Weighted Majority Voting Games

A special issue of Games (ISSN 2073-4336). This special issue belongs to the section "Cooperative Game Theory and Bargaining".

Deadline for manuscript submissions: closed (25 January 2022) | Viewed by 33510

Special Issue Editor


E-Mail Website
Guest Editor
School of Economics, University of Nottingham, University Park, Nottingham, UK
Interests: bargaining; weighted majority voting; power measures; fairness; social preferences; strategic information transmission; behavioural economics

Special Issue Information

Dear colleagues, 

The study of weighted majority voting games is important in understanding decision making in collective bodies such as the IMF, the EU Council of Ministers, and parliaments with disciplined political parties. In some of these bodies, the entire distribution of weights is chosen by design, while in others, it is the result not of planning but of citizens voting in an election. This Special Issue of Games will gather research on theory and applications of weighted majority voting. Relevant topics include, but are not limited to:

_ Government formation

_ Power measures

_ Specific classes of weighted majority games; enumeration

_ Noncooperative models of bargaining in weighted majority games

_ Cooperative solution concepts for weighted majority games

_ Modelling of voting in the EU

_ Optimal design of voting systems

_ Experimental research on weighted majority voting

Prof. Dr. Maria Montero
Guest Editor

Manuscript Submission Information

Manuscripts should be submitted online at www.mdpi.com by registering and logging in to this website. Once you are registered, click here to go to the submission form. Manuscripts can be submitted until the deadline. All submissions that pass pre-check are peer-reviewed. Accepted papers will be published continuously in the journal (as soon as accepted) and will be listed together on the special issue website. Research articles, review articles as well as short communications are invited. For planned papers, a title and short abstract (about 100 words) can be sent to the Editorial Office for announcement on this website.

Submitted manuscripts should not have been published previously, nor be under consideration for publication elsewhere (except conference proceedings papers). All manuscripts are thoroughly refereed through a single-blind peer-review process. A guide for authors and other relevant information for submission of manuscripts is available on the Instructions for Authors page. Games is an international peer-reviewed open access semimonthly journal published by MDPI.

Please visit the Instructions for Authors page before submitting a manuscript. The Article Processing Charge (APC) for publication in this open access journal is 1600 CHF (Swiss Francs). Submitted papers should be well formatted and use good English. Authors may use MDPI's English editing service prior to publication or during author revisions.

Keywords

  • weighted majority voting
  • government formation
  • power measures
  • voting paradoxes
  • bargaining
  • fairness
  • experiments
  • EU Council of Ministers

Benefits of Publishing in a Special Issue

  • Ease of navigation: Grouping papers by topic helps scholars navigate broad scope journals more efficiently.
  • Greater discoverability: Special Issues support the reach and impact of scientific research. Articles in Special Issues are more discoverable and cited more frequently.
  • Expansion of research network: Special Issues facilitate connections among authors, fostering scientific collaborations.
  • External promotion: Articles in Special Issues are often promoted through the journal's social media, increasing their visibility.
  • e-Book format: Special Issues with more than 10 articles can be published as dedicated e-books, ensuring wide and rapid dissemination.

Further information on MDPI's Special Issue polices can be found here.

Published Papers (11 papers)

Order results
Result details
Select all
Export citation of selected articles as:

Research

8 pages, 255 KiB  
Article
A Note on Time Inconsistency and Endogenous Exits from a Currency Union
by Yuta Saito
Games 2022, 13(2), 21; https://doi.org/10.3390/g13020021 - 23 Feb 2022
Viewed by 2380
Abstract
This paper investigates the effects of members’ exits from a currency union on the credibility of the common currency. In our currency union model, the inflation rate of the common currency is determined by majority voting among N member countries that are heterogeneous [...] Read more.
This paper investigates the effects of members’ exits from a currency union on the credibility of the common currency. In our currency union model, the inflation rate of the common currency is determined by majority voting among N member countries that are heterogeneous with respect to their output shocks. Once an inflation rate of the common currency has been selected, each member decides whether to remain in the currency union or not. If a member decides to exit, it has to pay a fixed social cost and individually chooses the inflation rate of its currency. Unlike previous research on this topic, we focus on the possibility of achieving an optimal outcome, which generates no inflation bias, when more than one member is expected to leave the currency union. We show that the optimal outcome can only be achieved if no members leave the currency union. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
25 pages, 307 KiB  
Article
Exits from the European Union and Their Effect on Power Distribution in the Council
by Dóra Gréta Petróczy, Mark Francis Rogers and László Á. Kóczy
Games 2022, 13(1), 18; https://doi.org/10.3390/g13010018 - 7 Feb 2022
Viewed by 3362
Abstract
Debates on an EU-leaving referendum arose in several member states after Brexit. We want to highlight how the exit of an additional country affects the power distribution in the Council of the European Union. We inspect the power indices of the member states [...] Read more.
Debates on an EU-leaving referendum arose in several member states after Brexit. We want to highlight how the exit of an additional country affects the power distribution in the Council of the European Union. We inspect the power indices of the member states both with and without the country which might leave the union. Our results show a pattern connected to a change in the number of states required to meet the 55% threshold. An exit that modifies this number benefits the countries with high population, while an exit that does not cause such a change benefits the small member states. According to our calculations, only the exit of Poland would be supported by the qualified majority of the Council. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

25 pages, 1819 KiB  
Article
Gender and Nominal Power in Multilateral Bargaining
by Nicola Maaser, Fabian Paetzel and Stefan Traub
Games 2022, 13(1), 11; https://doi.org/10.3390/g13010011 - 17 Jan 2022
Viewed by 2861
Abstract
In many bargaining situations, the distribution of seats or voting weights does not accurately reflect bargaining power. Maaser, Paetzel and Traub (Games and Economic Behavior, 2019) conducted an experiment to investigate the effect of such nominal power differences in the classic Baron–Ferejohn model. [...] Read more.
In many bargaining situations, the distribution of seats or voting weights does not accurately reflect bargaining power. Maaser, Paetzel and Traub (Games and Economic Behavior, 2019) conducted an experiment to investigate the effect of such nominal power differences in the classic Baron–Ferejohn model. This paper re-analyzes the data from that experiment, looking at gender differences in bargaining behavior and in the effect of nominal weights. We find that women and men differ in particular with respect to the proposed distribution of payoffs and coalition size. By contrast, nominal weights have only minor gender-specific effects. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

17 pages, 341 KiB  
Article
Dynamic Programming for Computing Power Indices for Weighted Voting Games with Precoalitions
by Jochen Staudacher, Felix Wagner and Jan Filipp
Games 2022, 13(1), 6; https://doi.org/10.3390/g13010006 - 26 Dec 2021
Cited by 3 | Viewed by 3021
Abstract
We study the efficient computation of power indices for weighted voting games with precoalitions amongst subsets of players (reflecting, e.g., ideological proximity) using the paradigm of dynamic programming. Starting from the state-of-the-art algorithms for computing the Banzhaf and Shapley–Shubik indices for weighted voting [...] Read more.
We study the efficient computation of power indices for weighted voting games with precoalitions amongst subsets of players (reflecting, e.g., ideological proximity) using the paradigm of dynamic programming. Starting from the state-of-the-art algorithms for computing the Banzhaf and Shapley–Shubik indices for weighted voting games, we present a framework for fast algorithms for the three most common power indices with precoalitions, i.e., the Owen index, the Banzhaf–Owen index and the symmetric coalitional Banzhaf index, and point out why our new algorithms are applicable for large numbers of players. We discuss implementations of our algorithms for the three power indices with precoalitions in C++ and review computing times, as well as storage requirements. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Graphical abstract

17 pages, 324 KiB  
Article
An Adaptive Model of Demand Adjustment in Weighted Majority Games
by Maria Montero and Alex Possajennikov
Games 2022, 13(1), 5; https://doi.org/10.3390/g13010005 - 26 Dec 2021
Cited by 1 | Viewed by 2617
Abstract
This paper presents a simple adaptive model of demand adjustment in cooperative games and analyzes this model in weighted majority games. In the model, a randomly chosen player sets her demand to the highest possible value subject to the demands of other coalition [...] Read more.
This paper presents a simple adaptive model of demand adjustment in cooperative games and analyzes this model in weighted majority games. In the model, a randomly chosen player sets her demand to the highest possible value subject to the demands of other coalition members being satisfied. This basic process converges to the aspiration set. By introducing some perturbations into the process, we show that the set of separating aspirations, i.e., demand vectors in which no player is indispensable in order for other players to achieve their demands, is the one most resistant to mutations. We then apply the process to weighted majority games. We show that in symmetric majority games and in apex games, the unique separating aspiration is the unique stochastically stable one. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
17 pages, 2136 KiB  
Article
Weighted Scoring Committees
by Alexander Mayer and Stefan Napel
Games 2021, 12(4), 94; https://doi.org/10.3390/g12040094 - 14 Dec 2021
Cited by 1 | Viewed by 2239
Abstract
Weighted committees allow shareholders, party leaders, etc. to wield different numbers of votes or voting weights as they decide between multiple candidates by a given social choice method. We consider committees that apply scoring methods such as plurality, Borda, or antiplurality rule. Many [...] Read more.
Weighted committees allow shareholders, party leaders, etc. to wield different numbers of votes or voting weights as they decide between multiple candidates by a given social choice method. We consider committees that apply scoring methods such as plurality, Borda, or antiplurality rule. Many different weights induce the same mapping from committee members’ preferences to winning candidates. The numbers of respective weight equivalence classes and hence of structurally distinct plurality committees, Borda commitees, etc. differ widely. There are 6, 51, and 5 plurality, Borda, and antiplurality committees, respectively, if three players choose between three candidates and up to 163 (229) committees for scoring rules in between plurality and Borda (Borda and antiplurality). A key implication is that plurality, Borda, and antiplurality rule are much less sensitive to weight changes than other scoring rules. We illustrate the geometry of weight equivalence classes, with a map of all Borda classes, and identify minimal integer representations. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

25 pages, 352 KiB  
Article
A Disproportionality Bias in the Bureau of the Regional Assembly of Madrid
by Omar de la Cruz Vicente, Fernando Tomé Bermejo and Rafael Ramiro Moreno
Games 2021, 12(4), 92; https://doi.org/10.3390/g12040092 - 7 Dec 2021
Viewed by 2759
Abstract
This paper analyses the voting behavior of the parliamentary groups in the Regional Assembly of Madrid to appoint the Bureau, its representative body, in all the legislatures since its inception (1983–2021). To this end, the actual result of the voting is compared with [...] Read more.
This paper analyses the voting behavior of the parliamentary groups in the Regional Assembly of Madrid to appoint the Bureau, its representative body, in all the legislatures since its inception (1983–2021). To this end, the actual result of the voting is compared with the mock result attained by following a Nash equilibrium (NE) and a d’Hondt (d’H) allocation in each vote. But the result of a d’Hondt allocation varies based on the number of stages in which the voting is performed (President, Vice-President, and Secretaries), so a bias towards disproportionality could exist as measured by the absolute index of disproportionality which calculates the number of seats non-proportionally allocated. The results show that, in view of the hypothesis on the importance of the number of seats, the NE was only followed in four of the 12 Legislatures for Vice-Presidents (it was always followed for Secretaries). Thus, parliamentary groups could gain more seats by modifying their strategies. Additionally, the absolute rate of disproportionality and the number of seats non-proportionally allocated indicate that, in general, parliamentary groups obtain voting results that are less disproportionate than they could be (due to the number of voting stages). Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
25 pages, 432 KiB  
Article
On Weights and Quotas for Weighted Majority Voting Games
by Xavier Molinero, Maria Serna and Marc Taberner-Ortiz
Games 2021, 12(4), 91; https://doi.org/10.3390/g12040091 - 6 Dec 2021
Cited by 1 | Viewed by 3266
Abstract
In this paper, we analyze the frequency distributions of weights and quotas in weighted majority voting games (WMVG) up to eight players. We also show different procedures that allow us to obtain some minimum or minimum sum representations of WMVG, for any desired [...] Read more.
In this paper, we analyze the frequency distributions of weights and quotas in weighted majority voting games (WMVG) up to eight players. We also show different procedures that allow us to obtain some minimum or minimum sum representations of WMVG, for any desired number of players, starting from a minimum or minimum sum representation. We also provide closed formulas for the number of WMVG with n players having a minimum representation with quota up to three, and some subclasses of this family of games. Finally, we complement these results with some upper bounds related to weights and quotas. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

10 pages, 340 KiB  
Article
The Number of Parties and Decision-Making in Legislatures
by Marina Bannikova, Artyom Jelnov and Pavel Jelnov
Games 2021, 12(4), 76; https://doi.org/10.3390/g12040076 - 12 Oct 2021
Viewed by 2735
Abstract
This paper proposes a model of a legislature, formed by several parties, which has to vote for or against a certain bill in the presence of a lobbyist interested in a certain vote outcome. We show that the ease with which the lobbyist [...] Read more.
This paper proposes a model of a legislature, formed by several parties, which has to vote for or against a certain bill in the presence of a lobbyist interested in a certain vote outcome. We show that the ease with which the lobbyist can manipulate a legislature decision increases with the number of elected parties, and, consequently, decreases with an electoral threshold. On the other hand, a lower electoral threshold increases the representativeness of a legislature. We combine these two effects in a notion of fairness. We show the existence of an electoral threshold that optimizes the fairness of a political system, which is close to 1–5%. Namely, the optimal threshold (in our sense) is close to thresholds that exist in most parliamentary democracies. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

18 pages, 2581 KiB  
Article
Simple Voting Games and Cartel Damage Proportioning
by Stefan Napel and Dominik Welter
Games 2021, 12(4), 74; https://doi.org/10.3390/g12040074 - 1 Oct 2021
Cited by 3 | Viewed by 2807
Abstract
Individual contributions by infringing firms to the compensation of cartel victims must reflect their “relative responsibility for the harm caused” according to EU legislation. Several studies have argued that the theoretically best way to operationalize this norm is to apply the Shapley value [...] Read more.
Individual contributions by infringing firms to the compensation of cartel victims must reflect their “relative responsibility for the harm caused” according to EU legislation. Several studies have argued that the theoretically best way to operationalize this norm is to apply the Shapley value to an equilibrium model of cartel prices. Because calibrating such a model is demanding, legal practitioners prefer workarounds based on market shares. Relative sales, revenues, and profits however fail to reflect causal links between individual behavior and prices. We develop a pragmatic alternative: use simple voting games to describe which cartel configurations can(not) cause significant price increases in an approximate, dichotomous way; then compute the Shapley-Shubik index. Simulations for a variety of market scenarios document that this captures relative responsibility better than market share heuristics can. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

10 pages, 819 KiB  
Article
Brexit and Power in the Council of the European Union
by László Á. Kóczy
Games 2021, 12(2), 51; https://doi.org/10.3390/g12020051 - 21 Jun 2021
Cited by 7 | Viewed by 3764
Abstract
The exit of the United Kingdom from the European Union has had profound economic and political effects. Here, we look at a particular aspect, the power distribution in the Council of the European Union. Using the Shapley–Shubik power index, we calculate the member [...] Read more.
The exit of the United Kingdom from the European Union has had profound economic and political effects. Here, we look at a particular aspect, the power distribution in the Council of the European Union. Using the Shapley–Shubik power index, we calculate the member states’ powers with and without the United Kingdom and update earlier power forecasts using the Eurostat’s latest population projections. There is a remarkably sharp relation between population size and the change in power: Brexit increases the largest members’ powers while decreasing the smallest ones’ powers. Full article
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Weighted Majority Voting Games)
Show Figures

Figure 1

Back to TopTop