1. Introduction
Farmland expropriation is an important task to promote urban renewal and development, and reducing the risk of conflicts in farmland expropriation is a necessary prerequisite to ensure smooth implementation of farmland expropriation. In the 1990s, China’s urbanization construction ushered in a period of rapid development. Under the powerful stimulus of land dividends, a large amount of farmland has since been converted into urban construction land. According to China’s “Summary of the National Land Use Master Plan,” by 2030, urban expansion will occupy more than 54.5 million mu of previously cultivated land, and the number of farmers losing land will reach 78 million. However, during this large-scale loss of farmland and urban construction, there have been many social conflicts, disputes, and even mass incidents. Among the many reasons for farmers’ petitions in China, land issues account for more than 65%, of which 73.2% are related to land expropriation [
1]. There are approximately four million disputes caused by land expropriation in China every year [
2]. In rural areas, conflicts in land expropriation, illegal construction, law enforcement, and farmland transfer are the most typical. Among them, land expropriation conflicts are the type with the largest proportion and the highest severity, with characteristics of high frequency, high intensity of resistance, and wide range of influence. Meanwhile, the development trend shows a gradual increase from the eastern coastal areas to the underdeveloped areas in the central and western regions. In fact, from China’s first land expropriation regulation in 1953, Measures on Land Expropriation for National Construction, to the implementation of the new Land Management Law in 2020, the state made many adjustments and changes to the scope of land expropriation, expropriation procedures, compensation standards, resettlement methods, etc., and was committed to reducing the risk of conflicts in farmland expropriation. Especially in recent years, as the state’s emphasis and penalties continue to increase, the issue of conflicts in farmland expropriation has gradually eased, but local conflicts still exist. Moreover, occasional vicious conflicts may not only lead to a crisis of trust among farmers as well as between farmers and the collective, and shake the legitimacy of grassroots organizations in rural society, but also cause a large number of property losses and even serious consequences of casualties. Therefore, the land issue centered on farmland expropriation has become the main issue of current rural conflicts in China.
Derived from sociology, the term “conflict” means that two or more social units are incompatible or mutually exclusive in their respective goals, which leads to psychological or behavioral contradictions [
3]. Some scholars define conflict as “a one-time, repeated or multiyear disagreement between actors due to a conflict of interest with limited resources” [
4]. As conflicts and disputes due to land expropriation have intensified, they have begun to draw the attention of researchers. Bishnu described land conflicts as the farmers’ struggles to change unequal social land relations [
5]. Reuveny et al. proposed the concept of land use conflicts, which is a contradictory state in the process of land resource utilization [
6]. Accordingly, this paper treats land expropriation conflict as an interactive process wherein various stakeholders exhibit confrontational psychology or behavior to fight for land benefits. In China, individual interest, collective interest, and public interest are the three common drivers causing land expropriation and demolition. Among them, farmland expropriation conflicts caused by individual interest are the most common [
7]. Based on their intensity, conflicts can be divided into autonomous demolition, joint demolition, illegal demolition, and violent demolition. The reason may be due to the local government’s management system, problems such as excessive reliance on the unscientific development model of land finance, excessive pursuit of the GDP (gross domestic product) assessment mechanism, and the “pan-administrative” tendency of grassroots organizations. It may also be caused by the lack of some key legal provisions in the upper-level law of farmland expropriation or vague interpretation, such as the difference in the understanding of compensation for expropriated land and for expropriated house, or the lack of corresponding regulations on the specific operating procedures and methods [
8]. It may also be caused by differences in compensation standards in various regions or inconsistencies in compensation standards for collective land acquisition and state-owned land acquisition [
9]. It is precisely because of the complexity and diversity of conflict causes that the resolution of conflicts in farmland expropriation has become the focus and difficulty of the reform of the farmland expropriation system.
Throughout the evolution of China’s social transformation and the alternation of old and new systems, the legal cognition contradiction between the principle of property protection and economic development has increased the risk of conflicts in farmland expropriation [
10]. For farmers, the imperfection of the social security system often makes them worry that demolition will lead to poverty and disrupt their original way of life, so they are hesitant to have their land expropriated. Confronting a reality in which both poverty and sudden wealth are simultaneously caused by demolition, farmers fearing huge economic losses express concern about the local governments’ abuse of the “public interest” in implementing farmland expropriation [
11]. In addition, due to the imperfect market supervision system, a housing evaluation agency is usually designated by the local government, and the evaluation price lacks fairness and neutrality, which often makes farmers question the evaluation results [
12]. The above phenomena, on the one hand, reflect the difference of behavior logic between farmers and the local government. On the other hand, they indicate that the farmland expropriation conflict is not only an economic problem, but also a complex social problem that includes behavioral preferences, strategic interactions, and belief interactions. In this process, the strategic interaction and belief interaction between different game subjects change with the adjustment of national policies and evolve into a new game equilibrium result, which leads to the multidimensional conflict characteristics of the farmland expropriation conflict. It is generally believed that the land expropriation system not only empowers local governments to requisition land but also provides farmers with legal protection of their rights and interests [
13]. However, in practice, due to the limitations of China’s current farmland expropriation system, the effect of policy implementation often deviates from the original intention of policy design. For example, different types of houses should correspond to different compensation standards, but the vastly different self-built houses in rural areas often lead to problems, such as fuzzy compensation standards and discretion. However, many legal provisions are only principles and frameworks, and they lack effective judgments on the behavior evolution of farmland expropriation conflicts and game results. These make it difficult for the local government and farmers to reach the goal of interest reconciliation and, on the contrary, aggravate the occurrence of conflicts and cause the two sides to fall into the “Boxed Pig” game in which the reconciliation–conflict cycle continues [
14].
In the process of farmland expropriation, farmers pay unprecedented attention to fairness. They not only pay attention to whether they are fully compensated, but they also compare their compensation with that of others. However, the inequality of resources and status determines the unfairness of the competition between farmers and the local government. In this case, it can be considered that the conflict of farmland expropriation is a fierce confrontation between public and private rights around different interests [
15]. The result of multiple interest appeals is bound to be a multiple interest game. When farmers receive more compensation, it means that local governments need to spend more. The interests relationship between the two is a zero-sum game. In addition to litigation settlement, nonlitigation settlement, affected by the behavioral logic of “a big problem needs a big solution, a small one needs a small solution,” has also become the main way for farmers to deal with disputes. From the perspective of conflict evolution, the farmland expropriation conflict is a dynamic evolution process from conflict accumulation to conflict intensification and then to conflict resolution. Among these, interest is the main inducing factor, and the strategic choice and interaction mode of both sides are the key variables to determine conflict intensity and evolution. Because of this, we must prevent a single type of conflict, but also prevent transformation of different conflicts to avoid causing more serious problems. That is why, in addition to litigation settlement, nonlitigation settlement has also become one of the main ways for farmers to deal with disputes over farmland expropriation. Accordingly, this article explores the formation mechanism of multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation, clarifies the evolutionary rules of conflicts in farmland expropriation, and proposes solutions to conflicts in farmland expropriation according to different types of conflicts, which have important practical and research value.
2. Literature Review
Since its reform and opening up, the evolution of the farmland expropriation system in China has mainly gone through three stages [
16]. The first stage was centered on economic construction, which mainly started from the State Council’s promulgation of the Regulations on Land Expropriation for National Construction in 1982. For the first time, the government proposed that land expropriation is compulsory and clarified the scope of compensation. By implementing the Land Management Law in 1987, land was allowed to enter the market as a production factor. Then, the Law of the People’s Republic of China on Rural Land Contracting passed in 2002, clarifying the scope of rural land. In short, farmland expropriation mainly follows the overall development of the concept of “centering on economic construction,” and the principle of compensation follows the original purpose of the expropriated land. The second stage mainly focused on the balance of interests of social subjects, which began with a Constitution amendment in 2004. For the first time, regulations on expropriation and compensation were made, but the regulations were rather vague and did not cover the subjects of how to compensate or what to compensate. When the 2007 Property Law was proposed as a manifestation of respect for and protection of the citizens’ property rights, the design of the land expropriation system began to emphasize fairness. The third stage focuses on social harmony, which started with the implementation of the Administrative Enforcement Law of the People’s Republic of China in 2012. It introduced a framework design of the administrative enforcement mode mainly applying to the people’s court for enforcement and supplemented by administrative enforcement, which helps to promote procedural justice and protect civil rights. By 2014, the “Several Opinions on Comprehensively Deepening Rural Reform and Accelerating the Advancement of Agricultural Modernization” proposed to speed up establishment of a system of value-added income distribution for rural collective operating construction land. In 2020, the new Land Management Law put forward the basic principle of expropriation compensation to ensure that the original living standards of the expropriated persons are not lowered and long-term livelihood is guaranteed. The evolution of the farmland expropriation conflict is closely related to the development of the farmland expropriation system, thus showing the transformation of power between the local government and farmers.
The current research on the multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation mainly includes two aspects: behavior research on multidimensional conflicts and game research on multidimensional conflicts. The behavior research on multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation can be divided into rights protection conflicts, profit-making conflicts, and institutional conflicts. Rights protection conflicts refer to violations of farmers’ rights due to illegal land expropriation by the local government, leading to farmers’ resistance and demand of rights protection [
17]. Since China implemented the Tax-Sharing Reform in 1994, the local governments’ dependence on land finance has further increased [
18]. Therefore, to obtain more fiscal revenue from the land, a local government may implement illegal land expropriation [
19], mainly by reducing compensation standards and forcing land expropriation [
20]. In the face of improper behavior of local governments, farmers’ dissatisfaction has been aroused, and the risk of conflicts in farmland expropriation has increased [
21]. However, the decision-making process of farmland expropriation, lacking the effective participation of farmers, often puts farmers at a disadvantage in the negotiation of interest distribution, leading to conflicts between farmers to obtain and protect land rights, exercise land rights, or exclude other people’s intervention in the land [
22,
23]. A survey showed that the current areas with more serious rights protection conflicts in farmland expropriation in China are mainly located in the southwest and southern provinces, especially in Guangdong and Yunnan [
24]. Among them, the high incidence of land conflicts in Yunnan is related to the acceleration of the industrialization process, the disregard for legal procedures for land expropriation by local officials, and the defects of the land compensation system [
25]. Guangdong is the forerunner of China’s reform and opening up, and its strong awareness of rights makes it easier for farmers to adopt various methods to protect their legal rights [
26].
Profit-making conflicts refer to the fact that there is a large amount of ambiguous interest space in the process of land expropriation, and the subjects of interest competition engage in fierce interest games to maximize their interests, including petitions and mass incidents [
27]. With the rapid development of urbanization, the economic externalities brought about by urban renewal projects have increased the level of housing prices [
28]. In the face of the huge added value generated by urban renewal projects, it inevitably intensifies the competition for the distribution of benefits among stakeholders [
29]. Studies have shown that when farmers consider the public interest, they tend to give in, but when adopting the personal interest, they tend to confront. When a local government expropriates land for personal gain, conflicts occur. In this process, the blind pursuit of personal interests leads to the occurrence of profit-making conflicts in land expropriation [
30]. Local governments often expect to obtain more financial resources through farmland expropriation and reduce the economic cost of urbanization. However, due to the huge gap between the amount of compensation given to farmers and the land transfer income received by local governments, farmers feel that their interests are damaged and choose to take risks to protect their rights [
31]. Some scholars attribute the local governments’ mercenary and radical decision-making on land-related issues to the lack of political ethics in the contemporary demolition policy [
32]. On the other hand, to maximize their interests, farmers may resist land expropriation, which may lead to conflicts between the local government and farmers [
33]. Based on loss aversion, endowment effect, and psychological accounting, farmers are often reluctant to accept development projects which may further aggravate the risk of farmland expropriation conflicts [
34]. Some scholars have found that most farmers currently welcome the expropriation of farmland, but the crux of the problem is that farmers want more compensation, and the farmers’ choice of a collective petition and fierce confrontation can improve their bargaining position and help to obtain high compensation. This approach will encourage more farmers to take similar actions. As a result, compensation standards will continue to increase, but demolition conflicts will continue to increase as well [
35]. If farmers get more compensation, local governments will incur more costs. However, local governments hope to obtain more economic benefits while gaining political achievements through land expropriation. Therefore, the interest between the two is a “zero-sum game” [
36].
Institutional conflicts refer to the conflicts caused by the unreasonable land expropriation system, which is manifested in three aspects: (1) the compensation standard for land expropriation is too low; (2) land expropriation lacks negotiation; (3) the scope of land expropriation is too wide. At present, China mainly adopts an administrative-led agricultural land expropriation system, and local governments have the “first mover advantage” and the “second mover advantage” in the negotiations, resulting in the passive and shallow participation of farmers, and they are in a disadvantageous position in the negotiations [
37,
38]. In the game process, local governments play a dual role in farmland expropriation. They are not only the competitors in interests, but also the rule-makers, which means that the game between a local government and farmers is unfair [
39]. When disputes over farmland expropriation occur, due to the direct interest relationship between the local government and farmers, the settlement mechanism of land expropriation disputes loses its function and causes land expropriation disputes to escalate into land expropriation conflicts due to bias [
40]. Some scholars believe that due to loopholes in the current administrative land expropriation system, which leaves room for illegal land expropriation, local governments can avoid penalties [
41]. When farmers cannot find effective measures to protect their interests, they are more willing to choose group behaviors such as petitioning to protect their rights and even resort to violent behaviors to fight. Farmers’ dissatisfaction with the land expropriation policy to a certain extent indicates that there are defects in the farmland expropriation system. The use of administrative farmland expropriation compensation methods often ignores farmers’ differential compensation needs. In the farmland expropriation compensation game without withdrawal rights, insufficient land compensation and uncertainty in future employment opportunities have led to conflicts in farmland expropriation [
42,
43,
44].
In the game research on the multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation, it is generally believed that the essence of farmland expropriation is the continuous game process of interest redistribution, in which each participant maximizes the distribution of land transfer benefits based on the current land expropriation system [
45]. In this process, there are complex relationships between the local government, developers, village collective organizations, and farmers, and the imbalance of interest distribution is the main source of conflicts in land expropriation [
46]. The root of the huge social contradictions in China caused by land expropriation lies in the imbalance of interest distribution, and the root of the imbalance of interest distribution lies in the imperfect interest distribution system and mechanism [
47]. Liu and Chen pointed out that property rights in the public domain are scarce resources. When all relevant stakeholders want to obtain these resources, conflicts of interest arise. They believe that the restriction of national laws on farmland rights, excessive intervention of local governments and grassroots organizations, and the lack of farmers’ capabilities are the causes of conflicts in farmland rights [
48]. Shi established a static game model with complete information and concluded that the main motivation for local government’s illegal land acquisition and farmers’ choice to resist behavior is the competition for land interests [
49]. Fan and Bai analyzed the game of interests between the local government and farmers in the process of farmland conversion and explained the reasons for the damage to farmers’ rights and the internal mechanism of legal rights protection [
50].
In summary, based on the behavioral game, the issue of conflicts in farmland expropriation in China may be the behavior of farmers’ rights protection triggered by unilateral rent-seeking by the local government, the boycott behaviors of farmers to obtain higher compensation, or the fierce competition between the two sides of the game based on the maximization of their respective interests. Therefore, this paper divides the farmland expropriation conflicts into three types: “government rent-seeking”, “nail household dilemma,” and “extreme controversy.” Since most of the existing studies are based on a single conflict perspective, focusing on the static game analysis between the local government and farmers, there is a lack of research on the correlation and dynamic evolution of conflicts. However, income expectations of the farmers losing land and local governments in different external environments are different, and the corresponding game strategies are constantly adjusted. Which equilibrium state is reached depends mainly on the initial conditions and the path of evolution [
51]. In the field of economic research, Bolding’s “Evolutionary Economics” and Nelson and Winter’s “Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change” are the signs of the birth of modern evolutionary economics, and “Evolutionarily Stable Strategy” published by Maynard Smith laid the theoretical foundation for evolutionary games. Different from the “complete rationality” assumption of traditional games, evolutionary games are based on bounded rationality and focus on the dynamic equilibrium of long-term games [
52]. Given this, based on the evolutionary game method of Friedman [
53], this paper establishes a multidimensional conflicts game analysis framework for farmland expropriation combined with conflict behavior and system development.
3. Game Analysis Framework
The essence of farmland expropriation is a process of interest redistribution [
54], so farmland expropriation conflicts often originate from the interest competition game between the local government and farmers. According to China’s Land Management Law, Land Management Law Implementation Regulations, and other relevant laws and regulations, farmland expropriation is usually carried out under the following procedures. Firstly, the local government announces planned land expropriation, clarifying the scope of land expropriation, compensation methods, compensation standards, resettlement channels, etc. Secondly, the local government launches an on-site investigation. Thirdly, the local government draws up a compensation and resettlement plan for land expropriation. If farmers have objections to the plan, they can raise them to the local government within the prescribed time limit, and the local government should hold a hearing. Fourthly, the local government organizes and implements farmland expropriation. Fifthly, the farmers go through the relevant procedures within the prescribed time limit and complete land delivery. When there is a dispute over the compensation standard, the farmers can file an administrative lawsuit or apply for administrative reconsideration. If the farmers refuse to relocate within the prescribed time limit and do not apply for administrative litigation or administrative reconsideration, the local government can apply to the court for enforcement. Given this, this paper draws on the van Damme’s game theory, considers the dynamic game of the local government and farmers’ successive decision-making and a static game of simultaneous decision-making in the process of farmland expropriation, and constructs a game analysis framework of multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation.
3.1. Van Damme’s Game Theory
As shown in
Figure 1, game player 2 makes decisions first, and has two strategies: R and D. If R is selected, both sides get 2X units of benefits, and then the game ends. If D is selected, the game enters the second stage, and the two sides make decisions simultaneously, and both sides have two strategies: S and W. When both sides choose S or W at the same time, the benefits of both sides are 0. When player 1 chooses W and player 2 chooses S, player 1 obtains X units of benefits and player 2 obtains 3X units of benefits. When player 1 chooses S and player 2 chooses W, player 1 obtains 3X units of benefits and player 2 obtains X units of benefits. The above game contains two types of interest conflicts: (1) when the two sides have complementary strategies, that is, one side shows strength and the other side shows weakness, distribution result (3X, X) or (X, 3X) may appear; (2) when the two sides have a competitive strategy, that is, when both sides show strength or weakness, distribution result (0, 0) may appear.
3.2. Multistage Van Damme’s Model
According to the van Damme’s game theory and the general process of farmland expropriation, this paper takes the local government and farmers as the game subjects based on the dynamic and static games between the two sides and constructs a multistage van Damme’s game matrix with multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation as shown in
Figure 2.
3.2.1. Model Assumptions
Assumption 1: both the local government and farmers are bounded rational economic agents aiming at maximizing economic benefits.
Assumption 2: The local government has the first mover advantage in the game process, and it first proposes a distribution plan.
Assumption 3: When the two sides of the game cannot reach an agreement on the distribution plan, the farmers have the advantage of a latecomer when facing disputes, and they can choose litigation settlement or non-litigation settlement.
Assumption 4: With the changes in the national farmland expropriation policy, the local government and farmers constantly adjust their strategic choices based on their cognitive judgments.
3.2.2. Model Construction
As shown in
Figure 2, the local government first proposes distribution scheme 1. If the farmers accept this scheme, the local government’s income is
, and the farmers’ income is
, satisfying
, and then the game ends. If the farmers refuse, the local government starts negotiations, and the farmers propose the second distribution scheme. If the local government accepts the results, the local government’s income is
, and the farmers’ income is
, where
are the time loss coefficient of the local government and the farmers, respectively, representing the negotiation cost and time cost caused by bargaining and satisfying
. If the local government refuses, farmers have two strategic choices: litigation and nonlitigation. Among them, the probability of farmers choosing litigation is
, and the probability of choosing nonlitigation is
. When farmers choose litigation settlement, the income distribution of both sides will be based on the distribution result of the court, that is, the local government’s income is
, and the farmers’ income is
, satisfying
, where
and
represent the litigation cost of the local government and the farmers, respectively, and satisfy
. If farmers choose nonlitigation settlement, it will be decided by the local government and farmers simultaneously. At this time, the local government has two strategic choices of “compromise” and “compulsion,” and the farmers have two strategic choices of “acceptance” and “confrontation.” For the local government, the probability of choosing compromise is
and the probability of choosing compulsion is
. For farmers, the probability of choosing acceptance is
and the probability of choosing confrontation is
.
According to the strategic choices of both sides in the game, there are four possible strategy combinations: when the local government chooses compromise and farmers choose acceptance, the local government’s income is and the farmers’ income is , satisfying , where and represent the positive externality benefits obtained by the local government and farmers, respectively. When the local government chooses compromise and farmers choose confrontation, the local government’s income is and the farmers’ income is , satisfying and , where represents the excess income obtained by the farmers and represents the struggle cost of the farmers. When the local government chooses compulsion and farmers choose acceptance, the local government’s income is and the farmers’ income is , satisfying and , where represents the excess income obtained by the local government and represents the struggle cost of the local government. When the local government chooses compulsion and farmers choose confrontation, the local government’s income is and the farmers’ income is , satisfying , where and represent the negative external losses borne by the local government and farmers, respectively.
3.3. Van Damme’s Evolutionary Game Analysis
According to the above model assumptions, when the two sides of the game cannot reach an agreement on the distribution plan, farmers have two path options for litigation settlement or nonlitigation settlement, and the starting point is to ensure the maximization of economic benefits. In the game, the strategic choice of both sides evolves with the change to each other’s relative income, and gradually forms a relatively stable game equilibrium result. Therefore, this article first analyzes the evolution of the game subject’s behavior under litigation settlement and nonlitigation settlement.
3.3.1. Evolutionary Game Analysis Under Litigation Settlement
Under litigation settlement, the game satisfies the following constraints:
and
, that is, no matter what strategy the local government chooses, the benefits of farmers when choosing confrontation are less than when choosing litigation. Therefore, when the two sides cannot reach an agreement on the distribution scheme, the farmers abandon the “confrontation” strategy and only retain the two strategic choices of “acceptance” and “litigation.” Accordingly, the game model is transformed, as shown in
Table 1.
For the local government, the expected benefits when choosing “compromise” and “compulsion” are
and
, respectively, and the average benefit is
, calculated as follows:
When
, the expected benefits of the local government when choosing the “compromise” strategy are greater than the average benefits. As time goes by, for the local government, the probability
of choosing the “compromise” strategy increases. When
, the expected benefits of the local government when choosing the “compulsion” strategy are greater than the average benefits, and the probability of choosing the “compromise” strategy decreases over time. Therefore, the replication dynamics equation for the local government can be achieved as follows:
For farmers, the expected benefits of choosing “acceptance” and “litigation” are
and
, respectively, and the average benefit is
, calculated as follows:
Similarly, the replication dynamic equation expressed as
for the farmers’ choice of “litigation” strategy is:
3.3.2. Evolutionary Game Analysis Under Nonlitigation Settlement
Under nonlitigation settlement, the game satisfies the following constraints:
and
, that is, no matter what strategy the local government chooses, the benefits of farmers when choosing the “acceptance” or “confrontation” strategy are greater than when choosing the “litigation” strategy. Therefore, when the two sides cannot reach an agreement on the distribution scheme, the farmers abandon the “litigation” strategy and only retain the two strategic choices of “acceptance” and “confrontation”. Accordingly, the game model is transformed, as shown in
Table 2.
For the local government, the expected benefits when choosing “compromise” and “compulsion” are
and
, respectively, and the average benefit is
, calculated as follows:
The replication dynamic equation
for the local government’s choice of the “compromise” strategy is as follows:
For farmers, the expected benefits when choosing “acceptance” and “confrontation” are
and
, respectively, and the average benefit is
, calculated as follows:
The replication dynamic equation
for the farmers’ choice of the “acceptance” strategy is as follows:
3.4. Equilibrium Point and Stability Analysis
According to the Friedman’s method [
53], this article first analyzed the stability of the local equilibrium point through the Jacobian matrix, and then analyzed the stability of the local equilibrium point of the dynamic replication system to find the evolutionary stability strategy (ESS) under litigation settlement and nonlitigation settlement, respectively.
The replication dynamic system under litigation settlement is composed of Equations (4) and (8). To obtain the abovementioned equilibrium points, we first set equations ; five possible local equilibrium points of the replication dynamic system can be obtained, which are , , , , and . Among them, , .
The partial derivatives of
and
with respect to
and
are calculated using the following formulae:
The Jacobian matrix
and trace
of the system are calculated using the following formulae:
Four Jacobian matrices can be obtained by substituting the above local equilibrium points with
; they are as follows:
The abovementioned equilibrium point is the result of continuous adjustment and improvement on the random combination of the local government and farmers’ strategy selection. Only if
and
, the equilibrium point is an evolutionary stable strategy (ESS). In this way, the determinants and traces of the above equilibrium points are obtained, as shown in
Table 3.
Under litigation settlement, when and , the ESS of the system is , in which the evolutionary stable equilibrium strategy of both parties in the game is (compulsion, acceptance). When , the ESS of the system is (1, 0), in which the evolutionary stable equilibrium strategy of both sides in the game is (compromise, acceptance).
The game replication dynamic system under nonlitigation settlement is composed of Equations (12) and (16). We first set equations ; the five possible local equilibrium points of the replication dynamic system can be obtained, which are , , , , and . Among them, , .
The partial derivatives of
and
with respect to
and
are calculated using the following formulae:
The Jacobian matrix
and trace
of the system are calculated using the following formulae:
Four Jacobian matrices can be obtained by substituting the above local equilibrium points with
, they are as follows:
Similarly, the determinants and traces of the above equilibrium points are obtained, as shown in
Table 4.
Under nonlitigation settlement, when and , the ESS of the system is (0, 0), in which the evolutionary stable equilibrium strategy of both sides in the game is (compulsion, confrontation). When and , the ESS of the system is (0, 1), in which the evolutionary stable equilibrium strategy of both sides in the game is (compulsion, acceptance). When and , the ESS of the system is (1, 0), in which the evolutionary stable equilibrium strategy of both sides in the game is (compromise, confrontation). When and , the ESS of the system is (1, 1), in which the evolutionary stable equilibrium strategy of both sides in the game is (compromise, acceptance).
5. Discussion and Conclusions
5.1. Discussion
Compared with the existing research, the research results of this article have both similarities and differences with the abovementioned literature. The similarities are shown in, first of all, the fact that the numerical simulation results of the multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation in this article are consistent with the changes in the farmland expropriation system since China’s reform and opening up. From 1982 to the present times, China’s farmland expropriation system has experienced an evolution from “centering on economic construction” to “centering on the main interests” and then to “centering on social harmony.” In different periods, there were obvious differences in the strength of the local government and farmers. According to the results of numerical simulations, the evolution of farmland expropriation conflicts proceeded through four stages: “strong government, weak farmers,” “weak government, weak farmers,” “weak government, strong farmers,” and “strong government, strong farmers.” This is consistent with the conflict characteristics of land expropriation in different periods. Secondly, the “government rent-seeking” conflict, the “nail household dilemma” conflict, and the “extreme controversy” conflict proposed in this article are in line with the reality of conflicts in China’s farmland expropriation. According to relevant studies, the current conflicts in farmland expropriation in China are mainly motivated by rights protection and gaining benefits. The three types of conflict correspond to three possible situations: the “government rent-seeking” conflict corresponds to situations where local governments illegally expropriate land and farmers defend their rights through resistance; the “nail household dilemma” conflict corresponds to the situation where farmers seek profits; the “extreme controversy” conflict corresponds to the situation where local governments and farmers seek profits simultaneously. Finally, according to most of the existing literature, farmland expropriation is a game of interest between different related entities, and the imbalance of interest distribution caused by the imperfection of the system is the main cause of conflict. The research in this article confirms it and further analyzes the correlation between system perfection and conflict evolution.
The difference is that most of the existing studies are based on a single perspective, focusing on analyzing a certain type of conflict problem, and there are relatively more studies on conflicts of farmers’ rights protection caused by illegal land expropriation by local governments. However, the reasons for conflicts in farmland expropriation are complex and diverse, which may be caused by local governments, farmers, or both sides of the game. Moreover, in different situations, conflicts may develop dynamically and lead to new conflicts. Therefore, we believe that different types of farmland expropriation conflicts cannot be separated from each other, and the research method should include not only the static analysis method, but also fully reflect the dynamic evolution process between different conflicts in the same field of view. Different from the existing studies, the contributions of this article are as follows: (1) the research object of this article is multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation, and different types of conflicts are based on the same model framework; (2) this article adopting the evolutionary game method uses the MATLAB software to simulate and analyze the dynamic evolution process of different types of conflicts in farmland expropriation during the evolution process of China’s farmland expropriation policy; (3) this article explores the two main ways for farmers to deal with disputes: litigation settlement and nonlitigation settlement, and respectively proposes countermeasures for conflict resolution under different paths.
However, this article also has several limitations. First of all, the feasibility of a solution largely depends on the corresponding policy support. When the environment changes, policies also need to be adjusted accordingly, otherwise policies may fail and solutions may not be as expected. Secondly, the inconsistency of national development goals in different periods may cause system conflicts. For example, the incoordination between the economic system and the social system will adversely affect the implementation effect of the plan. Finally, people’s subjective belief differences such as emotions, preferences, and other irrational factors results in a solution that can only minimize but not completely avoid the occurrence of problems. Therefore, in the future, this paper will further expand the research framework and introduce the multidimensional preference set in behavioral economics, which means the future research, from the perspective of psychology, combined with loss aversion, interactive fairness, reference dependence, and other behavioral preferences of the game subject [
55,
56], will be able to analyze the psychological utility value of the game subject in farmland expropriation. Meanwhile, we can improve the solution measures by strengthening the foresight and flexibility of policies and the coordination of different institutional goals, as well as by taking into account the differences in individual behaviors.
5.2. Conclusions
Multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation originate from the game of multidimensional interests between the local government and farmers. The strategic choices and equilibrium results of the two sides have evolved due to changes in the situation and policy adjustments. To present the complexity and diversity of farmland expropriation conflicts in the same dimension, this article constructed a multistage van Damme’s model of multidimensional conflicts in farmland expropriation and analyzed different types of farmland expropriation conflicts under litigation settlement and nonlitigation settlement. According to the strategic choice and evolution stable equilibrium of the local government and farmers under different conditions, this article discussed the formation mechanism and evolution law of three types of farmland expropriation conflicts, which are the “government rent-seeking” conflict, the “nail household dilemma” conflict, and the “extreme controversy” conflict, and used MATLAB numerical simulation to simulate and analyze behavior evolution and conflict resolution of the two sides at different stages to propose a balanced solution for different types of farmland expropriation conflicts. The conclusions are as follows:
When litigation conditions for farmland expropriation are significantly improved, it becomes relatively easy for farmers to protect their rights through the law, farmers are more inclined to resolve disputes through litigation. When litigation conditions for farmland expropriation deteriorate, farmers’ legal rights protection is costly and difficult, farmers are more inclined to resolve disputes through nonlitigation. According to the analysis of evolutionary equilibrium, under litigation settlement, there are only two possible evolutionary results in the game of farmland expropriation conflicts, which are (compulsion, acceptance) and (compromise, acceptance), and litigation cost is the key factor to determine the outcome of the game. However, under nonlitigation settlement, there is greater uncertainty in the game between the local government and farmers. With the evolution of the farmland expropriation system, the game underwent changes. There are four possible evolutionary results: (compulsion, acceptance), (compromise, acceptance), (compromise, confrontation), and (compulsion, confrontation).
Under litigation settlement, there is only the “government rent-seeking” conflict. The reduction of the litigation threshold provides convenience for farmers to participate in litigation, but if the litigation costs of farmers are high, farmers still choose to accept when they face disputes or suffer a loss of interests rather than seek legal protection. The occurrence of the above result not only weakens the social credibility of laws, but also makes it difficult to protect the legitimate rights and interests of farmers through legal channels. Through numerical simulation, when farmers’ litigation costs are reduced, farmers’ strategic choices gradually shift from acceptance to litigation resolution. As farmers’ strategic choices changed, the local government’s compulsion strategy wavered. Further, when the cost of litigation for farmers is reduced and the rent-seeking ceiling of the local government is controlled, the strategic choices of the local government tend to compromise, farmers’ strategic choices tend to accept, and the “government rent-seeking” conflict is resolved. In addition, increasing the rent-seeking costs of the local government or the positive social externality benefits under reasonable expropriation has the same effect. Therefore, reducing the litigation costs of farmers is conducive to have farmers seek legal ways to resolve the farmland expropriation conflicts and has a restrictive effect on the rent-seeking behavior of local governments, but this method cannot eliminate the rent-seeking behavior of local governments. Only by reducing the litigation costs of farmers and cooperating with other policy interventions, such as controlling the rent-seeking ceiling of the local government, increasing the rent-seeking costs of the local government or positive social externality benefits under reasonable expropriation can the “government rent-seeking” conflict be resolved. In reality, to resolve the “government rent-seeking” conflict under litigation settlement while creating convenient conditions for farmers to participate in litigation, we should also directly or indirectly reduce the litigation costs of farmers’ legal rights protection so as to ensure the maximum effect of legal rights protection. In addition, we should strengthen the supervision of the local government’s behavior norms and make necessary restrictions on its rent-seeking behavior.
Under nonlitigation settlement, there are three types of conflicts. At the stage of “strong government, weak farmers,” the system design of farmland expropriation biased to the local government creates conditions for the local government rent-seeking, so the “government rent-seeking” conflict may occur. To resolve the “government rent-seeking” conflict, we can control the rent-seeking ceiling of the local government, such as by increasing the penalties for the local government’s violations and forcing them to reduce rent-seeking. We can also increase the rent-seeking costs of the local government or its positive social externality benefits under reasonable expropriation. At the stage of “weak government, strong farmers,” when the local government’s behavior is restricted by the system, farmers’ rent-seeking costs are greatly reduced, making them more inclined to choose confrontation and become nail households, so the “nail household dilemma” conflict may occur. To resolve the “nail household dilemma” conflict, we can increase the rent-seeking costs of farmers or their positive social externality benefits under reasonable compensation. Moreover, local governments should pay attention to farmers’ interests, resolve farmers’ concerns timely, and avoid the “nail household dilemma” problems caused by their improper behavior. At the stage of “strong government, strong farmers,“ facing the continuous decline in land income and the continuous increase in the expropriation price, the inconsistency between local governments and farmers has brought farmland expropriation into a deadlock, so the “extreme controversy” conflicts may occur. To resolve the “extreme controversy” conflict, we can control the rent-seeking ceiling of farmers. Alternatively, while controlling the rent-seeking ceiling of local governments, we can increase the farmers’ positive social externality benefits under reasonable compensation or both sides’ negative social externality losses under rent-seeking. Corresponding to the actual situation, we can actively play the role of public opinion and media intervention to correctly guide the settlement of “extreme controversy” issues. Meanwhile, we should improve the mechanism of interest expression and interest coordination, strengthen the communication and consultation between the two sides, and constantly narrow the differences to continuously reduce the rent-seeking behavior of the two sides.