The NBA’s Maximum Player Salary and the Distribution of Player Rents
Abstract
:They arrived at this specific point after salaries ballooned over the past 15 years—not for superstars, but for complementary players who don’t sell tickets, can’t carry a franchise, and, in a worst-case scenario, operate as a sunk cost…It’s about Andre Iguodala, Emeka Okafor, Elton Brand, Andrei Kirilenko, Tyson Chandler, Larry Hughes, Michael Redd, Corey Maggette and Luol Deng making eight figures a year but being unable to sell tickets, create local buzz or lead a team to anything better than 35 wins.—Bill Simmons (2010) [1]
1. Introduction
2. The 1999 Collective Bargaining Agreement 2
3. Empirical Framework
Variables | Mean | Std. Dev. | Minimum | Maximum |
---|---|---|---|---|
Dependent | ||||
RSAL | 4,758,353 | 4,001,079 | 37,938,672 | 37,938,672 |
Independent | ||||
WS/48 | 0.099 | 0.059 | −0.186 | 0.316 |
PPG | 11.11 | 6.02 | 0.80 | 32.10 |
MIN | 1855 | 879 | 6 | 3485 |
EXPERIENCE | 6805 | 3.660 | 0 | 19 |
HEIGHT | 79.301 | 3.787 | 63 | 90 |
1st | 0.114 | 0.319 | 0 | 1 |
2nd | 0.114 | 0.319 | 0 | 1 |
3rd | 0.114 | 0.319 | 0 | 1 |
4th | 0.114 | 0.319 | 0 | 1 |
ROOKIECONTRACT | 0.205 | 0.404 | 0 | 1 |
DV2003 | 0.504 | 0.500 | 0 | 1 |
CTR | 0.223 | 0.417 | 0 | 1 |
PF | 0.217 | 0.413 | 0 | 1 |
SG | 0.185 | 0.389 | 0 | 1 |
PG | 0.181 | 0.386 | 0 | 1 |
4. Estimation Results
Variable | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) |
---|---|---|---|---|
WS/48 | 11,448,470 * (3.53) | 11,570,400 * (3.48) | ||
PPG | 205,665 * (4.01) | 214,282 * (4.20) | ||
MIN | 137.10 (1.10) | −513.83 * (−2.22) | 111.92 (0.85) | −522.89 * (−2.31) |
EXPERIENCE | 448,316 * (4.05) | 485,442 * (4.06) | 452,496 * (4.09) | 482,232 * (4.01) |
EXPERIENCESQ | −19,835 * (−2.93) | −19,960 * (−2.65) | −19,818 * (−2.92) | −19,771 * (−2.61) |
HEIGHT | 45,934 * (1.69) | 73,983 * (2.88) | 99,898 * (2.17) | 74,870 * (1.66) |
1st | 6,801,080 * (5.95) | 5,954,402 * (5.68) | 6,795,856 * (5.95) | 5,849,532 * (5.54) |
2nd | 2,663,831 * (8.35) | 2,202,278 * (5.71) | 2,671,115 * (8.43) | 2,169,702 * (5.51) |
3rd | 1,802,492 * (6.98) | 1,662,274 * (6.12) | 1,806,055 * (7.21) | 1,674,239 * (5.96) |
4th | 783,174 * (3.37) | 931,056 * (3.75) | 766,748 * (3.26) | 926,015 * (3.65) |
ROOKIECONTRACT | 572,744 * (1.68) | 247,285 (0.74) | 613,638 * (1.81) | 243,901 (0.73) |
DV2003 | 1,128,398 * (5.73) | 1,363,341 * (7.14) | 1,127,071 * (5.59) | 1,341,995 * (6.92) |
1st * DV2003 | 1,903,845 (1.34) | 1,627,122 (1.15) | 1,914,272 (1.32) | 1,716,194 (1.19) |
2nd * DV2003 | 2,772,432 * (4.40) | 2,492,349 * (3.78) | 2,771,133 * (4.38) | 2,559,076 * (3.88) |
3rd * DV2003 | 1,053,477 * (1.95) | 909,989 * (1.69) | 1,026,794 * (1.90) | 843,480 (1.56) |
4th * DV2003 | 761,291 * (1.77) | 405,425 (0.95) | 790,390 * (1.85) | 416,236 (0.98) |
ROOKIECONTRACT * DV2003 | −638,726 * (−2.11) | −676,659 * (−2.25) | −690,485 * (−2.26) | −649,338 * (−2.13) |
CTR | −299,661 (−0.94) | 294,576 (0.92) | ||
PF | −236,912 (−0.81) | 52,520 (0.19) | ||
SG | −3131 (−0.01) | −146,332 (−0.38) | ||
PG | 398,326 (1.11) | 325,586 (0.89) | ||
Constant | −4,502,654 * (−2.05) | −6,755,296 * (−3.18) | −8,731,644 * (−2.33) | −6,985,388 * (−1.91) |
R2 | 0.672 | 0.681 | 0.673 | 0.683 |
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
References
- B. Simmons. “A Fan-Friendly Solution to Fix the NBA.” ESPN.com, 24 February 2010. Available online: http://sports.espn.go.com/espn/page2/story?page=simmons/100224 (accessed on 18 March 2015).
- J.R. Hill, and P.A. Groothuis. “The new NBA collective bargaining agreement, the median voter model, and a Robin Hood rent redistribution.” J. Sports Econ. 2 (2001): 131–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- H. Beck. “For N.B.A. owners, 1999 labor deal was win with regrets.” New York Times, 3 July 2011, SP6. [Google Scholar]
- R.A. Kaplan. “The NBA luxury tax model: A misguided regulatory regime.” Columbia Law Rev. 104 (2004): 1615–1650. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J.K. Hakes, and R.D. Sauer. “An economic evaluation of the moneyball hypothesis.” J. Econ. Perspect. 20 (2006): 173–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J.C. Bradbury. “Does the baseball labor market properly value pitchers? ” J. Sports Econ. 8 (2007): 616–632. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J.A. Jenkins. “A reexamination of salary discrimination in professional basketball.” Soc. Sci. Q. 77 (1996): 594–608. [Google Scholar]
- “Rod Fort’s Sports Data Website.” Available online: https://sites.google.com/site/rodswebpages/codes (accessed on 18 March 2015).
- “Basketball-Reference.com.” Available online: http://www.basketball-reference.com/ (accessed on 18 March 2015).
- D.J. Berri, S.L. Brook, and M.B. Schmidt. “Does one simply need to score to score? ” Int. J. Sport Finance 2 (2007): 190–205. [Google Scholar]
- D.J. Berri, S.L. Brook, B. Frick, A.J. Fenn, and R. Vicente-Mayoral. “The short supply of tall people: Competitive imbalance and the National Basketball Association.” J. Econ. Issues 39 (2005): 1029–1041. [Google Scholar]
- J. Ducking, P.A. Groothuis, and J.R. Hill. “Minimum pay scale and career length in the NBA.” Ind. Relat. J. Econ. Soc. 53 (2014): 617–635. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- T.D. Kendall. “Celebrity misbehavior in the NBA.” J. Sports Econ. 9 (2008): 231–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- E.P. Lazear, and S. Rosen. “Rank-order tournaments as optimum labor contracts.” J. Polit. Econ. 89 (1981): 841–864. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- L.M. Kahn. “Cartel behavior and amateurism in college sports.” J. Econ. Perspect. 21 (2007): 209–226. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- A. Farmer, and P. Pecorino. “Is the coach paid too much? Coaching salaries and the NCAA cartel.” J. Econ. Manag. Strategy 19 (2010): 841–862. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- J. Nocera, and U. Skybox. New York Times, 28 October 2007, 38.
- D.J. Berri, M.A. Leeds, E.M. Leeds, and M. Mondello. “The role of managers in team performance.” Int. J. Sport Finance 4 (2009): 75–93. [Google Scholar]
- 1That the NBA’s 1999 collective bargaining agreement was expected to redistribute rents away from superstars toward other players was explained by Hill and Groothuis [2]. They argue that, consistent with previous research in labor economics, the redistribution of rents can be explained by a median voter model of union membership.
- 3Teams’ ability to offer their free agent players unlimited pay regardless of salary cap implications was sometimes referred to as the Larry Bird Exception. However, the 1999 Collective Bargaining Agreement still contained provisions, sometimes referred to as “Bird Rules,” permitting teams to pay their free agents more than the players could earn by moving to other teams but no longer allowing unlimited player pay. Because of the potential for confusion between the so-called Bird Exception and Bird Rules, this paper does not use those terms.
- 4Other notable provisions included minimum player salaries that escalated with player experience, a luxury tax imposed on teams exceeding the team salary cap, and a salary recovery provision allowing team owners to “clawback” some player pay if aggregate salaries exceed certain basketball-related income thresholds.
- 5Drafted player pay is determined by their “slot” or position taken in the draft.
- 6In examining contemporaneous salaries, our approach follows that of papers such as [5,6] in ignoring whether players had multi-year contracts and the year in which those contracts were signed. Jenkins [7] points out that using contemporaneous salary and contemporaneous productivity is potentially problematic because actual productivity may not match the anticipated productivity at the time a multi-year contract was signed. In any event, we know of no comprehensive source for data on the length or signing dates of NBA player contracts.
- 7Fort indicates that the salary data were originally published by USA Today.
- 8That mandating pay increase with experience could incentivize teams to substitute less experienced players for more experienced players is supported by Ducking et al. [12].
- 9Kendall [13] takes this approach to examining player misbehavior and finds that a player’s pay rank on his team has a strong relationship with the number of technical fouls received.
- 10A possible reason for systematic pay differences is the finding by Berri et al. [11] that the scarcity of talented tall players (centers or perhaps power forwards) is a source of competitive imbalance in the NBA.
© 2015 by the authors; licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Hastings, K.M.; Stephenson, F. The NBA’s Maximum Player Salary and the Distribution of Player Rents. Int. J. Financial Stud. 2015, 3, 75-83. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs3020075
Hastings KM, Stephenson F. The NBA’s Maximum Player Salary and the Distribution of Player Rents. International Journal of Financial Studies. 2015; 3(2):75-83. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs3020075
Chicago/Turabian StyleHastings, Kelly M., and Frank Stephenson. 2015. "The NBA’s Maximum Player Salary and the Distribution of Player Rents" International Journal of Financial Studies 3, no. 2: 75-83. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs3020075
APA StyleHastings, K. M., & Stephenson, F. (2015). The NBA’s Maximum Player Salary and the Distribution of Player Rents. International Journal of Financial Studies, 3(2), 75-83. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs3020075