Next Article in Journal
Forecasting Mortality Rates with a Two-Step LASSO Based Vector Autoregressive Model
Previous Article in Journal
A Combined Neural Network Approach for the Prediction of Admission Rates Related to Respiratory Diseases
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Construction of an SDE Model from Intraday Copper Futures Prices

by
Loretta Mastroeni
*,† and
Pierluigi Vellucci
Department of Economics, University of Roma Tre, 00145 Roma, Italy
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
These authors contributed equally to this work.
Risks 2022, 10(11), 218; https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110218
Submission received: 22 August 2022 / Revised: 4 November 2022 / Accepted: 14 November 2022 / Published: 17 November 2022

Abstract

:
This paper introduces a model for intraday copper futures prices based on a stochastic differential equation (SDE). In particular, we derive an SDE that fits the model to the data and that is based on the whitening filter approach, a method characterizing linear time-variant systems. This method is applied to construct a model able to simulate the trajectories of copper futures prices, statistically described by means of an empirical autocorrelation approach. We show that the predictability of copper futures prices is rather weak. In fact, the developed model produces trajectories close to the actual data only in the short term. Consequently, the investment risk for copper futures is high. We also show that the performance of the model improves significantly if the time series satisfy particular conditions, e.g., those with a determinism measure.

1. Introduction

Financial time series modeling is an essential aspect of forecasting and risk evaluation in financial markets. In this paper, we consider the case of copper, which, according to the NYMEX, is the third most used metal, which makes it important to assess the nature of its price fluctuations. Further, the likely pressure on copper prices due to its possible scarcity is a cause for concern Gordon et al. (2006); Tilton and Lagos (2007), especially in light of its importance for the growing network industry.
Our previous works, Mastroeni and Vellucci (2019); Mastroeni et al. (2018), showed that a significant level of noise is usually present in the time series of copper futures intraday prices, supporting the conclusion that logarithmic returns have both a stochastic and deterministic nature. Hence, the use of stochastic models appears to be a natural choice.
In this paper, we develop a novel stochastic differential equation (SDE) that models the data and is based on the whitening filter approach Wiener (1949), a method characterizing linear time-variant systems. From a statistical point of view, we assume that the time series of prices can be described by autocorrelation. This property is obtained by means of statistical analyses of the historical data recorded for the futures copper closing prices (HG1 ticker) as exchanged on the COMEX market (CMX). Starting from a model of the empirical autocorrelation shown by the time series of prices, we introduce an SDE, which is characterized by this autocorrelation, and fits the model to the data. To the best of our knowledge, there have been no papers following this approach.
The purpose of the developed SDE model is to move one step further concerning the analysis started in our previous paper Mastroeni et al. (2018). In that paper, we showed that the time series of copper prices (the same studied in the present paper but for a shorter interval) exhibited both stochastic and chaotic features. At the same time, the recurrence plot of the time series revealed a pattern typical of intermittency phenomena.
The presence of stochastic features and intermittency phenomena called for a second step of the time series analysis started in Mastroeni et al. (2018), i.e., a new approach to short-term modeling for copper futures prices.
Our model produced trajectories close to the real data only in the short run. This is due, on the one hand, to the fitted model from the empirical autocorrelation and, on the other, to the predominantly stochastic behavior of the copper price time series, which can only be predicted in the short term Mastroeni and Vellucci (2019, 2022). To investigate the stochastic (vs deterministic) nature of the data, we follow the intuition behind recurrence analysis Eckmann et al. (1987); Marwan et al. (2007). In the Appendix A, we show that the performance of the model improved significantly when the time series had an empirical autocorrelation function close to the damped cosine model and a determinism measure (DET), based on a recurrence plot, close to one. In the numerical section, we show that the presence of a large stochastic component produced a poorer performance than that obtained for time intervals with a large deterministic component.
So far, the literature does not seem to have focused on mathematical modeling of the copper futures market, following econometric and statistical approaches instead. The following is a brief review of the literature supporting this claim.
In Jin et al. (2021), the authors analyzed the effect of the price correlation between domestic and foreign copper futures contracts. Guo et al. (2020) investigated the nonlinear correlation between the spot and futures prices in China’s copper market using nonlinear Granger causality and multifractal methods. Gong and Lin (2018) examined whether structural breaks contained incremental information for forecasting the volatility of copper futures. In Zheng et al. (2022), the authors conducted a comparative exploration of the chaotic characteristics of Chinese and international copper futures prices, showing the differences in those series through recurrence plots and correlation dimensions.
The co-movements of the dynamic correlations between copper futures and spot prices on a scale by scale basis were analyzed in Yu et al. (2021), using grey correlation analysis and wavelet analysis. In Galán-Gutiérrez and Martín-García (2022), Granger causality was exploited to test whether, during the first COVID-19 wave, the evolution of the pandemic was cointegrated with the price structure of copper futures, on the one hand, and with incremental levels of copper stocks, on the other. The authors of Idrovo-Aguirre and Contreras-Reyes (2021) proposed the impulse–response functions of a vector autoregressive model to capture the dynamic between copper prices and house building permits.
As for the development of a model that fit the same copper time series considered in Mastroeni et al. (2018), the paper Rivero and Vellucci (2022) modeled the copper price time series with a matching pursuit algorithm, which used a waveform dictionary with rectangular window functions introduced in De Carli and Vellucci (2018). The novelty of the present paper is the introduction of an SDE for the copper futures market: to the best of our knowledge, this is the only paper in the literature that attempts to provide a mathematical model for the copper futures market.
This paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the state space reconstruction by introducing a formal definition of determinism for time series. In Section 3, we recall the whitening filter approach and prove some preliminary useful results. Section 4 contains a brief exploratory analysis of the data, whereas in Section 5, we give the main results of the paper, constructing an SDE characterized by a damped cosine autocorrelation function. In Section 6.2, we perform some numerical simulations on the SDE obtained in the preceding sections for copper futures prices’ time series and, in the Appendix A, we compare them with the results obtained from an artificial time series. Section 7 is devoted to our conclusions.

2. Background

2.1. State Space Reconstruction

With the state space reconstruction problem, we aim at recreating states where the only information available is contained in a time series. In other words, we would like the time series { x ( k ) } k = 1 n = { x ( 1 ) , x ( 2 ) , , x ( n ) } to be approximately described by a smooth dynamical system f on a d-dimensional manifold M (which we assume to be M = R d ):
s ( t ) = f t ( s ( 0 ) )
where s ( t ) is the state at time t. For t 0 , f t is the time-t map of the continuous dynamical system, i.e., the transformation of state space which takes s ( 0 ) to s ( t ) . For noise-free data, the time series is related to the dynamical system by
x ( t ) = h ( s ( t ) ) ,
where h : M R is known as the measurement function.
To analyze a time series through the formalism of dynamical systems theory, the reconstruction of state space is necessarily the first step. There is no way to reconstruct states in their original form because f and h are typically both unknown but, luckily, the reconstructed state space is in some sense equivalent to the original.
The state space is reconstructed according to the delay coordinate method proposed by Takens (1981) and Packard et al. (1980). The delay coordinate method defines the state vector at time i as follows
x ( i ) = x ( i ) , x ( i + τ ) , x ( i + 2 τ ) , , x ( i + ( d 1 ) τ ) T ,
where d is the embedding dimension, and τ is an appropriate time delay. Here, T denotes the transpose, and we adopt the convention that states are represented by column vectors. Obviously, if n is the length of the time series, then i ranges in { 1 , 2 , , n ( d 1 ) τ } . For a complete characterization of τ and d see Mastroeni et al. (2018, 2019); Mastroeni and Vellucci (2019, 2022) and references therein.
In Takens (1981), Takens studied the delay reconstruction map Φ ( f , h ) , introducing the following result:
Theorem 1
(Takens 1981). For generic pairs ( f , h ) , where
  • f : M M is a C 2 -diffeomorphism of M in itself, and
  • h : M R is a C 2 -differentiable function,
the map Φ ( f , h ) : M R 2 d + 1 defined by
Φ ( f , h ) ( s ) = h ( s ) , h ( f τ ( s ) ) , , h f 2 τ d ( s ) T
is an embedding of M in R 2 d + 1 .
The important point of the theorem depends on the topological notion of “genericity”:
Definition 1.
Let P be a property of functions in C k ( M , N ) , which they might or might not have. Then, we say that P ( f ) is true for a generic f C k ( M , N ) if the set of functions for which it holds is open and dense in C k -topology.
For Theorem 1 to work, the genericity needs to be taken in the space of pairs ( f , h ) , but it can be replaced guaranteeing additional requirements for f, directed towards establishing a slightly different version of the theorem:
Theorem 2.
Let f : M M be a C 2 -diffeomorphism such that
  • the periodic points with period k 2 d are finite in number;
  • if x is any periodic point with period k 2 d, then the derivative of ϕ k at x has all distinct eigenvalues.
Then, for a generic h C 2 ( M , R ) , the map Φ ( ϕ , y ) : M R 2 d + 1 defined as in Theorem 1 is an embedding of M in R 2 d + 1 .
Under the assumptions of Taken’s Theorem 1, an embedding is a smooth one-to-one coordinate transformation with a smooth inverse. For a compact manifold M , a smooth one-to-one map M M whose derivative is everywhere one-to-one is a smooth embedding, i.e., the inverse is smooth for free (the local smoothness of the inverse essentially comes from the inverse function theorem).
If Φ is an embedding, then a smooth dynamics F is induced on the space of reconstructed vectors:
F t ( x ) = Φ f t Φ 1 ( x ) ,
where F is equivalent to the original dynamics f. Likewise, the reconstructed states can be used to estimate F; thus, we can use this for the purpose of the paper, as described in the following section.

2.2. A Definition of Determinism

In this section, we formalize the notion of determinism of a time series, taking it from the field of chaos theory. It is based on the recurrence plot, introduced by Eckmann et al. (1987) to visualize the different times at which a trajectory visits roughly the same area of the state space, which in turn is the result of the state space reconstruction theory, already seen in the previous section.
Let be the Euclidean norm in R d and ϵ be a tolerance parameter to be chosen as recommended in Mastroeni et al. (2018, 2019); Mastroeni and Vellucci (2019, 2022) and references therein. Let
Θ ( x ) : = 1 , x > 0 0 , x 0
be the Heaviside step function. Then, we have the following definition of the recurrence plot.
Definition 2.
Let us consider the matrix
M i j = Θ ϵ v ( i ) v ( j ) .
The recurrence plot R is the set of all points ( i , j ) for which M i j = 1 :
R : = ( i , j ) R 2 | M i j = 1
The matrix M is symmetric due to the symmetry of the Euclidean norm, so that the recurrence plot R is likewise symmetric around the bisecting line of the first quadrant.
Let P ( l ) be the histogram of diagonal lines of length l, i.e.,
P ( l ) = i , j = 1 N 1 M i 1 , j 1 1 M i + l , j + l k = 0 l 1 M i + k , j + k .
As recalled in Marwan et al. (2007), “processes with uncorrelated or weakly correlated, stochastic or chaotic behavior cause none or very short diagonals, whereas deterministic processes cause longer diagonals and less single, isolated recurrence points”. This allows us to introduce the following definition of the determinism of a system:
Definition 3.
Fix l m i n > 1 . Then, the percentage of recurrence points placed on diagonal structures with respect to all recurrence points,
D E T = l = l m i n N l P ( l ) l = 1 N l P ( l ) ,
is introduced as a measure for the determinism of the system.
(For the choice of l m i n see Marwan et al. (2007)). This is the measure for determinism of the reconstructed system and, from Equation (5), also of the smooth dynamical system f that approximately describes the starting time series.

3. Preliminary Results: The Whitening Filter Approach

Let us recall the whitening filter approach and introduce some preliminary results that we need to achieve the mathematical results in the subsequent sections.
One of the most commonly used methods to characterize a linear time-variant system, that is, to specify its input–output relationship, is based on the impulse response of the system. For example, a two-terminal pair system, with input x ( t ) and output y ( t ) is depicted in Figure 1. The impulse response of the linear time-variant system is denoted by h ( t , τ ) . It is the output at time t to an input applied at time τ . Given T > 0 , for a physically realizable system, we assume that h ( t , τ ) is zero outside the range [ 0 , T ] . Then, the input–output relation assumes the form:
y ( t ) = 0 T h ( t , τ ) x ( τ ) d τ
Let us consider now a nonstationary noise n ( t ) that can be characterized by its autocorrelation R n ( t , τ ) . The whitening filter problem consists in finding the system h ( t , τ ) for a given R n ( t , τ ) , such that the output spectrum is R n ( t τ ) = δ ( t τ ) . Let us introduce the following Proposition.
Proposition 1.
Let ϕ j be the set of eigenfunctions of R n ( τ , τ ) ,
λ j ϕ j ( τ ) = 0 T R n ( τ , τ ) ϕ j ( τ ) d τ .
Then, the filter given by the expansion of equation:
h ( t , τ ) = j a j ( t ) ϕ j ( τ ) w h e r e a j ( t ) = 0 T h ( t , τ ) ϕ j ( τ ) d τ
solves the whitening filter problem.
Proof. 
Given the expression of noise output
n ( t ) = 0 T h ( t , τ ) n ( τ ) d τ ,
we can compute its autocorrelation function as:
R n ( t 1 , t 2 ) = E n ( t 1 ) n ( t 2 ) = E 0 T h ( t 1 , τ ) n ( τ ) d τ 0 T h ( t 2 , τ ) n ( τ ) d τ = E 0 T 0 T h ( t 1 , τ ) h ( t 2 , τ ) n ( τ ) n ( τ ) d τ d τ = 0 T 0 T h ( t 1 , τ ) h ( t 2 , τ ) E n ( τ ) n ( τ ) d τ d τ ,
and then,
R n ( t 1 , t 2 ) = 0 T 0 T h ( t 1 , τ ) h ( t 2 , τ ) R n ( τ , τ ) d τ d τ .
If n ( t ) is real R n ( τ , τ ) , it is symmetric; therefore, a standard eigenfunction approach can be used to solve the integral Equation (15).
Let ϕ j be the set of eigenfunctions of R n ( τ , τ ) ,
λ j ϕ j ( τ ) = 0 T R n ( τ , τ ) ϕ j ( τ ) d τ .
Since the set of eigenfunctions is complete, the system functions can be expanded as
h ( t , τ ) = j a j ( t ) ϕ j ( τ ) ,
where
a j ( t ) = 0 T h ( t , τ ) ϕ j ( τ ) d τ .
By using the expansion (17), Equation (15) becomes:
R n ( t 1 , t 2 ) = j a j ( t 2 ) 0 T h ( t 1 , τ ) 0 T R n ( τ , τ ) ϕ j ( τ ) d τ d τ = j λ j a j ( t 2 ) 0 T h ( t 1 , τ ) ϕ j ( τ ) d τ = j λ j a j ( t 1 ) a j ( t 2 ) .
If one first considers making the output noise spectrum only stationary:
R n ( t 1 , t 2 ) = R ( t 1 t 2 ) ,
then a j ( t 1 ) is identified as γ j / λ j 1 / 2 ψ j ( t 1 ) , where ψ j ( t 1 ) and γ j are the eigenfunction and eigenvalue associated with R ( t 1 t 2 ) , respectively:
γ j ψ j ( t 1 ) = 0 T R ( t 1 t 2 ) ψ j ( t 2 ) d t 2 .
Now, we denote by L f ( s ) = L f ( s ) or simply F ( s ) the bilateral Laplace transform of a function f : R R .
If a random (wide-sense stationary) process n ( t ) passes through a time-invariant filter h ( τ ) , such as the one depicted in Figure 1, then the autocorrelation function given by Equation (15) becomes
R n ( t ) = R n ( t τ + τ ) h ( τ ) h ( τ ) d τ d τ .
For white noise input, R n ( t ) = δ ( t ) , and
R n ( t ) = h ( τ t ) h ( τ ) d τ .
The power spectrum of the output is the Laplace transform of R n ( t ) :
S n ( s ) = R n ( t ) e s t d t = h ( τ t ) h ( τ ) e s t d t d τ .
By integrating first with respect to t:
h ( τ t ) e s t d t = e s τ h ( γ ) e s γ d γ = e s τ H ( s ) ,
and then with respect to τ , we obtain:
S n ( s ) = H ( s ) h ( τ ) e s τ d τ = H ( s ) H ( s ) .
Let us now explain what the relation is between a pole or zero of H ( s ) and the corresponding pole or zero of H s . The poles and zeros of H s are those of H ( s ) mirrored across the imaginary axis of a complex plane. Therefore, the poles and zeros of S n ( s ) are paired across the imaginary axis. With N pole pairs and M zero pairs in S n ( s ) , we have (in principle) 2 N + M different choices of whitening filter that produce S n ( s ) . However, imposing the causality/stability of the whitening filter, we have to place all the poles in the left-hand-side complex plane. After that, we have just 2 M choices. Then, to impose a minimum phase, we place all zeros in the left-hand-side complex plane. At the end, the filter is stable, causal, and minimum phase. Here, we refer to a strictly stable linear system as being one with all the poles of its transfer function in the open left-hand-side complex plane C 0 = { s C : s < 0 } , and we refer to a stable linear system as being one with poles in the closed left-hand-side complex plane.

4. Exploratory Data Analysis

The dataset employed in our analysis was the time series of intraday Generic 1st Futures Copper closing prices (HG1 ticker) as exchanged on the COMEX market (CMX) and retrieved from the Bloomberg website. The dataset consisted of 2864 observations and spanned from 8 June 2021 to 8 June 2022.
We denoted the time series of intraday prices by P ( t ) t = 1 n , with P ( t ) R + , and the logarithmic returns by { p ( t ) } t = 1 n 1 = ln P ( t + 1 ) P ( t ) t = 1 n 1 . The overall time series is shown in Figure 2 and Figure 3.
The data were not equally spaced intraday prices, i.e., the number of intraday observations was not constant but varied over time. See Figure 4.
The Hurst exponent of the series p ( t ) was 0.53, which meant that the time series was trending. This value was near to 0.5 (i.e., the time series was generated by a geometric Brownian motion).
Figure 5 shows the autocorrelation of the considered data set for time lags up to points in time 10 (number of observations, recall that we have intraday prices). The red line is the autocorrelation computed from the data, while the green line corresponds to the nonlinear fit according to the expression
R ( τ ) = σ 2 e α | τ | cos ( ω τ )
The damped cosine function was a good approximation to the autocorrelation for time lags up to approximately 10 observations.

5. Construction of the SDE-Based Model

Let us assume the logarithmic returns p ( t ) = ln P ( t + 1 ) P ( t ) were characterized by the damped cosine autocorrelation R ( τ ) = E p ( t ) p ( t + τ ) described by (27), whose decay rate is governed by the coefficient α .
Since we know that the autocorrelation price process p ( t ) fits a function such as (27), the problem was to derive an SDE that describes a process with this autocorrelation. Theorem 3 answers this question:
Theorem 3.
Let w ( t ) be the white noise. Let also p ( 0 ) = κ 1 , p ˙ ( 0 ) = κ 2 , and w ( 0 ) = κ 3 . If R p ( τ ) = E p ( t ) p ( t + τ ) is the autocorrelation of log-price p ( t ) described by (27), then the SDE that results from the whitening filter procedure is
p ¨ ( t ) + 2 α p ˙ ( t ) + β 2 p ( t ) + κ 2 κ 3 + 2 α κ 1 δ ( t ) + κ 1 δ ˙ ( t ) = β w ( t ) + w ˙ ( t ) ,
where δ is the Dirac delta function, β = ω 2 + α 2 , and the variance of w ( t ) is 2 α σ 2 .
Proof. 
The Wiener–Kolmogorov whitening procedure from Wiener (1949) is used on R p ( τ ) to represent the log-price p ( t ) = ln P ( t + 1 ) P ( t ) as a function of time, driven by a white noise input w ( t ) . The procedure is used in the proof to decompose the Laplace transform of R p ( τ ) into the product of white noise and a system function: L R ( s ) = W ( s ) H ( s ) H ( s ) . Here, the quantity H ( s ) is the transfer function of the whitening filter for the log-price p ( t ) , and W ( s ) is the transform of the white noise w ( t ) that drives p ( t ) .
The Laplace transform of the autocorrelation function R p ( τ ) is
L R ( s ) = σ 2 e α | τ | cos ( ω τ ) e s τ d τ .
Splitting the module,
L R ( s ) = 0 σ 2 cos ( ω τ ) e ( α s ) τ d τ + 0 σ 2 cos ( ω τ ) e ( α + s ) τ d τ ,
solving the integrals,
L R ( s ) = σ 2 α s ω 2 + ( α s ) 2 + s + α ω 2 + ( s + α ) 2 ,
and factorizing the resulting expression, we obtain
L R ( s ) = 2 α σ 2 β s s 2 2 α s + β 2 β + s s 2 + 2 α s + β 2 ,
where β = ω 2 + α 2 . Hence, we have
H ( s ) = β + s s 2 + 2 α s + β 2 ,
and
W ( s ) = 2 α σ 2 .
Indeed, the autocorrelation function R w ( τ ) of the white noise input is found by taking the inverse Laplace transform of (34) as
R w ( τ ) = 2 α σ 2 δ ( τ ) ,
where 2 α σ 2 is the variance of w ( t ) .
From the definition of a transfer function, we have that H ( s ) = P ( s ) W ( s ) , where P ( s ) is the Laplace transform of p ( t ) . Moreover, it is well known that for a generic function y ( t ) ,
s Y ( s ) = L ( y ˙ ( t ) ) + y ( 0 ) = L ( y ˙ ( t ) + y ( 0 ) δ ( t ) ) s 2 Y ( s ) = L ( y ¨ ( t ) ) + s y ( 0 ) + y ˙ ( 0 ) = L ( y ¨ ( t ) + y ( 0 ) δ ˙ ( t ) + y ˙ ( 0 ) δ ( t ) ) .
Applying these last considerations to Equation (33), and recalling that p ( 0 ) = κ 1 , p ˙ ( 0 ) = κ 2 , and w ( 0 ) = κ 3 , we obtain the differential Equation (28). □
Remark 1.
As anticipated in Section 3, it can be easily demonstrated that the whitening filter, whose transfer function is described by Equation (33) in the proof of Theorem 3, is unique, stable, causal, and minimum phase.
At this stage, we do not yet have the formulation of a standard SDE, i.e., a rigorously defined equivalent implicit Ito’s integral equation. For instance,
d p ( t ) = a t , p ( t ) d t + b t , p ( t ) d B ( t ) p ( t ) = p ( 0 ) + 0 t a s , p ( s ) d s + 0 t b s , p ( s ) d B s ,
where B denotes a Wiener process (the standard Brownian motion). Instead, the approach followed in Theorem 3 presents us with these mathematical problems Evans (2012):
  • Defining the white noise w ( t ) in a rigorous way;
  • Showing that (28) has a solution, discussing uniqueness, asymptotic behavior, and dependence upon α and ω .
However, we can start from (28) with a heuristic explanation: we could think of the white noise introduced in Theorem 3 as the “derivative” of Brownian motion. It is just heuristic reasoning because the standard Brownian motion is nowhere differentiable with probability one, but it is a way to start and move intuitively from (28). To formalize this rigorously, we use the theory of generalized functions.
As we know, a generalized function is a continuous linear function on the set of infinitely differentiable functions with bounded support, which we denote with C 0 or simply D . The space of generalized functions on D is denoted by D . We write
F [ ϕ ] : D R .
We define the generalized derivative of F [ ϕ ] to be the generalized function F [ ϕ ] , so that
F [ ϕ ] F ϕ , for all ϕ D .
Thinking of Brownian motion as a random function, we can define a white noise w ( t ) as its generalized derivative. Hence:
Lemma 1.
Let B ( t ) 0 be a real-valued Brownian motion on a probability space ( Ω , A , P ) . Then,
B ˙ ( t ) = w ( t ) .
Proof. 
Formally, according to Evans (2012); Lord et al. (2014), white noise w ( t ) is a stochastic process on a probability space ( Ω , A , P ) with E [ w ( t ) ] = 0 and E [ w ( s ) w ( t ) ] = δ ( s t ) for all s , t [ 0 , 1 ] , where δ denotes the Dirac delta function.
We define
D ( t , Δ t ) : = B ( t + Δ t ) B ( t ) Δ t for t 0 ,
for some Δ t > 0 . Then, D ( t , Δ t ) is a stochastic process on ( Ω , A , P ) with
E D ( t , Δ t ) = 0 for all t 0 ,
and for all s , t 0 ,
η ( s t , Δ t ) : = Cov D ( s , Δ t ) , D ( t , Δ t ) = Δ t | s t | Δ t 2 , if | s t | Δ t 0 , if | s t | Δ t .
Let ϕ D . Then, we have
lim Δ t 0 ϕ ( x ) η ( x , Δ t ) d x = lim Δ t 0 Δ t Δ t ϕ ( x ) Δ t | x | Δ t 2 d x ,
i.e., replacing x Δ t x ,
lim Δ t 0 1 1 ϕ ( Δ t x ) ( 1 | x | ) d x = ϕ ( 0 ) 1 1 ( 1 | x | ) d x = ϕ ( 0 ) .
Therefore, in distribution, we can write
η ( x , Δ t ) Δ t 0 δ ( x ) .
Thus, we have that the derivative of the covariance matrix for the Brownian motion is the same as the covariance matrix for the white noise; thus, the derivative of the Brownian motion is the white noise. □
In a similar manner, we introduce the second time derivative on a Wiener process (or just the time derivative on a white noise):
Lemma 2.
Let B ( t ) 0 be a real-valued Brownian motion on a probability space ( Ω , A , P ) . Then, the stochastic process
B ¨ ( t ) = w ˙ ( t ) = η ( t )
has the following statistics:
E η ( t ) = 0 ; E η ( t ) η ( s ) = d 2 d z 2 δ ( z ) | z = t s .
Proof. 
Similar to the proof of Lemma 1, we define
D ( t , Δ t ) : = w ( t + Δ t ) w ( t ) Δ t for t 0 ,
and we take Δ t at the last step.
For the expected value of D ( t , Δ t ) we have that 1 Δ t E w ( t + Δ t ) E w ( t ) = 0 . For the covariance, we have instead
E D ( t , Δ t ) D ( s , Δ t ) = 1 Δ t 2 E w ( t + Δ t ) w ( t ) w ( s + Δ t ) w ( s ) ,
i.e.,
E D ( t , Δ t ) D ( s , Δ t ) = 1 Δ t 2 { E [ w ( t + Δ t ) w ( s + Δ t ) ] E [ w ( t + Δ t ) w ( s ) ] + E [ w ( t ) w ( s + Δ t ) ] + E [ w ( t ) w ( s ) ] } .
From the statistics of a white noise,
E [ w ( t ) w ( s ) ] = E [ w ( t + Δ t ) w ( s + Δ t ) ] = δ ( t s ) E [ w ( t + Δ t ) w ( s ) ] = δ ( t s + Δ t ) E [ w ( t ) w ( s + Δ t ) ] = δ ( t s Δ t ) ,
we have that
E D ( t , Δ t ) D ( s , Δ t ) = 1 Δ t 2 δ ( t s + Δ t ) 2 δ ( t s ) + δ ( t s Δ t )
= d 2 d z 2 δ ( z ) | z = t s
as Δ t 0 . □
Corollary 1.
The Ito’s integral form of Equation (28) is
d p ( t ) = v ( t ) d t κ 1 d Θ + d B ( t ) , p ( 0 ) = κ 1 , v ( 0 ) = 2 κ 1 κ 3 d v ( t ) = β 2 p ( t ) + 2 α v ( t ) d t κ 2 κ 3 d Θ + ( β 2 α ) d B ( t ) ,
where Θ is the Heaviside step function with the distributional derivative Θ ˙ = δ . Equation (54) has the unique solution:
p ( t ) = e α t ω p 0 ω cos ω t + α sin ω t + v 0 sin ω t + + e α t ω 0 t e α s ω cos ω ( t s ) + ( β α ) sin ω ( t s ) d B ( s ) + + e α t ω κ 1 ω cos ω t + α sin ω t + ( κ 3 κ 2 ) sin ω t v ( t ) = e α t ω p 0 β 2 sin ω t + v 0 ω cos ω t α sin ω t + + e α t ω 0 t e α s ω ( β 2 α ) cos ω ( t s ) + ( β 2 α β + 2 α 2 ) sin ω ( t s ) d B ( s ) + e α t ω κ 1 β 2 sin ω t + ( κ 3 κ 2 ) ω cos ω t α sin ω t .
Proof. 
From Lemmas 1 and 2, we can rewrite Equation (28) as
p ¨ ( t ) + 2 α p ˙ ( t ) + β 2 p ( t ) + κ 2 κ 3 + 2 α κ 1 δ ( t ) + κ 1 δ ˙ ( t ) = β B ˙ ( t ) + B ¨ ( t ) .
To reduce the order in Equation (56), we combine the derivative terms shifting some of them around. Hence, we obtain a first-order system with the substitution v ( t ) = p ˙ ( t ) B ˙ ( t ) + κ 1 δ ( t ) , i.e., v ˙ ( t ) + B ¨ ( t ) κ 1 δ ˙ ( t ) = p ¨ . Accordingly,
v ˙ ( t ) + B ¨ ( t ) κ 1 δ ˙ ( t ) + 2 α v ( t ) + B ˙ ( t ) κ 1 δ ( t ) + β 2 p ( t ) + + κ 2 κ 3 + 2 α κ 1 δ ( t ) + κ 1 δ ˙ ( t ) = β B ˙ ( t ) + B ¨ ( t ) .
With simple algebra, we obtain
p ˙ ( t ) = v ( t ) κ 1 δ ( t ) + B ˙ ( t ) v ˙ ( t ) = 2 α v ( t ) β 2 p ( t ) κ 2 κ 3 δ ( t ) + β 2 α B ˙ ( t ) ,
and thus the corresponding well-defined Ito’s integral form (54).
By passing to the vectorial form and neglecting the Heaviside terms, Equation (54) can be rewritten as
d p ( t ) v ( t ) = A p ( t ) v ( t ) d t + 1 β 2 α d B ( t ) ,
where
A = 0 1 β 2 2 α .
Given any initial value ( p ( 0 ) , v ( 0 ) ) = p 0 , v 0 R 2 , from the linearity of the SDE, we know that Equation (59) has the unique solution Mao (2007)
p ( t ) v ( t ) = e A t p 0 v 0 + 0 t e A ( t s ) 1 β 2 α d B ( s ) .
To consider the neglected terms, let us replace the Brownian motion B ( t ) by the process X ( t ) such that
X ( t ) : = 0 t 1 β 2 α d B ( s ) + 0 t κ 1 κ 3 κ 2 d Θ ( s ) = 1 β 2 α B ( t ) + κ 1 κ 3 κ 2 Θ ( t ) + X ( 0 ) = X ( 1 ) ( t ) X ( 2 ) ( t ) ,
whose quadratic variation is
X ( 1 ) , X ( 1 ) t = t + κ 1 2 Θ ( t ) , X ( 2 ) , X ( 2 ) t = ( β 2 α ) 2 t + ( κ 3 κ 2 ) 2 Θ ( t ) X ( 1 ) , X ( 2 ) t = ( β 2 α ) t + κ 1 ( κ 2 κ 3 ) Θ ( t ) .
Now, for a one-dimensional Brownian motion { B ( t ) : t 0 } , we have
E B ( t ) F + ( s ) = E B ( t ) B ( s ) F + ( s ) + B ( s )
= E [ B ( t ) B ( s ) ] + B ( s ) = B ( s ) .
Hence, a Brownian motion is a martingale with respect to the filtration F + ( t ) : t 0 . Moreover, using the definition of the total variation of a real-valued function, it is possible to show that the variation of Θ is 0 on every interval in ( , 0 ) and 1 on every larger interval. This means that the total variation of Θ is Θ itself; hence, it is a càdlàg adapted process of finite variation. Thus, X ( t ) is a semi martingale Rogers and Williams (2000).
Hence, Equation (54) can be rewritten as
d p ( t ) v ( t ) = A p ( t ) v ( t ) d t + d X ( t ) .
Ito’s formula gives us the solution of (66), i.e.,
p ( t ) v ( t ) = e A t p 0 v 0 + 0 t e A ( t s ) d X ( s ) .
The matrix A has the property that A p v = v β 2 p 2 α v , so we can use it to define sequences x n , y n as
A n 1 0 = x n x n + 1 A n 0 1 = y n y n + 1 ,
where x 0 = 1 , x 1 = 0 , y 0 = 0 , y 1 = 1 , and
x n + 2 = 2 α x n + 1 β 2 x n y n + 2 = 2 α y n + 1 β 2 y n .
The general closed formula for x n , y n , when the discriminant of the quadratic polynomial Δ is not zero, is in terms of x + , x = 2 α ± Δ 2 . In our case, Δ = 4 α 2 4 β 2 = 4 ω 2 , which is by definition different from 0. Thus, x + , x = α ± i ω , and
y n = 1 2 ω i x + n x n x n = 1 2 ω i x + x n x x + n .
So:
k = 0 1 k ! ( A t ) k 0 1 = k = 0 y k t k k ! k = 0 y k + 1 t k k ! = 1 2 ω i e x + t e x t x + e x + t x e x t ,
which is the right column of e A t . The left column is similarly calculated as:
1 2 ω i x + e x t x e x + t β 2 e x t e x + t .
Equation (54) then has the unique solution:
p ( t ) = e α t ω p 0 ω cos ω t + α sin ω t + v 0 sin ω t + + e α t ω 0 t e α s ω cos ω ( t s ) + ( β α ) sin ω ( t s ) d B ( s ) + + e α t ω 0 t e α s κ 1 ω cos ω ( t s ) + α sin ω ( t s ) + ( κ 3 κ 2 ) sin ω ( t s ) d Θ ( s ) v ( t ) = e α t ω p 0 β 2 sin ω t + v 0 ω cos ω t α sin ω t + + e α t ω 0 t e α s ω ( β 2 α ) cos ω ( t s ) + ( β 2 α β + 2 α 2 ) sin ω ( t s ) d B ( s ) + e α t ω 0 t e α s κ 1 β 2 sin ω ( t s ) + ( κ 3 κ 2 ) ω cos ω ( t s ) α sin ω ( t s ) d Θ ( s ) .
Thus, since Θ ( 0 ) = 0 , we have the claim. □

6. Numerical Implementation and Experiments

In this section, we demonstrate how the whitening filter approach with a damped cosine function as an autocorrelation function was able to fit the data through examples of simple simulations and intraday prices of copper futures.

6.1. Simulations

We generated an artificial time series that was a damped cosine function, whose oscillations were blurred by white noise w ( t ) . The time series was the following:
s ( t ) = 2 e t 100 cos t 2 w ( t ) ,
where w ( t ) [ 0 , 1 ] t . Figure 6 shows the autocorrelation of s ( t ) for time lags up to points in time 30. The red line is the autocorrelation computed from data, while the green line corresponds to a nonlinear fit, according to expression (27). Compared to Figure 5 for copper prices, the damped cosine function perfectly fit the empirical autocorrelation of the artificial data.
As shown in Figure 7, we randomly generated 250 observations from the distribution (69), and our approximation (green), according to model (54), was able to come close to the true values of the series up to about 60 observations. This was certainly a better result than that observed for the copper price series. The improved results obtained on the artificial series were due to the fact that it had an empirical autocorrelation function that perfectly fit the damped cosine assumed by our model. Moreover, let us recall that, from Section 6.2, the determinism coefficient seemed to be able to explain the goodness of the fit. Indeed, the determinism of the artificial data was much higher than that of copper prices—DET = 0.88 for s ( t ) .

6.2. Intraday Copper Futures Prices

First, time-series data were segmented into consecutive equal segments by applying a time window of width n = 250 observations. All the segments were disjoint. In particular, we focused on the following time ranges: (i) from 8 June 2021 to 8 July 2021; (ii) from 9 July 2021 to 10 August 2021; (iii) from 21 September 2021 to 17 November 2021; (iv) from 18 November 2021 to 8 December 2021; (v) from 9 December 2021 to 12 January 2022; (vi) from 13 January 2022 to 28 February 2022; and (vii) from 28 April 2022 to 18 May 2022. All these ranges were characterized by an autocorrelation function, such as the one depicted in Figure 5. In the following, we denote them by the corresponding Roman numerals.
In order to perform the simulations for the SDE model (54), we employed the R solver deSolve. This package uses a scheme introduced by Petzold (1983) for automatically determining whether an initial value problem, d y / d t = f ( y , t ) , y t 0 = y 0 , can be solved more efficiently using a class of methods suited for nonstiff problems or a class of methods designed for stiff problems. We approximated a Dirac delta by a Gaussian function whose width was controlled by a parameter σ . We chose a Gaussian function located in the origin and with σ = 0.1 . We also used a geometric Brownian motion simulation model with 2000 possible trajectories. We fixed one of these trajectories, adding it to the deterministic part with Dirac delta term, according to the scheme (54). We repeated this procedure for all the trajectories, selecting the one which minimized the sum of the residuals
r ( p ^ ( t ) ) : = t = 1 n 1 p ( t ) p ^ ( t ) 2 ,
where n is the width of the time window, { p ( t ) } is the time series of logarithmic returns, and { p ^ ( t ) } represents the simulated prices according to Equation (54). We denote by p ^ opt ( t ) the simulated price series, which minimizes (70), and r opt = r ( p ^ opt ( t ) ) .
However, since the log returns of copper were cosine-exponentially autocorrelated only for time lags up to 10 observations, the ability of the developed model (54) to represent the copper price behavior was expected to be acceptable only for that time frame. Indeed this was the case, as shown in Figure 8, Figure 9 and Figure 10. The trajectories were very close to the real data up to 10 observations. The residuals estimated for the optimum trajectory, r opt , can be read in Table 1 where we also detailed the values of the standard deviation and determinism for each of the considered time ranges. The model’s ability to fit data only up to 10 observations was related to the following points: (1) the data did not really show an inflection and sign change in the first three points, as we would expect from the cosine—see Figure 5—and the damped cosine function (27) was just a valid approximation for the first few lags; (2) the determinism level in Table 1 revealed the presence of a large stochastic component, and this meant that the behavior of the copper price could be predicted only in the short term Mastroeni and Vellucci (2019, 2022). Regarding Table 1, the worst values of r opt were achieved in the ranges (vii), (v), and (ii), and these were also the ranges that showed the smallest possible value of determinism (i.e., 0). In terms of the residuals of (iii): they were about 18, as in (ii), which had a null value of determinism, despite the latter being different from 0 for (iii). With the exception of range (iii), all intervals with a determinism other than 0 appeared to show lower residuals. The values of the standard deviation did not seem to be able to explain the goodness of fit. In fact, the Pearson correlation coefficient between the standard deviation and r opt was 0.0836063 , whereas between determinism and r opt , it was 0.6120757 .

7. Conclusions

In this paper, we developed a novel stochastic differential equation (SDE) that fit the model of intraday copper futures prices and was based on the whitening filter approach Wiener (1949), a method characterizing linear time-variant systems. We assumed that the time series of prices could be described by its autocorrelation. This property was obtained through statistical analyses of historical data. Starting from an empirical autocorrelation model obtained from the price time series, we introduced an SDE that was characterized by this autocorrelation and fit the model to the data.
The model we developed produced trajectories close to the real data only in the short run. This was due, on the one hand, to the model fitted by empirical autocorrelation and, on the other, to the predominantly stochastic behavior of the copper price time series, which can only be predicted in the short term Mastroeni and Vellucci (2019, 2022). To investigate the stochastic (vs. deterministic) nature of the data, we followed the intuition behind the recurrence analysis Eckmann et al. (1987); Marwan et al. (2007). In the Appendix A, we also show that the performance of the model improved significantly, when the time series had an empirical autocorrelation function close to the damped cosine model and a determinism measure (DET) based on the recurrence plot close to one. Therefore, future work will include the assumption of more complex functions to model the autocorrelation function of intraday copper futures prices.
Based on the numerical results presented in Section 6.2 regarding the level of determinism through the recurrence plot and the performance of the SDE model, this paper showed that the predictability of copper futures prices is rather weak. In fact, as already said, the model we derived produced trajectories close to the actual data only in the short term. Consequently, the investment risk of copper futures is high, which confirms the results in Mastroeni et al. (2018). Based on the reconstructed copper price phase space, the recurrence plot confirmed that deterministic features coexisted with stochastic ones in copper futures prices. In the intervals considered, the level of determinism was often zero, indicating that the copper futures prices were not predictable.
Compared to other metal futures such as aluminum and nickel, copper futures seem to have a higher investment risk. For instance, the prices considered by Sun et al. (2022) were highly deterministic. In any case, the time series considered here were different in terms of granularity and time span, and intraday copper futures are probably a riskier investment than daily ones. Investigating this aspect could be an interesting issue for a future work.
Additional further research would be to generalize the SDE model to the multivariate case. In fact, since copper prices are correlated with other commodities (such as steel, gold, and oil), it would be interesting to know whether this model could use this information. In any case, co-movements among these series did not arise from the model, but it is necessary to use ad hoc methodologies, e.g., those employed in our previous papers Mastroeni et al. (2021, 2022); Benedetto et al. (2020, 2021), Benedetto et al. (2016). A possible generalization of the SDE model proposed in this paper should integrate these methodologies in the whitening filter approach.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, L.M. and P.V.; methodology, L.M. and P.V.; formal analysis, L.M. and P.V.; writing—original draft preparation, L.M. and P.V.; writing—review and editing, L.M. and P.V. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

The data are available upon request.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A. Option Prices on Copper Futures

The present research aimed at matching the paths between the copper future prices and the proposed model. In this section, we also consider the prices of options on copper futures, collected from Barchart.com. We focused on American options with an expiration date at the end of December 2022.
We considered the daily open prices for the options contract. We also considered options contracts “near the money” (i.e., whose strike price was close to the current market price of the corresponding underlying security)—here, it was 10 strikes + / —and options contracts with 50 Strikes + / . We focused on the strike prices 3.40 and 3.45. The results concerning these contracts are depicted in Figure A1 and Figure A2.
The obtained results did not appear to be as good as those achieved for futures. However, this could be due to several reasons, for example the granularity of the data (intraday for futures, daily for options), which did not make it possible to effectively compare the results in this section with those shown in the previous ones.
Figure A1. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the option prices on copper futures. Temporal range: from 1 February 2021 to 25 February 2022. Strikes (near the money): 340 call (top left), 340 put (top right), 345 call (bottom left), and 345 put (bottom right).
Figure A1. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the option prices on copper futures. Temporal range: from 1 February 2021 to 25 February 2022. Strikes (near the money): 340 call (top left), 340 put (top right), 345 call (bottom left), and 345 put (bottom right).
Risks 10 00218 g0a1
Figure A2. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the option prices on copper futures. Temporal range: from 1 February 2021 to 25 January 2022. Fifty strikes + / : 340 call (top left), 340 put (top right), 345 call (bottom left), and 345 put (bottom right).
Figure A2. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the option prices on copper futures. Temporal range: from 1 February 2021 to 25 January 2022. Fifty strikes + / : 340 call (top left), 340 put (top right), 345 call (bottom left), and 345 put (bottom right).
Risks 10 00218 g0a2

References

  1. Benedetto, Francesco, Gaetano Giunta, and Loretta Mastroeni. 2016. On the Predictability of Energy Commodity Markets by an Entropy-based Computational Method. Energy Economics 54: 302–12. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Benedetto, Francesco, Loretta Mastroeni, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2020. Extraction of information content exchange in financial markets by an entropy analysis. ACM Transactions on Management Information Systems (TMIS) 12: 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Benedetto, Francesco, Loretta Mastroeni, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2021. Modeling the flow of information between financial time-series by an entropy-based approach. Annals of Operations Research 299: 1235–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. De Carli, Laura, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2018. Stability results for Gabor frames and the p-order hold models. Linear Algebra and its Applications 536: 186–200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Eckmann, J.-P., S. Oliffson Kamphorst, and D. Ruelle. 1987. Recurrence Plots of Dynamical Systems. EPL (Europhysics Letters) 4: 973. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  6. Evans, Lawrence C. 2012. An Introduction to Stochastic Differential Equations. Rhode Island: American Mathematical Society, vol. 82. [Google Scholar]
  7. Galán-Gutiérrez, Juan Antonio, and Rodrigo Martín-García. 2022. Fundamentals vs. Financialization during Extreme Events: From Backwardation to Contango, a Copper Market Analysis during the COVID-19 Pandemic. Mathematics 10: 559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Gong, Xu, and Boqiang Lin. 2018. Structural breaks and volatility forecasting in the copper futures market. Journal of Futures Markets 38: 290–339. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Gordon, R. Bertram, Marlen Bertram, and Thomas E. Graedel. 2006. Metal stocks and sustainability. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 103: 1209–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  10. Guo, Yaoqi, Shanshan Yao, Hui Cheng, and Wensong Zhu. 2020. China’s copper futures market efficiency analysis: Based on nonlinear Granger causality and multifractal methods. Resources Policy 68: 101716. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Idrovo-Aguirre, Byron J., and Javier E. Contreras-Reyes. 2021. The Response of Housing Construction to a Copper Price Shock in Chile (2009–2020). Economies 9: 98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Jin, Xue, Shiwei Zhou, Kedong Yin, and Mingzhen Li. 2021. Relationships between Copper Futures Markets from the Perspective of Jump Diffusion. Mathematics 9: 2268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Lord, Gabriel J., Catherine E. Powell, and Tony Shardlow. 2014. An Introduction to Computational Stochastic PDEs. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, vol. 50. [Google Scholar]
  14. Mao, Xuerong. 2007. Stochastic Differential Equations and Applications. Amsterdam: Elsevier. [Google Scholar]
  15. Marwan, Norbert, M. Carmen Romano, Marco Thiel, and Jürgen Kurths. 2007. Recurrence plots for the analysis of complex systems. Physics Reports 438: 237–329. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Mastroeni, Loretta, Alessandro Mazzoccoli, Greta Quaresima, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2021. Decoupling and recoupling in the crude oil price benchmarks: An investigation of similarity patterns. Energy Economics 94: 105036. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Mastroeni, Loretta, Alessandro Mazzoccoli, Greta Quaresima, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2022. Wavelet analysis and energy-based measures for oil-food price relationship as a footprint of financialisation effect. Resources Policy 77: 102692. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Mastroeni, Loretta, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2019. Chaos versus stochastic paradigm in energy markets. In Handbook of Energy Finance: Theories, Practices and Simulations. Singapore: World Scientific, pp. 765–86. [Google Scholar]
  19. Mastroeni, Loretta, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2022. Replication in Energy Markets: Use and Misuse of Chaos Tools. Entropy 24: 701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Mastroeni, Loretta, Pierluigi Vellucci, and Maurizio Naldi. 2018. Co-existence of stochastic and chaotic behaviour in the copper price time series. Resources Policy 58: 295–302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Mastroeni, Loretta, Pierluigi Vellucci, and Maurizio Naldi. 2019. A reappraisal of the chaotic paradigm for energy commodity prices. Energy Economics 82: 167–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Packard, Norman H., James P. Crutchfield, J. Doyne Farmer, and Robert S. Shaw. 1980. Geometry from a time series. Physical Review Letters 45: 712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Petzold, Linda. 1983. Automatic selection of methods for solving stiff and nonstiff systems of ordinary differential equations. SIAM Journal on Scientific and Statistical Computing 4: 136–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Rivero, Jorge Andres, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2022. A solution for the greedy approximation of a step function with a waveform dictionary. Communications in Nonlinear Science and Numerical Simulation 116: 106890. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Rogers, Leonard C. G., and David Williams. 2000. Diffusions, Markov Processes, and Martingales: Volume 1, Foundations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, vol. 1. [Google Scholar]
  26. Sun, Xiaotian, Wei Fang, Xiangyun Gao, Sufang An, Tao Wu, and Shuai Ren. 2022. Nonlinear dynamical analysis of metal futures price fluctuations: A recurrence quantification analysis approach. Applied Economics, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Takens, Floris. 1981. Detecting strange attractors in turbulence. In Dynamical Systems and Turbulence, Warwick 1980. Berlin/Heidelberg: Springer, pp. 366–81. [Google Scholar]
  28. Tilton, John E., and Gustavo Lagos. 2007. Assessing the long-run availability of copper. Resources Policy 32: 19–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Wiener, Norbert. 1949. Extrapolation, Interpolation, and Smoothing of Stationary Time Series: With Engineering Applications. Cambridge: MIT Press, vol. 113. [Google Scholar]
  30. Yu, Hui, Yinghui Ding, Qingru Sun, Xiangyun Gao, Xiaoliang Jia, Xinya Wang, and Sui Guo. 2021. Multi-scale comovement of the dynamic correlations between copper futures and spot prices. Resources Policy 70: 101913. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Zheng, Shuxian, Zhanglu Tan, Wanli Xing, Xuanru Zhou, Pei Zhao, Xiuqi Yin, and Han Hu. 2022. A comparative exploration of the chaotic characteristics of Chinese and international copper futures prices. Resources Policy 78: 102790. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Linear time-variant system, S.
Figure 1. Linear time-variant system, S.
Risks 10 00218 g001
Figure 2. Temporal behavior of intraday prices P ( t ) t = 1 n .
Figure 2. Temporal behavior of intraday prices P ( t ) t = 1 n .
Risks 10 00218 g002
Figure 3. Temporal behavior of logarithmic returns { p ( t ) } t = 1 n 1 .
Figure 3. Temporal behavior of logarithmic returns { p ( t ) } t = 1 n 1 .
Risks 10 00218 g003
Figure 4. Distribution of intraday observations by day.
Figure 4. Distribution of intraday observations by day.
Risks 10 00218 g004
Figure 5. Autocorrelation of the intraday futures log returns, from 28 April 2022 to 18 May 2022.
Figure 5. Autocorrelation of the intraday futures log returns, from 28 April 2022 to 18 May 2022.
Risks 10 00218 g005
Figure 6. Autocorrelation of the artificial time series (69).
Figure 6. Autocorrelation of the artificial time series (69).
Risks 10 00218 g006
Figure 7. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the artificial data (69). On the left: the entire temporal range. On the right: the first 25 time steps.
Figure 7. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the artificial data (69). On the left: the entire temporal range. On the right: the first 25 time steps.
Risks 10 00218 g007
Figure 8. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the copper price data. Temporal ranges: (i) on the left and (ii) on the right.
Figure 8. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the copper price data. Temporal ranges: (i) on the left and (ii) on the right.
Risks 10 00218 g008
Figure 9. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the copper price data. Temporal ranges: (iii) on the left and (iv) on the right.
Figure 9. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the copper price data. Temporal ranges: (iii) on the left and (iv) on the right.
Risks 10 00218 g009
Figure 10. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the copper price data. Temporal ranges: (v) on the left, (vi) on the right and (vii) below.
Figure 10. Price trajectories generated by the model (54) vs. the copper price data. Temporal ranges: (v) on the left, (vi) on the right and (vii) below.
Risks 10 00218 g010
Table 1. Characterization of the log returns of copper for different time ranges.
Table 1. Characterization of the log returns of copper for different time ranges.
RangeStandard DeviationDeterminism r opt
(i)0.000024679580.216374314.96101
(ii)0.00001708622018.56718
(iii)0.000046684790.368421118.03019
(iv)0.000015764870.464912315.72518
(v)0.00001830713021.52263
(vi)0.000022188240.485074617.27463
(vii)0.00002092907028.45987
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Mastroeni, L.; Vellucci, P. Construction of an SDE Model from Intraday Copper Futures Prices. Risks 2022, 10, 218. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110218

AMA Style

Mastroeni L, Vellucci P. Construction of an SDE Model from Intraday Copper Futures Prices. Risks. 2022; 10(11):218. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110218

Chicago/Turabian Style

Mastroeni, Loretta, and Pierluigi Vellucci. 2022. "Construction of an SDE Model from Intraday Copper Futures Prices" Risks 10, no. 11: 218. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110218

APA Style

Mastroeni, L., & Vellucci, P. (2022). Construction of an SDE Model from Intraday Copper Futures Prices. Risks, 10(11), 218. https://doi.org/10.3390/risks10110218

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop