1. Introduction
With the rapid development of globalization and informatization, service alliances have emerged as crucial forms of collaboration for enterprises [
1,
2]. A service alliance refers to a scenario in which multiple independent service providers collaborate to share resources and technologies, aiming to achieve common business objectives. An increasing number of enterprises have realized that relying solely on their own capabilities is insufficient to optimize service resources and maximize profit [
3]. As service scales continue to expand, the models for service transactions have become increasingly complex. Single types of services are no longer adequate to meet the needs of service consumers. Instead, multiple service providers collaborate, each contributing value in a specific aspect of the service, thereby forming high-quality service alliances that fulfill user demands. In this collaborative model, numerous service providers join forces to collectively offer comprehensive service solutions to customers. Such alliances typically integrate resources, technologies, and expertise from all parties, thereby enhancing the quality and efficiency of services to meet a broader range of customer needs. Service alliances have been widely adopted across various industries, including technology, healthcare, and logistics, where they help address challenges such as resource integration, customer satisfaction, and competitive advantage. For example, in the healthcare industry, service alliances allow hospitals, pharmaceutical companies, and technology providers to collaborate on integrated patient care solutions, while in logistics they enable seamless supply chain management and last-mile delivery. An illustration of service alliance scenarios is provided in
Figure 1:
Collaboration among parties is essential to complete service transactions, with profit allocation being a crucial aspect of service alliance cooperation. Fairness and equity in profit allocation not only affect party cooperation and the stability of long-term relationships but also influence the overall profitability and sustainability of the service alliance. Without a clear profit-allocation mechanism, the contributions of some members may be overlooked, leading to a lack of deserved profits and resulting in a lack of enthusiasm from certain members for participating and providing services. Consequently, this can impact the overall efficiency and effectiveness of the service alliance [
4]. If some members bear excessive risks without corresponding returns, doubts regarding the cooperative relationship may arise, which can affect the stability and sustainability of the service alliance [
5]. Traditional profit allocation methods often rely on the proportion of contributions from each party or adhere to fixed allocation rules, neglecting the actual risk-bearing situations of each party. This results in unfair and opaque profit allocation, potentially leading to disputes and conflicts among partners. Therefore, addressing how to achieve fair and equitable profit allocation in service alliance transactions has become an urgent issue [
6].
Although significant progress has been made in the study of service alliances, there remains a considerable research gap regarding fair and effective profit allocation, especially when considering the risks borne by each party. Many existing models focus on contribution proportions but fail to adequately address the complexity of risk distribution. Furthermore, while cooperative game theory has been extensively studied, there is limited research on its practical applications in specific industries. Addressing these gaps could provide actionable insights for industries such as technology, healthcare, and logistics, where service alliances play a critical role in fostering collaboration and improving service outcomes. Another approach is to apply cooperative game theory. In service alliance transactions, the challenge of profit allocation, which involves cooperation among multiple service providers, represents a typical cooperative game [
7]. Cooperative game theory can help determine a fair method for profit allocation, thereby encouraging better participation and promoting the stability and sustainability of the alliance. However, cooperative game theory encompasses multiple solution concepts, and different solutions may lead to different profit allocation outcomes, potentially causing subjectivity and controversy [
8]. Therefore, further research is needed to identify the appropriate solution concept that ensures the fairness and acceptability of the final scheme. These research gaps indicate the need for more refined models that not only consider marginal profit but also take into account the risk-bearing capacities of each party, thereby ensuring fairness and sustainability within service alliances.
A commonly used theoretical approach to modeling fair profit allocation is Nash bargaining theory, introduced by John Nash in 1950 [
9]. Nash bargaining theory provides a framework for allocating resources or profits in a way that maximizes collective benefits while ensuring fairness among participants. In the context of service alliances, Nash bargaining theory focuses on how multiple service providers can negotiate profit sharing based on their profits and the risks they bear, ensuring an equitable distribution of benefits. The Nash bargaining solution is particularly suitable for situations where participants must cooperate to achieve mutual gains but must also balance the distribution of those gains based on the bargaining power of each participant. Several studies have applied Nash bargaining theory to analyzing cooperation and profit allocation in service alliances. For example, Chen et al. [
10] applied Nash bargaining theory to studying profit allocation in multi-party cooperation, emphasizing the balance between risk and contribution proportions. Li et al. [
11] used Nash bargaining theory to address profit distribution in supply chains, considering the risk and contribution proportions of different suppliers, thus optimizing resource allocation. The Shapley value, introduced by Lloyd Shapley in 1953 [
12], is another widely used solution concept in cooperative game theory. The Shapley value provides a fair method for distributing the total profit among participants based on their individual contributions to the overall outcome. It calculates each player’s marginal contribution in every possible coalition and then averages it to determine their fair share of the total profit. The Shapley value has been applied in various fields, including supply chain management, to allocate profits fairly among participants. In the context of service alliances, the Shapley value can be particularly useful for quantifying the contributions of each service provider and ensuring that profits are allocated proportionally to these contributions. For instance, Liu et al. [
13] proposed a Shapley value-based profit allocation model to optimize resource sharing and cooperation in supply chains. Wang et al. [
14] studied risk-bearing among service alliance members and proposed a profit allocation method integrating the Shapley value to address fairness concerns when members face different levels of risk. In the context of service alliance profit allocation, the Nash bargaining theory and the Shapley value can complement each other. Nash bargaining provides a framework for fair negotiation, while the Shapley value allows for precise quantification of each participant’s profit to the alliance’s success.
The main objective of this paper was to propose an improved Nash bargaining profit allocation model that would consider marginal profit and risk, aiming to provide a reasonable allocation scheme for alliance services jointly completed by multiple service providers. Our model seeks to identify an optimal method for profit allocation that maximizes the overall profit of the cooperative alliance while ensuring the profits of individual participants, thereby achieving the goal of win–win cooperation. The main contributions of this paper are summarized as follows:
- (1)
A service alliance transaction model based on Nash bargaining theory is established, which takes into account the interactions among multiple participants in the service alliance, providing an effective transaction framework for alliance members.
- (2)
The concept of marginal risk is introduced, and a calculation method for marginal risk is designed, using the Shapley value approach. By considering risk and a risk adjustment factor, an improved Nash bargaining model is proposed, addressing the shortcomings of conventional methods that fail to incorporate dynamic risk analysis into profit allocation.
- (3)
Through numerical calculations and result analyses, this model combines Nash bargaining theory with the Shapley value, demonstrating its ability to optimize the profits of each service provider while maximizing overall profit, thereby achieving fair profit allocation.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows:
Section 2 outlines related works;
Section 3 describes how our study was performed, including a description of the problem, the definition of the model, and the Nash bargaining model;
Section 4 introduces the concept of marginal risk and the method for designing the improved Nash bargaining model, focusing on enhancing the model with considerations for marginal risk;
Section 5 discusses the numerical calculations and results in detail and provides a high-level summary of our findings; finally,
Section 6 presents our conclusions and explores possible directions for future work.
2. Related Works
Profit allocation in collaborative ventures has become a significant focus of research across various disciplines, with models evolving to address the increasing complexity of economic interactions. From traditional methods that rely solely on fixed contributions to more advanced approaches incorporating game theory and risk factors, scholars have proposed numerous frameworks to ensure equitable and efficient allocation of profits.
2.1. Traditional Models of Profit Allocation
Early studies introduced traditional methods of profit allocation that are primarily based on the contributions or production inputs of each party, often employing fixed proportions to allocate profits. These methods are well-suited for relatively straightforward cooperative relationships, emphasizing profit allocation according to participants’ contributions, such as sales or resource inputs. Within this collaborative framework, researchers have proposed various forms of profit allocation, including the equal allocation model [
15], quantity discounts [
16,
17], repurchase agreements [
18], two-part tariffs [
19], revenue-sharing contracts [
20], and mail-in rebates [
21], all of which have been widely applied.
Govindan et al. [
22] implemented profit-sharing contracts considering decentralized reverse setting, defining customer preferences as a function of discounts offered by the seller, and distributing profit proportionally based on participants’ contributions or sales volume. Noori-Daryan et al. [
23] introduced quantity and freight discounts, providing discounts or preferential prices based on participants’ contributions or purchase quantities, optimizing the overall profit of sales prices and order volumes under composite incentive contracts, studying the impact of optimal decision-making strategies. Taleizadeh et al. [
24] proposed two-part tariff contracts, dividing profit into two parts, one allocated based on participants’ contributions and the other evenly distributed among all participants.
However, these allocation forms often rely on simplistic rules or fixed proportions, overlooking the actual risk-bearing situations of parties during the collaboration process. Such an approach can lead to unfair and opaque allocations, especially in more complex cooperative settings where participants assume different levels of risk. For example, parties who assume higher risk exposure, such as those investing in new technology or bearing operational risks, may receive the same share of profit as those with lower risk exposure, leading to dissatisfaction and undermining the willingness to cooperate. This lack of consideration for risk factors can destabilize cooperative relationships, especially in contexts like service alliances where risk is often a significant component. Incorporating fairness theory and game theory principles, such as Nash bargaining or the Shapley value, is essential for ensuring a more equitable and flexible profit allocation that better reflects the risks and profits of all parties involved.
2.2. Profit Allocation Based on Cooperative Game Theory
As economic cooperation become more complex, cooperative game theory [
25,
26] has emerged as a vital theoretical foundation for addressing profit allocation challenges. This theory primarily focuses on allocating profits generated from the collaboration of multiple participants, employing analytical approaches to develop mathematical models for quantitative research. Classic profit allocation methods, such as the Shapley value model [
12] and the Nash bargaining model [
9], provide solutions for fair and stable profit allocation.
The Shapley value offers a clear allocation equation that divides total profits among all collaborators forming an alliance, satisfying properties such as set monotonicity and coalition monotonicity. The Nash bargaining model focuses on how two participants share surplus value in cooperation. These methods have been widely applied in various fields, including transportation energy [
27,
28,
29,
30], supply chain management [
31,
32,
33], and agricultural-product-sharing transactions [
34]. Eissa et al. [
35] developed a conceptual framework using the Shapley value as an alternative to the traditional investment-based approach, proposing an axiomatically fair methodology for profit-sharing negotiations. This profit-allocation scheme was based on the marginal profits of each participant. Jiang et al. [
7] proposed a profit allocation mechanism based on the Shapley value method, to maintain stable cooperative relationships. Various factors, including contribution, synergistic effect, and cost coefficient, were considered. However, the risks borne by enterprises were not assessed, and the incorporation of multiple factors increased the complexity. Wang et al. [
27] proposed an improved Shapley value model that addresses existing deficiencies by identifying key factors such as risk, input, and service quality. This model combines these factors with the modified Shapley value, to determine the allocation for each participant. Wang et al. [
36] established a multi-weight interval Shapley value method for the benefit allocation model. This model reflects the impact of key parameter variables, including resource input ratios, allocation operation scales, risk taking, and other factors. However, the added complexity may hinder practical implementation, suggesting the need for a more straightforward approach that still considers risk. Meng et al. [
37] constructed a four-level supply chain model and proposed three new Shapley values to address participants’ varying risk attitudes. However, the Shapley value lacks flexibility and cannot capture dynamic changes. Li et al. [
38] developed a two-layer revenue allocation model for road data assets, using a modified Shapley value approach. It adjusts allocations for data risk factors and determines correction factors for a consolidated allocation. However, this model may still struggle with scalability and might not fully account for the complexities of interdependencies in larger networks, reinforcing the need for a robust bargaining method that incorporates risk considerations.
In contrast, the proposed Nash bargaining model in this study addresses these issues by incorporating both marginal profit and risk, providing a more flexible and equitable approach to profit allocation. This model resolves the existing gap by considering risk-sharing mechanisms alongside traditional profit-based models, offering a solution that better suits the complexities of service alliances.
2.3. Profit Allocation Models Considering Risk
In recent years, researchers have increasingly recognized the importance of risk factors in profit allocation. In real-world collaborations, parties contribute differently and face varying levels of risk. Recent studies have focused on optimizing both profit and risk allocation among collaborators in various contexts of uncertainty. Radwa et al. [
39] explored a model that allocates both profits and risks among collaborators under uncertain conditions by introducing a risk-sharing mechanism, which optimizes overall profit allocation and enhances cooperation sustainability. Ding et al. [
40] presented a quantitative approach that models alliance members’ inequity aversion, to analyze risk-sharing arrangements in an alliance project. The derivation involves solving a constrained optimization problem using concepts and methods from Stackelberg game theory. Gao et al. [
41] adopted a profit distribution method that combines improved Shapley values and independent risk contribution theory to allocate the total revenue, taking into account the risk levels and comprehensive marginal benefits of various entities. Feng et al. [
42] presented several factors that affect profit allocation, including input level, effort level, innovation level, risk factor, and value-added factor. They constructed a profit allocation method for service-oriented manufacturing alliances, based on the modified Shapley value method, with risk being one of the key considerations. Yang et al. [
43] employed a risk objective function, which aims to minimize risk while controlling operational costs, and they proposed a Shapley value cost-allocation mechanism.
Collectively, these studies highlight that the allocation of profit and risk is crucial for ensuring the success of collaborations within alliance services. The model proposed by Radwa et al. [
39] emphasizes the contribution of optimizing the distribution of profits and risks under uncertain conditions to the sustainability of cooperation. Ding et al. [
40] and Gao et al. [
41] revealed the importance of risk-sharing arrangements for equitable profit distribution by analyzing the risk aversion of alliance members, and they offered a new perspective by integrating risk levels with the marginal benefits of various parties, providing a framework for revenue allocation. The research by Feng et al. [
42] and Yang et al. [
43] validated the importance of minimizing risk within the cost-allocation mechanism through their risk objective function model.
However, while these studies introduced risk considerations into profit allocation, they largely focused on static models that do not account for the varying risk of participants over time. In some cases, the proposed models still use simplified allocation methods that fail to capture the complexity of risk interactions in more dynamic collaborations.
In summary, while the literature on profit allocation has examined the topic from various perspectives, most existing models primarily emphasize tangible contributions, such as sales or effort, often neglecting the risk exposure faced by each participant. In the context of service resource transactions, overlooking the uncertainties encountered by service providers can adversely impact the successful completion of service alliances and affect the earnings of other members, ultimately resulting in imbalanced profit allocation. Therefore, this study proposes a profit allocation model that accounts for the risks undertaken by each party, offering a fairer and more efficient solution for service alliances. The proposed Nash bargaining model is specifically designed to address these gaps by incorporating both profit and risk factors, ensuring that profits are allocated more equitably and flexibly in environments characterized by uncertainty and dynamic risks.
3. Problem Description and Definition
In service alliances, profit allocation involves cooperation among multiple service providers and requires careful consideration of the key components involved in the problem and the model development process. In what follows, we describe the problem, define the service alliance transaction model, and examine the interactions between multiple participants, ultimately establishing a Nash bargaining-based model.
3.1. Problem Description
Service alliances are formed by groups of service providers that collectively address personalized user needs by integrating different services to achieve more complex functionalities. Within these alliances, transactions and collaborations among multiple participants are essential. Consumers seeking services can include individuals, businesses, institutions, and other users, while providers may be single entities or a consortium of institutions or enterprises that collaborate as service-provider alliances. These dynamic service alliances emerge in response to the needs of service consumers, facilitating the extensive combination of services tailored to customer requirements. Through the contributions and collaboration of participants, the personalized service demands of consumers are met within the service alliance, as illustrated in
Figure 2.
After service consumers receive the services, they pay the corresponding fees, which the service alliance distributes as profit shares to the participating providers. The service alliance serves as the primary entity responsible for creating and delivering services, with each provider establishing relationships within the alliance. However, the formation of such alliances carries inherent risks, including the potential for incomplete service transactions following establishment. Therefore, it is essential for multiple entities within the alliance to reach a consensus on both profit and risk sharing.
3.2. Model Definition
In a cooperative game involving
n service providers, each provider seeks to maximize their own interests by forming alliances with others and offering alliance services composed of multiple services. Let S represent the formed alliance, denoted as
, where each service
represents the service provided by the
provider. Then, the members not included in the alliance are represented as
. Profit allocation is carried out after obtaining the profit based on the cooperative game, which can be represented by a binary tuple, as shown in Equation (
1):
where
N represents the set of participants and
v represents the profit function of all possible cooperative alliances in the participant set. The notations of the parameters used in this paper are given in
Table 1, and the notations of the variables used in this paper are given in
Table 2.
The risk function is a key element in ensuring that risk considerations are appropriately integrated into the profit allocation process. It quantifies the overall risk faced by the alliance, taking into account the varying levels of exposure each member faces based on their contribution to the alliance and their individual risk profiles.
Let
represent the risk exposure for provider i in the alliance. This function is typically modeled as a function of the profits generated by the alliance and the specific risks undertaken by each provider. The definition of
is as shown in Equation (
2):
where
is the proportion factor that quantifies how much risk member
i bears relative to the entire alliance’s risk, and where
is the total risk of the alliance, which is a function of the individual risks of all the members in the alliance.
The total risk function
is computed by aggregating the individual risks
across all the alliance members, possibly using a weighted sum depending on the level of risk exposure each provider faces. The model for
is as shown in Equation (
3):
where
is the individual risk function, reflecting the risk exposure of member
i, and where
n is the total number of members in the alliance.
The cooperative game is super-additive, which is defined as Definition 1:
Definition 1 (Super-Additivity)
. For a cooperative game , for any alliances A and B formed by service providers , , if A and B have no intersection, i.e., then the profit of the new alliance formed by A and B, , is greater than or equal to the sum of the profit of A and B, as shown in Equation (4): 3.3. Nash Bargaining Model
In profit allocation for service alliance transactions, multiple service providers collaborate to form an alliance and deliver services to consumers. The Nash bargaining model is employed, to seek a fair allocation of profit based on both marginal profit and risk within the alliance.
The Nash bargaining model offers a solution to allocating profit among participants based on a utility function that incorporates influencing factors, such as risk, marginal profit, and the bargaining positions of each party. The Nash bargaining solution must satisfy four key axioms: symmetry, linearity preservation, Pareto efficiency, and the independence of irrelevant alternatives. These axioms ensure that the solution is fair, stable, and consistent across different bargaining scenarios. In service alliances, ensuring fairness and stability in profit allocation is crucial for maintaining long-term cooperation among participants. The Nash bargaining model addresses these issues by providing a mathematically rigorous framework that guarantees each participant’s utility is maximized within the bounds of fairness and stability.
We assume that the reward function maps from to the real number space, which is a strictly increasing concave function. Let be the bargaining breakdown point, and the lower bound is . If the four axioms are satisfied then the balanced reward point (equilibrium point) has only one unique and valid solution. These four axioms are discussed below.
3.3.1. Symmetry
If service A and service B provided by two service providers are exactly the same then their bargaining breakdown points are the same, as well as the return function, i.e., (
,
); then, the final return is also the same, as shown in Equation (
5):
Both parties have equal bargaining power. Symmetry ensures that if two participants are identical in their roles and contributions then they will receive equal shares of the profit. This ensures fairness, as no participant will feel disadvantaged or unfairly treated, thus promoting cooperation and minimizing the risk of alliance breakdown.
3.3.2. Linearity Preservation
If the service provider’s reward function U or the bargaining rupture point is scaled and shifted to perform a linear transformation then the resulting is also scaled and shifted in the same way; that is, the linear transformation invariance axiom is satisfied. Linearity preservation means that any scaling or shifting of reward functions or bargaining points will be consistently reflected in the resulting profit allocation. This property ensures that the solution remains consistent and scalable, regardless of any external changes to the underlying model, thus providing stability in the face of fluctuations in the external environment.
3.3.3. Pareto Efficiency
There is no other point of return that is better than . Neither party can be made better-off without making the other party worse-off. Pareto efficiency guarantees that the allocation cannot be improved for one participant without making another worse-off. This is crucial for maintaining cooperation among service providers, as no party can increase their utility without reducing the others, which ensures a stable and non-exploitative distribution of profits.
3.3.4. Independence of Irrelevant Alternatives
We assume that service providers A and B reach a consensus on , resulting in in the value range U. Then, if in a new bargaining problem the effective reward point set is a strict subset of the value range U, and is still in this subset, then the equilibrium point of this new problem is still . The independence of irrelevant alternatives ensures that the equilibrium outcome remains unchanged even if irrelevant alternatives are introduced into the bargaining process. This guarantees the robustness of the Nash bargaining solution, ensuring that minor changes or the introduction of unrelated alternatives will not disturb the final equilibrium, which further strengthens the stability of the profit allocation.
Together, these axioms ensure that the Nash bargaining model yields a solution that is not only mathematically rigorous but also practical and equitable for the participants in the service alliance. Compared to other profit allocation models, the Nash bargaining model is preferable because it incorporates well-established game-theoretic principles to ensure fairness and stability, addressing both the marginal profit and the risk faced by participants. In service alliances, this model is particularly effective in maintaining long-term cooperation by ensuring that all parties are motivated to contribute without fear of exploitation or unfair treatment.
3.3.5. Objective Function
Based on the preceding analysis, the issue of profit allocation in service alliance transactions satisfies the four axioms of symmetry, linearity preservation, Pareto efficiency, and independence of irrelevant alternatives. Therefore, the Nash bargaining model is applicable for profit allocation. In the cooperative game
, we assume the profit allocation factors of service providers
N in the alliance
S are
, where these factors represent the proportion of the alliance’s total profit allocated to each service provider
N. The objective function of the Nash bargaining for the profit allocation of service provider
i after joining the alliance
S is represented in Equation (
6):
in which,
n is the number of service providers participating in the bargaining,
Y is a set of feasible solutions,
is the allocation profit of service provider
i participating in the alliance
S, and
represents the threat points (i.e., the reservation payoffs of each participant).
In order to motivate mutual coordination and cooperation among service providers, the solution of Nash bargaining can exclude the scenario of bargaining breakdown and only consider outcomes that are superior to the reservation point. This exclusion is crucial, because it focuses the negotiation on achievable, mutually beneficial outcomes, thus promoting cooperation rather than conflict. In a multi-participant Nash bargaining model, logarithmic transformation can be used to simplify the calculation process and ensure the solvability of the maximization problem of the product, transforming the product maximization problem into a sum maximization problem, as shown in Equation (
7):
Therefore, the objective function of Nash bargaining can be equivalently transformed into Equation (
8):
Maximizing the utility product of each service provider corresponds to maximizing the utility of the alliance. Service providers engage in cooperative games, to ensure fair allocation of profits. By focusing on maximizing the utility of the collective group rather than individual gain, the Nash bargaining model aligns the interests of all participants, thus ensuring a stable and fair profit distribution. The Nash bargaining model, which is based on influencing factors and the bargaining equilibrium point, appropriately addresses the allocation of total profit among multiple service providers.
4. Proposed Improved Nash Bargaining Model
The valuation of each participant’s contributions in a service alliance is crucial for achieving fair profit allocation, and the following two aspects should be taken into consideration: (1) the resources invested, the expertise provided, and the amount of work performed by each participant in the service delivery process; (2) the risks faced by each party in the service alliance, including project risks, financial risks, and market risks. To address these issues, we first conducted an impact factor analysis. Subsequently, an improved Nash bargaining model considering risk was designed, to achieve fair profit allocation.
4.1. Impact Factor Analysis
The allocation of profit in a service alliance transaction involves multiple service providers, with influencing factors determined by the necessary costs and value generated by the alliance services. According to the principle of fairness, the greater the value created, the larger the share of profit that should be allocated. There are two main factors that affect profit allocation.
4.1.1. Profit
Marginal profit generated by service providers after joining the alliance, which is defined as in Definition 2:
Definition 2 (Marginal profit). For a cooperative game , considering the order in which service providers join the alliance, when a new service provider joins the alliance the overall profit of the alliance increases. The additional profit is called the marginal profit.
Assuming service provider
i joins service alliance
S, its marginal profit can be given by Equation (
9):
Here, S represents the coalition of service providers before i joins, is the new coalition including i, is the profit generated by coalition S and is the profit of the coalition after adding i.
The Shapley value method can determine the weight factor
for the marginal profit of cooperative profit, as it calculates the allocation of the cooperative profit that satisfies the core allocation. The Shapley value was chosen for its well-established properties of fairness and stability in cooperative game theory. It ensures that each participant’s share reflects their marginal profit across all potential coalition formations, thus making it suitable for scenarios where both value and shared responsibilities, such as risk, are considered. In a cooperative game,
, the equation for calculating the profit allocation of the Shapley value for service provider
i after joining alliance
S is presented in Equation (
10):
where
represents the number of service providers included in coalition
S, and where
represents how many kinds of cooperation sequences there are after service provider
I joins coalition
S, where
. Then,
represents how many kinds of cooperation sequences the remaining coalition members have;
represents the marginal profit of the coalition S after joining the service provider
i. Service provider
i’s participation in different sequence combinations in alliance
S is divided by the sequence possibilities of all
n members; that is, the profit that service provider
I should share for alliance
S.
Based on the calculation by Equation (
10) of the Shapley value allocation, the calculation equation for the weight factor
of the cooperative profit after service provider
i joins the alliance
S can be expressed as Equation (
11):
where
represents the weight factor for the marginal profit of the cooperative profit.
4.1.2. Risk
The risk incurred by service providers after joining the alliance can be understood as the Operation and Maintenance (O&M) cost that service providers need to incur during the process of delivering services. This cost is typically a fixed value and can be quantified after a certain O&M period. When providing services individually, the independent risk only needs to consider the O&M cost incurred by the service providers. However, upon joining the alliance, the independent risk incurred by service providers in delivering services includes not only the O&M cost but also the shared risk of the alliance. During the service process, failure to complete the service or consumer dissatisfaction leading to non-payment can impose significant costs on service providers, impacting their profitability and reputation.
To allocate risk fairly, the Shapley value is employed, as it considers the marginal impact of each participant on the total risk, distributed across all possible coalition formations. This method ensures that each provider’s risk allocation reflects the additional burden they contribute when joining or leaving the alliance, thereby promoting an equitable balance. By treating risk as a quantifiable cost shared among participants, the Shapley value provides a mechanism for determining each member’s fair share of the total incurred risk. This ensures that risk allocation, similar to profit allocation, reflects the marginal change each participant brings to the alliance.
With reference to marginal profit, we introduced the concept of marginal risk, as defined in Definition 3, which represents the additional risk or loss incurred by adding or removing a service member in the alliance.
Definition 3 (Marginal risk). For a cooperative game , taking into account the sequence in which service providers join the alliance, the additional risk incurred when a new service provider joins the alliance and the overall risk as the alliance increases is considered as the marginal risk.
Assuming service provider
i joins service alliance
S, its marginal risk can be given by Equation (
12):
Here, S represents the coalition of service providers before i joins, is the new coalition including i, is the risk generated by coalition S, and is the risk of the coalition after adding i.
Utilizing the Shapley value model, the marginal risk of each service provider can be calculated. In the cooperative game
, the risk allocation equation for service provider
i after joining the alliance
S can be expressed as Equation (
13):
where
represents the risk value,
denotes the number of service providers in
S,
presents the number of cooperation sequences after service provider
i joins
S,
;
presents the number of cooperation sequences the remaining coalition members have;
represents the increased marginal risk after the service provider
i joins
S. Service provider
i participates in different sequence combinations in
S, divided by the sequence possibilities of all
n members, that is, the risk value of service provider
I for
S.
The proportion factor of risk
is the proportion factor of cooperative profit after service provider
I joins alliance
S, which can be calculated by the proportion of marginal risk in the alliance. Assuming that the marginal risk of each service provider
I joining the alliance is expressed as
, the equation for calculating the proportion factor
is as shown in Equation (
14):
where
represents the proportion factor of risk.
The interaction between profit and risk is critical in ensuring a balanced profit allocation. The improved Nash bargaining model considers both factors by integrating risk-adjusted profit measures. Specifically, the profit allocated to each service provider not only depends on the marginal profit they bring but also on the marginal risk they bear. This ensures that service providers are compensated in proportion to their profits and the associated risk, thereby fostering a sustainable and fair alliance.
4.2. Improved Nash Bargaining Model Considering Risk
Based on the above analysis, we propose an improved Nash bargaining model that considers risk. The architecture of the model is illustrated in
Figure 3, which outlines the key components and their interactions. The model considers both marginal profit and risk-adjusted factors, allowing for a more balanced and equitable distribution of profits among service providers in a cooperative alliance.
To better address the interaction between the profit and risk of each service provider in the alliance, the Nash bargaining objective function presented in Equation (
8) is enhanced to derive a profit allocation model that incorporates these dual aspects. This refined model, which takes into account both marginal profit and marginal risk, is expressed as Equation (
15):
where
denotes the profit allocated to service provider
i upon joining the alliance
S,
represents the profit of service provider
i’s independent decision making,
signifies the risk allocated to service provider
i after joining the alliance
S,
represents the risk of service provider
i’s independent decision making, and
represents the risk adjustment factor, used to represent the impact of risk on profit.
6. Conclusions
This paper introduces an optimized profit allocation game model based on Nash bargaining theory, which accounts for both marginal profit and risk. The unique contribution of this study lies in integrating marginal risk into the traditional Nash bargaining framework, offering a more comprehensive approach to profit allocation in service alliances. Unlike many previous models that primarily focus on contribution proportions, our model ensures a fairer distribution by considering the risk-bearing capacities of each service provider. This enhancement improves both fairness and cooperative efficiency among alliance members. A contribution of this work is the introduction of the Shapley value method for calculating marginal risk, addressing a common issue in the literature where risk is often neglected or oversimplified. The addition of the risk adjustment factor further strengthens the model’s ability to account for the varying risk-bearing capacities in profit allocation. Our computational analysis shows that this improved Nash bargaining model effectively balances profit and risk, maximizing overall profitability while ensuring equitable profit distribution. This represents a significant advancement in the field, offering a more balanced and fair solution for service alliance cooperation.
However, this study has certain limitations. The current model relies on assumptions regarding the interactions between service providers and does not fully account for dynamic changes in real-time transactions or fluctuating service conditions. Additionally, obtaining accurate risk data in practical settings may present challenges, potentially affecting the precision of the model. The model, as currently designed, is tailored to specific types of service alliances and may require modifications to be applicable to other business environments or industries.
Future work will focus on extending the model to scenarios involving multiple providers, various service alliances, and real-time business environments. This will involve adapting the model to different business models, market conditions, and service complexities. We also plan to explore applications beyond those covered in this study, such as logistics, healthcare, and technology services, where unique risk profiles and profit-sharing dynamics exist. These expansions will enhance the applicability and effectiveness of our approach, addressing challenges related to fairness, incentive mechanisms, trust, and transparency across a wider array of service alliance contexts.