1. Motivation
The background of the paper [
1] about Riesz estimators is [
2]. In the present paper, we determine the projection operator, which is necessary to fit the Riesz estimator regression. This operator relies on a partition of a sample’s values as they appear in the design matrix. This projection operator implies the goodness-of-fit measures, which are necessary for any model of linear regression. This projection operator is compatible with the relationship between sub-lattices and positive projections. This formulation relies on using the positive basis of the sub-lattice generated by a design matrix
X, while in the usual method of linear regression, the fitting relies on a covariance matrix,
. The calculation of its parameters is carried out almost directly though observing a partition for the set of sample observations. This partition is the one defined by the subset of observations taking different positive values. The estimators are actually the ordinary least squares estimators. This corollary was not determined previously. This linear regression model may include data coming from both categorical and non-categorical variables as well. The support for the last ones may be some interval of real numbers. Another important contribution is that we define goodness-of-fit measures for the proposed Riesz regression model. These measures rely on the dimension of the sub-lattice generated by the columns of the design matrix. We do emphasize that the fitting of Riesz estimator regression may include only data from categorical variables. It also may include both data from categorical variables and data coming from variables whose support is some interval of real numbers. Options as factors in the so-called beta pricing are related to the regression model being proposed since option payoffs lie in the sub-lattice generated by the span of the variables included in the Riesz estimation model. Factor pricing, as it is presented in Chapter 20.7. of [
3] is the same as in the regression model in p. 435 of [
1]. The positive parts of random variables are related to portfolio insurance, and this is a motivation for the use of such a regression model. Riesz estimator regression is not related to specific probability distributions. Hence, it may be used for data analysis in both actuarial and financial issues, where there is not any specific way of fitting a linear regression model, as we mentioned above. The specification of ’factors’ that are not correlated with each other for a large number of samples implies an appropriate use of ’options’, which may be considered payoffs of some stop-loss reinsurance contract. The reader may refer to [
4] for a rigorous introduction to reinsurance. The projection operator
defined in this paper implies the fitting of the Riesz estimator linear regression. The idea of its use arose due to the linearity of the regression model appearing in p. 439 and p. 440 of [
1]. A question that arises naturally is the following. Since the set of the affine Riesz estimators lie in the generated sub-lattice, what is a unified way to specify this sub-lattice? The answer is ’by using the positive basis of this sub-lattice’. The error term geometry is also specified by the complementary projection operator I-
. Both of the operators
and I-
imply the goodness-of-fit measures of the Riesz estimator regression, which have not been determined previously. The last numerical examples are included in the present paper for a better understanding of the fitting procedure. The objective probability values may be estimated by the usual
test. For this reason, some previously obtained samples may be used. This fashion of testing is a ’Bayesian’ one since it relies on the values arising from previous samples. The objective probability approach of uncertainty in economics was introduced by [
5], and it was developed mainly in [
6,
7].
2. Finite-Dimensional Sub-Lattices
We consider the vector space , where m is the number of the observed realizations for the m states of the world. We refer to any as a ‘state’ since we assume that the set is the space in terms of probability theory. is actually the set of all elementary possible events. is ordered by point-wise ordering. As is well-known, if and only if for any . A positive vector of is any such that for any . The set of the positive vectors of is the positive cone of , denoted by . If , this is denoted by , where 0 is the zero vector of . We also consider L to be some subspace of . If , where , if and only if for any , L is called an ordered subspace of . Then, by , we denote the positive cone of L. A basis of L is called a positive basis of L if , where for any and . Additionally, for any , and . L does not always have a positive basis. L is a sub-lattice of if, for any , . Any sub-lattice of has a positive basis. The support of a positive vector is the set
We recall from [
8] the following:
An ordered subspace Z of is a sub-lattice of and has a positive basis such that for any .
If Z is a sub-lattice of , whose positive basis is , then for any , we have .
If
Z is a sub-lattice of
, whose positive basis is
, then for any
and
,
If
Z is a sub-lattice of
, whose positive basis is
, where
, then
If Z is a sub-lattice of , and if the vector , then a positive basis exists, which is a partition of the unit. Namely, for each vector , where .
If Z is a sub-lattice of , whose positive basis is , then for each , the vector has minimal support in Z. Namely, a positive vector such that is a pure subset of does not exist.
Suppose now that
are fixed, linearly independent, positive vectors of
and that
Z is the subspace of
generated by the vectors
. Since the variables of the design matrix
X may take either positive or negative values and
is a vector lattice itself under the usual point-wise partial ordering, for any column
of the design matrix
X,
, where
denote the positive and the negative part for any of the vectors
.
r denotes the number of a maximal set of linearly independent vectors of
. The determination of a positive basis of the sub-lattice
W of
generated by the set
is specified through the method initially proved in Th.3.7 of [
8]. The reader of the paper may find the statement of the above Theorem in [
9] if
. The paper of [
9] is devoted to the equilibrium in incomplete markets, including European (vanilla) options arising from a given incomplete market. A relationship between the content of this paper and the paper [
9] relies on what we call
beta pricing. The study of this connection is a possible extension of the present paper.
If the positive basis of the sub-lattice generated by is such that , the elements of the partition of the unit and the supports of the vectors , coincide. Namely, for the the same finite set of states , if and . Hence, for any .
Below, we show that the partition of the set of states
is not related to the assumption that
, but it is implied by the measurability of random variables in finite probability spaces. The “true” state of the world appears from some
, where
. Events and states do not coincide in economic modeling. Any
is an element of some
partition of
. They constitute the
information obtained by the design matrix
X, or what is called
observations in terms of statistics. This vector of probabilities provides an explanation of
causality. Anything mentioned above about states, events, and objective probability arise from seminal works such as [
5].
3. Fitting Riesz Linear Regression
We pose some assumptions, which are useful for the results of the present paper:
A vector of objective probabilities concerning the states of the world exists. For any state among , we suppose that holds.
Two time periods are considered, denoted by 0 and 1, respectively.
Any vector is a random variable since the probability denotes the probability for the state s to occur at the 1-time period.
The probability of the 0-time period is equal to since the uncertainty refers to the 1-time period.
Under the existence of the vector
p, the standard inner product of two random variables
and
. Any vector of
represents the possible results of any action at the 1-time period. The usual inner product is changed to the
p-inner product, which is defined as follows:
The p-inner product denotes the correlation between c and d under the probability vector p.
Under the existence of the vector
p, the function
is a norm of the random variable
x arising from the
p-inner product.
Let us suppose that the size of a sample is equal to m.
Definition 1. As mentioned above, a finite-dimensional probability space consists of a set of states of the world , a partition of Ω, and a vector of objective probabilities for the set Ω, where for any .
Remark 1. Since Ω is a finite set, and a probability space is defined through some (σ) algebra consisting of subsets of Ω, there exists a partition of disjoint sets that generate it. Hence, the definition of such a probability space relies on the partition . Any is called an event.
Both of the definitions and propositions appearing below in a more clear form are obtained from Chapter 5 of [
10].
Proposition 1. A random variable is -measurable, if its form is .
Proof. Since x has to be -measurable, for any . denotes the open interval of real numbers where . Hence, for any . □
Definition 2. Suppose that . The
Conditional expectation
of x, with respect to an event , is equal to the real numberwhere . Definition 3. The random variableis called the
Conditional expectation of x with respect to . denotes the characteristic function of The following Proposition is important, since it implies that Riesz estimators are ordinary linear regression estimators in the framework assumed in the entirety of this paper about the objective probability vector p.
Proposition 2. If y is some -measurable random variable, then minimizes the square error . The solution is unique.
Proof. Since
y is
-measurable, its form is
. Since
, then
is minimized if it is equal to zero; hence,
. From elementary calculus, this value is the unique one that minimizes
for any
. □
Hence, we obtain the following.
Proposition 3. is an element of the sub-lattice generated by .
Proof. This is obtained directly from the definition of the . □
Definition 4. The
Riesz estimator
of with respect to is any vector of the form , where is the partition of , which is composed of the supports of .
Definition 5. A projection operator Π with respect to the sub-lattice S of is called a
strictly positive projection
if for any , while .
Theorem 1. is a strictly positive projection Π on with respect to the sublattice W, as defined above.
Proof. For any , ; hence, is a positive projection. If , then because , and moreover, since , this implies that for any . □
According to what has been previously mentioned, for any random variable
, we obtain the decomposition
where
with respect to the sub-lattice of
-measurable random variables. We may thus give the following definition.
Definition 6. The
Error term
of with respect to Π is , where I is the identity operator on .
Definition 7. The
Riesz estimator regression
of with respect to is the following decomposition of x: .
Definition 8. The
Goodness-of-fit for the Riesz estimator regression measure
of x with respect to is the following number: Definition 9. The
Adjusted goodness-of-fit for Riesz estimator regression
of x with respect to is the following number: Remark 2. These two goodness-of-fit criteria denote the distance between the random variable x and its Riesz estimator with respect to . We notice that in the case where , the values for both of the above goodness-of-fit measures are equal. If the value of is less than 1, then it looks similar to the of the usual Regression. A question for further study is whether is less than 1 if .