan’s, where most of the population (43%) relies on agriculture, increases productivity, gives access to market and modern food supply chains, and helps move towards market-oriented and/or commercial agriculture [
35,
36,
37]. Further, investing in smallholder agriculture can encourage sustainability in the face of mounting environmental and food crises [
38,
39,
40]. Therefore, there is a need to understand and design programs and interventions that recognize the heterogeneity of smallholder agriculture and shedding a significant impact on their market participation level is a matter of foremost concern [
41]. Likewise, an alternative argument is poorly supported by research failing to explore smallholders’ capacities to engage in commercial activities [
42], particularly when they are provided with interest-free operating capital.
Why is smallholders’ market participation vital for rural poverty reduction, urban-rural linkages and farmer’s welfare? We can trace the answer from rational choice theory. Generally, this theory offers a foundation to study individual farmers’ behavior in market participation decision making. This theory is based on the core principle of individual decision-making, where individuals face snags while making choices among market goods and services. In such situations, it provides insights on how individuals decide upon participation in interest-free agriculture credit to achieve or maximize utility, constrained by uncontrollable factors. The rational choice theory discourse states that the demand for agriculture credit generally involves several aspects: (1) the type and nature of credit services provided, (2) the need for financial services (i.e., credit, saving, insurance, etc.), and (3) the terms and conditions under which market intermediaries or financial institutions provide these services [
43]. Thus, under given circumstances, i.e., the interest-free nature of credit, farmers are encouraged to participate in interest-free credit and, therefore, make choices to enhance areas under rice production to expand market participation in the presence of uncontrolled factors. Further, the interactions developed due to improved information sharing and market participation instigate larger-scale production and the adoption of dynamic technologies that improve productivity, farm income, urban-rural linkages and welfare of the rural communities [
44,
45]. Robustly, on the supply side, transaction cost theory provides the foundations for participation in interest-free agriculture credit. Transaction cost theory opines that smallholders would not be encouraged to participate in the market until the lending cost is kept to the lowest level [
46]. Net welfare gains from market-oriented production are not just because of trade-off, but perhaps come more from the opportunities emerging from vertical integration and large-scale commercial production in the presence of sunk or nontrivial fixed cost of production [
47].
What does it take to break the trap or vicious cycle of auto-consumption and semi-subsistence agriculture poverty traps in a developing country like Pakistan? According to Barrett and Swallow [
48], limited access to credit and poor physical infrastructure represent low-level equilibria. Given this, lack of credit and related incentives prompt auto-consumption and/or semi-consumption, characterized by, inter alia, poverty trap (low-level equilibrium), a rudimentary production, capital constraints, and modest market participation and urban-rural integration. Contrary, holding other factor(s) constant, interest-free agriculture credit might help achieve a virtuous cycle of agriculture commercialization (high-level equilibria) by increasing the area under rice production, technology use, productivity and income, and reducing the cost of production [
49]. Thus, under given circumstances, farmers are encouraged to rationally make choices to achieve a higher income and welfare gains in the presence of uncontrolled factors (see
Figure 1).
4. Results and Discussion
Given the presumption that OLS might lead to biased estimates, we ran OLS in addition to IV models to illustrate the difference between both estimations to address the endogeneity concerns. Next, the three IVs were inserted individually and collectively for first and second-time participation to monitor their effects on market participation and subsequent diagnostic checks. Thus, in total, six models were estimated: one using OLS, and five 2SLS, using individually and collectively three IVs for both models, respectively. Furthermore, the results based on calculated market participation and commercialization (urban-rural integration) indexes are presented. Finally, the impact of credit participation on productivity and farmers’ income is estimated.
4.1. First Stage Results
Based on the preceding debate, we ran a probit function (first-stage of IV process) estimating the determinants of participation in interest-free agriculture credit, presented in
Table 2. Most of the covariates and IVs included showing the expected sign. Age and literacy have a significant effect on participation in interest-free credit. As expected, literate and young farmers are more inclined to seek progressive opportunities than illiterate and old farmers, and thus have a greater probability of participating in interest-free credit. Livestock heads as a source of farmers’ immediate wealth were found to have a negative effect on credit participation. This indicates that better-off farmers do not tend to participate in interest-free credit. Interestingly, distance from all-weather roads as an indicator of market access shows a negative effect on interest-free credit participation. This justifies that under-development in the area creates substantial transportation costs, which hinders farmers from engaging in progressive opportunities aimed at broader agriculture commercialization. Fortunately, all of the three chosen IVs that are also among the pre-conditions of participation, the willingness to constitute a group, land registration with PLRA, and social collateral, also show a significant positive effect on participation in interest-free agriculture credit. This clarifies that farmers with entrepreneurial mindsets who prefer collaborations and are more concerned about land property rights and public sector initiatives have a higher possibility of participating in interest-free credit than those who pay no heed to policy change and remain wrapped up in the social evils which frequently occur in rural districts. Furthermore, the diagnostic check results confirm endogeneity using OLS and, therefore, endorse the validity of instruments applied using 2SLS (see
Table 3).
4.2. Second Stage Results
The second-stage involves inserting the chosen valid and statistically appropriate treatment of the endogenous regressor into the main structural model, both individually and collectively, and applying them to the outcome variable. Accordingly,
Table 4 represents the results of IV estimates for the key variable of interest, credit participation, with diagnostic statistics for clarity, including other covariates, available in
Appendix A,
Table A2,
Table A3 and
Table A4. Further, the results of the OLS estimation are also presented for comparison.
The OLS estimates show a consistent negative effect of first-period credit participation on farmers’ market participation. It indicates four mounds per acre decrease in rice crop output sold in the market, ceteris paribus. This estimation suffers the endogeneity problem as the coefficients of IV models predict more consistent estimates. The results of selected diagnostic statistics also validate the need for IV models. It shows 16 mounds per acre decrease in market participation when collectively applying the three IVs. However, it indicates a consistent but fairly slight decrease when applying the individual IV. This reflects that provision of a crop loan only for six months tends to decrease market participation. There might be several reasons for this decrease. First, credit is being granted before crop cultivation (meeting running expenses, i.e., purchase of inputs, land preparation, and buying other crop inputs) and, therefore, farmers must need to return it at the crop harvest or sometimes before. Second, during the focus group discussion, several farmers’ claimed that lending for such a meager period worsens their plight and further increases their engagement with village-level stakeholders, i.e., local dealers and traders. Third, farmers also highlight that while providing social collateral, usually they were asked to provide two guarantors from influential village families or their immediate family members and, therefore, while being pledged on the farmers’ behalf, they started visiting farmers one or two months ahead of the deadline which, in turn, put greater pressure on them. Indeed, at the time of crop harvest, due to surplus rice production in the country, prices are usually at their lowest level, leaving them to lend from market intermediaries to meet pledged repayment before the deadline. Accordingly, this forced them into a cash-strapped dilemma which initiates a debt cycle where farmers seek credit to repay previously due loans. These findings are in line with Hung et al. [
57], Kirimi [
58], and Arinloye [
59]. Further, these findings complement Feder’s [
60] arguments indicating the divergent role of short-term credit. Hence, it suggests that ’crop credit’ is often utilized to pay over-due farm credit and consumption and fails to transform from subsistence to commercialized agriculture systems.
Contrary, results based on consecutive second-period credit participation (interaction second period) show a positive connection between interest-free credit and market participation (see
Table 4). Approximately, it indicates 25 mounds per acre increase in rice output sold in the market. It reinstates that provision of interest-free credit for another consecutive period increases farmers’ ability to store their rice produce for a period until they find fair market prices and sell in markets rather than the village and to local stakeholders at lower prices. Further, inter alia, interest-free capital reduced production cost by enabling cash payments, decreased farmers’ reliance on local stakeholders for credit and crop inputs, and thus got rid of the integrated and spillover effect improved market participation. Interestingly, most of the covariates represent significant effects, but credit participation introduces the largest impact on market participation (see
Appendix A,
Table A2,
Table A3 and
Table A4). This suggests that the form of the lending institution, interest-free nature, and relaxation in the repayment period reflect farmers’ market participation. Similar findings have been noted by prior studies [
22,
23,
24,
28,
29].
4.3. Extent of Commercialization and Urban-Rural Integration
The extent of market participation and agriculture commercialization is a distinctive measure when dealing with the sampled households, consisting of auto-consumer and semi-commercial households [
61]. We followed the presumption that the provision of interest-free credit might be a phenomenal lever to change production decisions among smallholders and could create a differential change between participants and non-participants, notably, in terms of increased agriculture commercialization and vertical urban-rural integration. For the purpose, we calculated indexes as follows: (1) market participation index, (2) marketability index, (3) market orientation index, (4) agriculture commercialization index of input, (5) agriculture commercialization index of output, (6) commercialization of rural economy, (7) degree of integration into the cash economy, (8) vertical urban-rural integration of input, (9) and vertical urban-rural integration of output. The value of these indexes varies between 0 and 1. However, a value equal or slightly above 0.50 indicates that a household has escaped from auto-consumption and entered into semi-commercialization, whereas a value close to 1 shows a high extent of commercialization and urban-rural vertical linkage. These indexes help indicate the difference in non-participants, first-period participants, second period, and above two-period participants [
62,
63], as illustrated in
Table 5.
First, we calculated the market participation index for all the designated categories herein. This is the ratio of the value of rice products sold in the market and the total value of rice products produced at the average market price. Results indicate that the provision of interest-free credit for only one period decreased rice crop market participation. However, it shows a significant improvement in market participation for farmers who secured credit for consecutive next crop and/or above two periods. This reinforces our empirical results and implies that credit provision for a very short period (six months) adds to farmers’ plight. This protects smallholder entry into commercialized agriculture from auto-consumption or subsistence systems. In fact, farmers having secured credit for the immediate next crop have a greater possibility of waiting for stability in market prices for rice and make no hurry to sell their produce at the time of harvest. Hence, they do not feel any immediate credit liability and participate in the market rather than selling their produce to rural stakeholders. Thus, the provision of credit for one year serves a better function in improving rice crop market participation in Pakistan. Next, we examined farmers’ marketability index. This refers to the ratio of the total value of all crops sold in the market and the total value of quantity produced at the average market price. Results show that both non-participants and one period credit participants fall into auto-consumption or subsistence agriculture; therefore, credit for only one crop fails to meet the proposed agenda. Conversely, second and above two times participation shows a substantial improvement in farmers’ marketability extent, bringing them into a high level of agriculture commercialization from subsistence agriculture. This clarifies that the provision of interest-free credit provides synergies, helping bridge resource constraints that, in turn, improve productivity, production, and market participation.
Once the marketability index was calculated, the market orientation index in land allocation was computed. This states the weighted ratio of the farmer’s land allocation pattern by the crop’s marketability index. Results reinstate no difference in non-participants and six-month credit participants, despite being involved in subsistence agriculture systems. However, it indicates a high extent of market orientation among consecutive second and above two-time credit participants. This reflects that having secured credit for another consecutive term allows farmers’ to better respond to the market signals and allocate more land to marketable commodities. Specifically, under auto-consumption and semi-commercialized agriculture systems, resource allocation (land, labor, and capital) and production decision making play a conclusive role. Thus, the provision of interest-free running capital plays fuels resource transformation and allows farmers to allocate more land to commercial crops. This implies that the provision of interest-free credit for one year or above substantially improves market orientation. Subsequently, commercialization of input for rice was computed. This reports the ratio of the total value of inputs purchased from the market and the total value of rice crop produce. Computations illustrate a significant difference between first period participants and non-participants—where non-participants either highly depend on rural input providers or use little input while operating under subsistence agriculture systems (see
Table 4). Similarly, results justify the notable impact of the second and above two periods’ credit participation on the commercialization of rice crop input. This implies that credit participation raises commercialization interests and allows farmers’ to move towards markets rather than being dependent on rural stakeholders and/or create improved demand for crop inputs as farmers shift from subsistence to commercialized agriculture.
The output commercialization index for rice was computed; this is the ratio of the total rice output value sold in the market and the total rice crop produce value. Results highlight that both non-participants and first period participants tend to show similar lower engagements in output commercialization. This indicates the vast prevalence of auto-consumption or subsistence agriculture systems where either the household consumes most of the rice production or sells a meager portion in the market. Conversely, results show a higher degree of rice output commercialization for farmers who participated for the second or above two periods. This finding complements the 2SLS results and develops a line of argument that credit provision for only a six month period further decreases output market participation. It implies that such an intervention fails to meet its purpose, whereas relaxation in repayment time would offer a substantial improvement in agriculture’s commercialization. Afterward, the extent of the commercialization of the rural economy was estimated. It examines the total value of agricultural products and services—including the value of in-kind payments—attained through market transactions in relation to the total agriculture income. Results disclose a significant difference between non-participants and first period participants—complementing the relevance of interest-free credit in transforming the rural economy. Likewise, the provision of credit for a consecutive second period or above two periods offers a comparatively high extent of rural commercialization.
Finally, the degree of integration into the cash economy was computed. This refers to the ratio of the total value of agricultural products and services attained through cash transactions to the total agriculture income. Computations clarify the notable effect of first-period credit participation on the degree of integration into the cash economy. Put simply, the provision of credit enables farmers to deal in cash payments and, therefore, protects them from lending crop inputs on credit which often turns costly. It implies that putting money into farmers’ pockets might work as a foremost gauge to integrate rural areas into the cash economy. Further, results for second and above two-period credit participation reinforce that, the greater the relaxation in the repayment period, the greater the degree of integration into the cash economy. Lastly, we examined vertical urban-rural integration of input and output. The results indicate that second and above two-period credit participation serves a better function in fostering better urban-rural vertical linkage. From these findings, we see that market intermediaries often act like parasites [
11], forcing farmers into cash-strapped auto-consumption or/and semi-commercialized systems, which weakens urban-rural vertical linkages, bolstering their vulnerabilities to poverty and food insecurity.
4.4. Credit Participation, Income and Productivity
While most of the prior literature identifies a positive impact of credit on income, the IV approach presented in this study develops a valid estimation that comprehensively addresses endogeneity concerns. First, we ran OLS to examine the impact of credit participation, followed by IV estimated and diagnostic statistics. Further, we repeat a similar practice for assessing the impact of credit participation on rice productivity. Accordingly,
Table 6 represents the results of IV and OLS estimates for variable interest (credit participation) with diagnostics statistics for clarity. However, including covariates and independent variables are available in
Appendix A,
Table A5,
Table A6 and
Table A7.
The OLS estimate shows a consistent negative effect of first-time credit participation on farmers’ income. It indicates a 0.131 units decrease in farmers’ income, ceteris paribus. This estimation suffers the endogeneity problem as the coefficients of IV models predict more consistent estimates. The results of selected diagnostic statistics also validate the need for IV estimation. It shows a 0.175 units decrease in farmers’ income when collectively applying the three IVs. This reflects that the provision of a crop loan—only for six months-tends to reduce farmers’ income. The potential causes might be as follows: (1) the amount obtained per acre credit might not be sufficient to cover the cost of production and other running expenses, (2) strict and less repayment time, and (3) the greater influence of social collateral. Consequently, inter alia, cash-strapping hinders escape from auto-consumption and/subsistence systems. Thus, these systems add to farmers’ plight, leaving them to borrow from market intermediaries to meet their credit needs and remaining trapped in a vicious cycle of poverty. These findings are amply supported by the prior literature [
3,
8,
10,
61].
Conversely, results based on consecutive second-period credit participation (interaction second period) show its positive impact on farmers’ income (see
Table 4). It indicates a 0.588 units decrease in farmers’ income. This reinforces that the provision of interest-free credit for another consecutive period improves storage and marketing decision-making, which increases income. Among other advantages, interest-free running capital reduced the cost of production and enhanced economic independence, allowing them to choose between profitable, cost-effective and reliable channels that spur vertical integration between farms and markets. This implies that the provision of interest-free credit for one year serves a better function in integrating farmer-market linkage that might be translated into improved farm income. Similar findings have been reported by prior studies [
64,
65,
66,
67]. Lastly, we examined the impact of interest-free credit participation on rice crop productivity. Diagnostic statistics justify estimation using OLS as no endogeneity was detected. Results indicate a positive impact of credit participation on productivity. Approximately, it shows a 13 mounds per acre increase in crop productivity with credit participation. This implies that credit provision helps duly meet crop financial requirements for key inputs and ensures proper application of improved seeds, mechanization, fertilizers, and, subsequently, increased productivity. These findings are amply supported by prior literature [
65,
68,
69,
70].
Smallholder farmer(s) received different prices for similar rice variety in the studied region.
Table 7 presents the rice prices received by non-participants, first-period participants, and second-period participants. Further, it illustrates the average annual prices for rice in the sampled districts and compares the smallholders’ prices. These variations might be attributed to the participation in interest-free credit. We disaggregated the mean prices for three categories of the sampled smallholders to estimate how credit participation helps obtain higher prices for different crops. The results indicate that the second-period participants received relatively higher prices for rice, obtaining 8.5% higher than non-participants and 7.6% higher than first-period participants. Comparatively, first-period participants received per mound higher price (rupees 27 or USD 0.18) than non-participants and lower than second-period participants (rupees 190 or USD 1.23). Put simply, in terms of profit, second-period participants with an average market participation rate of 14.32 mounds (see
Table 1) obtained 3,104 rupees (USD 20) per acre. Likewise, with the average area under rice production of 4.67 acres in this study (see
Table 1), second-period participants received an additional 14,495 rupees (USD 93) than non-participants. This implies that second-period credit participation substantially improves smallholder farmers’ income and, therefore, improved income enhances their credit repayment capacity and future participation in such programs. Hence, the interest-free nature of agriculture credit encourages smallholder farmers’ to participate in programs aimed at broader agriculture commercialization and improved urban-rural linkages. Contrary, it is also evident from results that there is a meager per acre average difference (rupees 386 or USD 2.5) between prices received by non-participants and first-period participants. In case of short-term credit repayment, the farmer would not be encouraged to participate in agriculture commercialization. Therefore, it suggests that second-period credit participation substantially improved income earned (rupees 3.104 or USD 20 per acre) from market participation and further encourages farmers’ credit participation.
5. Conclusions
Credit is fuel in agriculture production systems. It allows farmers’ to meet the cash need induced by the agriculture production cycle which characterizes land preparation, planting, cultivating, managing and harvesting the crop, which is usually done over a lean/slack period of several months. In developing countries, formal institutions have largely failed to satisfy farmers’ credit needs, which extend local traders’ or intermediaries’ opportunistic role and leave farmers to operate in auto-consumption systems. Thus, this deteriorates urban-rural vertical linkages in terms of the food supply. Further, these agents take advantage of farmers’ weak bargaining power and low social status and grab a significant share of benefits accrued from the sale of crops, leaving farmers to sell their produce to them in the village at low prices. Hence, most smallholders become cash-strapped which further instigates a vicious cycle of poverty characterized, inter alia, by low productivity, on the one hand, and the existence of oligopsony or a monopsony type market structure, on the other hand, yielding low economic returns. Given this, we studied the effect of interest-free agriculture credit on market participation and urban-rural integration for first and second-period credit participants using the IV approach.
The results show a mixed impact of interest-free credit on the market participation of rice growers. In general, the effect is negative on market participation and income when farmers obtained credit for six months, forcing farmers into cash-strapped, auto-consumption and/or semi-commercialized systems. However, it shows a positive impact when farmers’ received credit for the next consecutive crop altogether. The provision of interest-free credit for one year serves a better function as it significantly improved land size under rice production, market participation, income, and productivity. Further, computed indexes complement these empirical results, indicating a positive impact on the extent of commercialization and urban-rural vertical linkages. The study is relatively novel in several aspects: the effect of interest-free credit on market participation and urban-rural vertical linkages is rarely undertaken in the prior literature; the subjects being non-participants, first, and second-period participant smallholders. Rice growers were chosen through a systematic approach, thus making the study findings highly relevant for coherent policymaking. Further, this study comprehensively addresses endogeneity concerns and presents the three valid IVs, land registration, willingness to constitute a farmers’ group, and social collateral, which can be further applied using the criterion developed herein. Likewise, the estimates applying these IVs—individually and collectively—unanimously show the higher effect of credit participation than OLS estimates; thus, the results presented are superior estimates of the impact of credit on market participation. Moreover, the study also contains findings for the farmers: (1) participation in and strengthening of the role of the agriculture cooperative would be an alternative strategy to boost smallholder agriculture transformation from subsistence to commercial agriculture, (2) ensuring first-period credit retirement would enhance second-period credit participation which, in turn, would substantially improve productivity and income and instigate a virtuous cycle of agriculture commercialization, and (3) improved agriculture commercialization fosters market arbitrage and, therefore, enhances information flow within the farming community through already established agriculture cooperatives.
In terms of policy implications, the study suggests the positive effect of one-year interest-free credit on smallholder decisions by alleviating the credit constraints and increasing area under rice cultivation which, in turn, increased the probability of market participation, commercialization, urban-rural vertical integration and farmers’ income. Likewise, the development of agriculture cooperatives, a by-product of interest-free credit, would offer lasting benefits for farmers and rural communities. Further, improved smallholder farmers’ resilience, social status, bargaining power, and income, can shed substantial impact(s) on agriculture production systems, urban-rural food supply chains and the wellbeing of both rural and urban communities. Moreover, these findings complement the notion in the prior literature that the provision of short-term credit (crop loans) forces farmers to become cash-strapped that, in turn, keeps them trapped in a vicious cycle of poverty and subsistence-oriented agriculture systems. Thus, relaxation in repayment time is suggested to encourage the increased transformation into commercial agriculture and ensure ’value for money’ by increasing the overall intervention ripple effect on a smallholders’ wellbeing, broader agribusiness trajectory, and vertical urban-rural integration, and economic growth. Further, policymakers must consider a more targeted approach that incentivizes the purchase of farm machinery for market participants, i.e., smallholders having a good credit retirement record, and contributes to interest-free credit funds. However, this requires policymakers to further identify the effect of different levels of market engagement. Nonetheless, policy actions set for agriculture commercialization should be adequately supported by a dynamic and effective credit service.
The study provides three valid instruments and robust estimation of interest-free credit on market participation and income. However, several caveats need to be considered when applying an IV approach, and future studies are needed to complement the findings of this study. First, the appropriateness and validity of an instrument is key when applying the IV approach. Although we are quite sure of the suitability of the applied instruments and, therefore, diagnostic statistics commend their validity, it is logical to admit that some other instruments could be applied. Second, the sample size used consists of smallholder farmers which, nevertheless, provides sound justification for the developed models herein. However, categorizing farmers’ into extra-small, small, medium and large scales would offer additional support to the estimation and help explore the extent of market participation, varying with the degree of farm size and resource endowments. Third, the study’s findings provide a foundation to build upon the unbiased and robust IV approach, therefore, ensuring the policymakers’ objective that ’value for public money’ is met, requiring further step-wise evaluations. Therefore, future research studies could investigate and compare the productivity, effectiveness, and impact of various credit forms, i.e., institutional, non-institutional, and interest-free on smallholders. Lastly, this research studied the particular context of interest-free agriculture credit in the least developed Punjab, Pakistan districts, where interest-free credit participation is subjected to some pre-conditions. Therefore, research findings are generalizable for developing countries with a similar context.