Next Article in Journal
Systematic Literature Review of the Take-Home Route of Pesticide Exposure via Biomonitoring and Environmental Monitoring
Next Article in Special Issue
Identifying the Driving Factors of Black Bloom in Lake Bay through Bayesian LASSO
Previous Article in Journal
Water-Use Characteristics and Physiological Response of Moso Bamboo to Flash Droughts
Previous Article in Special Issue
A Nonlinear Inexact Two-Stage Management Model for Agricultural Water Allocation under Uncertainty Based on the Heihe River Water Diversion Plan
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Pricing Model for Groundwater Rights in Ningxia, China Based on the Fuzzy Mathematical Model

Business School, Hohai University, Nanjing 211100, China
*
Authors to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16(12), 2176; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph16122176
Submission received: 19 May 2019 / Revised: 15 June 2019 / Accepted: 18 June 2019 / Published: 19 June 2019
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Water Resources Systems Quality and Quantity Management)

Abstract

:
To reduce groundwater overexploitation and alleviate water shortages, market mechanisms are introduced to allocate water rights. Scientific and reasonable pricing of groundwater rights is key to ensuring the effectiveness of the groundwater market. Because of the complexity and uncertainty of water resources, this study calculates the price of groundwater rights based on the value of water resources with an evaluation indicator system. The system includes 14 indicators developed with a fuzzy mathematics model addressing three dimensions: environment, society, and economy. The weights of the indicators are determined through the analytic network process (ANP) and the entropy method. The results show that the price of groundwater rights in Ningxia, China increased from 5.11 yuan/m3 to 5.73 yuan/m3 between 2013 and 2017; this means the price was basically stable, with a slight increase. The ratio of residents’ water fee expenditures to real disposable income also remained essentially stable, fluctuating around 0.37%, far below the normal level. These data demonstrated that the current regional water price policy does not reflect the true value of groundwater resources; there is room to increase urban water prices. Local governments need speed up water price system reforms and adopt water rights systems to optimize water resource allocations.

1. Introduction

Due to the decrease of the total amount of water resources caused by the uncertainty of global climate change, water resources are becoming increasingly strained. Groundwater has become an important supplement to surface water, and is attracting more and more attention. China has always been faced with water shortage problems of varying degrees, and the growing large population and uneven distribution aggravates the water resources management dilemma [1,2]. According to the statics from the ministry of water resources of the People’s Republic of China (MWRPRC), the per capita availability of water in China ranked just 108th in the world, making it one of the 21 most water-scarce countries worldwide, and has only 25% of the world’s average level.
Northwest China relies heavily on groundwater. However, with continuous development, groundwater overexploitation and groundwater pollution are becoming the main factors restricting sustainable development. According to MWRPRC statistics, average annual groundwater overexploitation in China increased from 10 billion m3/a in the 1980s to 22.8 billion m3/a in the 2000s; the average area of groundwater overexploitation has expanded from 56,000 km2 to 180,000 km2 during the same period. The continuous expansion of groundwater exploitation has led to the formation of regional water level depression funnels and serious geological problems, such as salinization, land subsidence, ground fissures, and karst collapses [3].
For example, Ningxia, a province located in the arid area of Northwest China, is suffering problems caused by groundwater overexploitation. According to the Ningxia Water Resources Bulletin, in 2017, there were five groundwater overexploitation areas in Ningxia, with total area of 741 km2. Specifically, Yinchuan City has one overexploitation area of 294 km2 and Shizuishan City has four overexploitation areas with a total area of 447 km2. The total groundwater overexploitation in Ningxia is 28.38 million m3. The average groundwater depth has increased by about 1 m compared with the level in 1980, and the consequent geological disasters such as land subsidence and karst collapses have caused serious economic losses and social crises. These have directly or indirectly restricted the sustainable development of regional economies. The effective allocation and rational use of groundwater resources is critical to harmoniously unify ecological and social development.
In order to control overexploitation, the government has implemented legislation such as the Water Law of PRC, Regulations on Administration of Water Abstraction Licensing and Collection of Water Resources Charges, Regulations on the Development and Utilization of Urban Groundwater and the Law on the Prevention and Control of Water Pollution. The contents of these laws and regulations mainly include the following aspects: First, delimit the groundwater overexploitation area. Second, strictly control the groundwater exploitation. Third, strengthen well management in groundwater overexploitation areas. Fourth, artificially recharge groundwater.
Although the legislation has reduced groundwater overexploitation to a certain extent, it has little effect on the low efficiency of groundwater utilization. A new method of water resources allocation needs to be introduced. Water trading markets is a good way to improve the efficiency of water resources [4,5,6,7,8], which will be helpful to promote the areas of low utilization rate of groundwater flowing to the areas with high utilization rate of groundwater [9,10]. For this reason, China, Australia, and South Asia have some kind of groundwater trading markets [11,12,13,14,15]. However, compared with the increasingly mature and perfect surface water market in these areas [16], the incompleteness of groundwater price mechanism restricts the effectiveness of the groundwater market [17]. Scientific and reasonable groundwater pricing urgently needs to be studied for the optimization of allocating groundwater resources [18].
There are many classical surface water pricing methods, such as the shadow price method [19], the supply and demand price model [20], cost pricing method [21], real option method [22], game method [23], and principal-agent method [24]. Many pricing factors have been proposed for water rights, including resource utilization efficiency and cost [25], ecological sustainability [26], seasonality [27], and water users and market [28]. However, these achievements cannot be directly applied to groundwater pricing, because of the difficulty of transporting groundwater resources across regions [29] and the complexity of groundwater recharge compared with surface water [30], which makes it difficult to use conventional mathematical models in pricing. In addition, current studies on groundwater rights pricing method consider just one single factor [31,32,33,34], ignoring the fact that the pricing of groundwater rights is a complex system of interactions and couplings between natural systems, economic systems, and social systems.
To fill these gaps, we propose a scientific and feasible pricing method for groundwater using fuzzy mathematics [35,36,37,38,39]. This paper uses fuzzy mathematics combined with the analytic network process (ANP) and entropy method to estimate the fuzzy value of groundwater rights, which is multiplied with the price vector in the price calculation model to obtain the groundwater rights price. It is worth mentioning that unlike the traditional method, this study selects environment, society, and economy as the pricing indicators and calculates each indicator’s weight. As a result, the study generates dynamic trends of groundwater rights pricing in Ningxia from 2013 to 2017 which is conducive to improving the utilization efficiency of groundwater and the sustainable development of water resources in China. This paper is organized into four parts. Section 1 is the introduction. In Section 2, the materials and methods are introduced, including the research area and the pricing method. Section 3 details the statistical data, the calculation results of the model, and a discussion of the groundwater rights price. Finally, the conclusions are provided in Section 4.

2. Materials and Methods

2.1. Research Area

Ningxia is short for Ningxia Hui Autonomous Region, which is located in the middle and upper reaches of the Yellow River in northwest China (35°14′N–39°23′N, 104°17′E–107°39′E) and adjacent to Gansu Province, Inner Mongolia Autonomous Region, and Shaanxi Province. The northern part belongs to the Inner Mongolia Plateau, surrounded by the Tenggeli, Ulanbuhe, and Maowusu deserts. The southern part belongs to the Loess Plateau. The total area of the region is 664,400 km2, and it has five prefecture-level cities. In 2017, the permanent population was 681,790. Figure 1 shows a location and regional map of Ningxia [40]. The per capita GDP of Ningxia in 2017 was 50,765 yuan, ranking 15th of all the provinces in China. Ningxia’s economy is very extensive and its water use efficiency is very low. In 2017, the per 104-yuan-GDP water consumption is 191.95 m3, ranking 4th of all the provinces in China.
Ningxia province is one of China’s provinces with the most significant water resource shortages, which hinders the further development of the local economy. In 2017, the total annual precipitation for Ningxia was 332 mm, which was 17.177 billion m3 in terms of total precipitation (ranking 3rd from the bottom). Ningxia’s total water resources were quantified at 1.077 billion m3 (ranking last). Of all the water resources, surface water resource quantities accounted for 865.3 million m3 (ranking last), groundwater resource quantities were 1.933 billion m3 (ranking 3rd from the bottom), the double counting amount between surface water and groundwater was 1.721 billion m3, and total water consumption was 6.606 billion m3. Table 1 lists the groundwater resources in Ningxia according to “Ningxia Water Resources Bulletin 2017” [41]. The data are estimates from the Ningxia Water Conservancy based on the groundwater hydrological data measured at monitoring stations.
The shortage of groundwater sources in Ningxia has seriously affected local development, calling for attention of both the government and the general public. Therefore, how to improve the utilization efficiency of groundwater in Ningxia and reduce overexploitation are the key problems. However, at present, most of the research on the water resource governance in Ningxia focuses on fields such as water distribution [42,43], benefits of water rights transfer [44], and water resources sustainable utilization [45]. However, there is a lack of research on groundwater rights pricing. As a result, the water price is unscientific and the government’s pricing policy lacks appropriate support. Therefore, to develop a reasonable pricing scheme for water resources by drawing on the existing Ningxia water rights trading market is the focus of this paper. Our findings might be helpful for other similar provinces.

2.2. Data Sources

Based on data operability and availability, the data used in this study were derived from the “Ningxia Water Resources Bulletin 2013–2017” [41], “Ningxia Statistical Yearbook 2013–2017” [46], “Ningxia Autonomous Region Statistical Bulletin of National Economic and Social Development 2013–2017” [47], “Monthly Report of Groundwater Regime in China January 2013–December 2017” [48], and “China Tap Water Price 2013–2017” [49].

2.3. Methods

Groundwater rights are defined as the property rights associated with groundwater resources. As demonstrated above, a reasonable price for groundwater rights should be based on the value of groundwater resources in the government-led primary market. This value can be measured by a fuzzy synthetic evaluation model. The model used in this study to quantitatively evaluate the price of groundwater rights in Ningxia can be divided into two parts: the groundwater rights fuzzy evaluation model and the price calculation model. In the groundwater rights fuzzy evaluation model, we calculate the fuzzy value of groundwater rights, which is combined with the price vector to calculate the price.

2.3.1. Groundwater Rights Fuzzy Evaluation Model

In this model, the fuzzy value is estimated with the synthetic weight vector of pricing indicators and the evaluation matrix. The first step is to select pricing factors. This paper proposes three kinds of factors: environment, society, and economy. The fuzzy value of groundwater is expressed in the following equation:
V = f ( X 1 , X 2 , X 3 , , X n )
where V is the value of groundwater rights and X 1 , X 2 , X 3 , , X n are the selected indicators characterizing the factors affecting the value of groundwater rights. The selection of pricing indicators affects the effectiveness of groundwater rights price. A reasonable price for groundwater rights need have three main functions [50]:
  • Save groundwater resources and improve the utilization rate of groundwater resources
  • Protect groundwater resources and the water environment
  • Encourage different funds to invest in groundwater resources’ development, utilization, allocation, conservation, and protection.
Based on this, referring to relevant experience related to water rights pricing [51], indicator selection should consider the following principles:
(1)
Sustainable development. Scientific and reasonable prices should coordinate the interests of governments, enterprises, and water users; coordinate ecological, economic, and social benefits; coordinate contemporary and future generation benefits; and ultimately realize the fairness and sustainability of water resources utilization in space and time.
(2)
Efficient utilization. The insufficient supply of groundwater makes it difficult to meet all needs. Therefore, from the economic perspective, we should pursue the best use of water under the guidance of price tools. This allows groundwater to be allocated to places with high utilization efficiency and to create more value. This involves striving to maximize the utilization of groundwater resources.
(3)
Fairness. Water resources are necessary for human production and life. As such, it is necessary to ensure the basic needs of all people, to ensure the fair allocation of groundwater in different regions and across different industries and groups. It is particularly important to ensure the water rights of vulnerable groups.
The selection of indicators is detailed in Section 3.1. After the factors are determined, the domain U is set for the groundwater pricing indicators. The U domain is expressed by Equation (2).
M = { X 1 , X 2 , X 3 , , X n }
This equation means that the domain of the model is the pricing indicators of groundwater rights. The evaluation vector of pricing indicators is shown in Equation (3):
H = { H i g h ,   R e l a t i v e l y   H i g h , C o m m o n ,   R e l a t i v e l y   L o w ,   L o w }
where H is the evaluation vector. This equation means that all the pricing indicators are evaluated into five grades. Equations (2) and (3) are used as presupposition. By setting the synthetic weight vector and the evaluation matrix of pricing indicators, Equation (1) is transformed into Equation (4):
V = W·R
The fuzzy value of groundwater rights can be estimated by this equation. In this formula, V is the value of groundwater rights; W is the synthetic weight vector of pricing indicators; and R is the evaluation matrix, shown as Equation (5):
R = | R 1 R 2 R 3 R n | = [ r 11 r 12 r 13 r 14 r 15 r 21 r 22 r 23 r 24 r 25 r 31 r 32 r 33 r 34 r 35 r n 1 r n 2 r n 3 r n 4 r n 5 ]
In this expression, r i j ( i = 1 ,   2 ,   3 , ,   n ;   j = 1 ,   2 ,   3 ,   4 ,   5 ) is the membership degree of indicator i to evaluation factor grade j . This study chose the ascending (descending) semitrapezoidal distribution and established a linear membership function [52] to calculate the membership degree of each indicator in matrix R to different evaluation grades in vector H. That is,
When   j = 1 ,
r i 1 = { 1 x i x i 1 x i 2 x i x i 2 x i 1 x i 1 < x i < x i 2 0 x i x i 2
When j = 2 ,   3 ,   4 ,
r i j = { 0 x i x i , j 1 x i x i , j 1 x i , j 1 x i , j x i , j 1 < x i < x i j x i , j + 1 x i x i , j + 1 x i , j x i , j < x i < x i , j + 1 0 x i x i , j + 1
When j = 5 ,
r i 5 = { 0 x i x i 4 x i x i 4 x i 5 x i 4 x i 4 < x i < x i 5 1 x i x i 5
where x i is the actual value of evaluation indicator i , and x i , j 1 , x i , j , x i , j + 1 is the criterion value of the two adjacent levels of the evaluation indicator. With Equations (6)–(8), the evaluation matrix R is calculated. To achieve the value of groundwater rights, the next step is to calculate the synthetic weight vector of indicators (W) according to Equation (4). The calculation process is detailed in Section 2.3.2.

2.3.2. Factor Weights Calculation Method

Based on the importance of each evaluation indicator, a corresponding weight is assigned. ANP is a commonly used decision-making tool. The weight of the model is obtained by comparing the factors in pairs, combining the comparison results with fuzzy mathematics, and constructing a hyper matrix [53]. Considering the interlocking interaction between pricing factors, ANP is a suitable tool. However, the ANP model is easily influenced by researcher subjectivity, leading to errors in the results. Therefore, the ANP model is often combined with an entropy weight method, and objective coefficients are introduced to modify the results [54,55]. In this paper, the synthetic weights are also obtained by combining these two models.
The ANP model works by constructing supermatrices. With the software “Super Decisions”, the supermatrices can be constructed by the following steps:
(1)
According to the network hierarchy, the pricing indicators were compared pairwise. Setting a certain indicator as the criterion, the relative influence intensity of the other elements influencing the indicator was evaluated. Generally, the magnitude of influence was expressed with the numbers from 1 to 9.
(2)
Construct the unweighted supermatrix. The element in the matrix, for example, ω ij , was the degree of influence of the element i on the element j.
(3)
Similarly, the influence vectors between clusters were obtained by comparing two clusters with each other. The unweighted supermatrix was multiplied by the corresponding weight to obtain the weighted supermatrix. The power operation was applied to the weighted supermatrix, so that the power exponent tended to infinity. When every column element no longer changed, the limit matrix was obtained. The limit matrix shows the quantitative influence of all the indicators on the price, namely, the weights of indicators.
As mentioned above, this result is so subjective that it needs to be combined with the result of the entropy weight method. The indicator initial value matrix was set as U, in which the element μij represented the initial number value of indicator i for item j. Based on matrix U, another weight was calculated with the entropy method through the following steps:
(1)
Data standardization. This paper used 0-1 standardization. The formula is:
μ i j = { μ i j m i n ( μ i j ) max ( μ i j ) m i n ( μ i j ) , μ i j   i s   p o s i t i v e max ( μ i j ) μ i j max ( μ i j ) m i n ( μ i j ) , μ i j   i s   n e g a t i v e
where μ i j is the element of matrix U, and μ i j is the standardized element corresponding to μ i j .
(2)
Data normalization. The formula is:
d i j = μ i j i = 1 n j = 1 m μ i j
where d i j is the normalized element corresponding to μ i j n is the total of the indicators; and m is the total of items in the research.
(3)
Calculate the entropy of each indicator. The entropy of indicator i is calculated as Equation (11)–(12).
E i = 1 l n m j = 1 m 1 + d i j j = 1 m ( 1 + d i j ) l n [ 1 + d i j j = 1 m ( 1 + d i j ) ]
h i = 1 E i i = 1 n ( 1 E i )
where h i is the entropy and weight of indicator i.
The synthetic weight of indicator is calculated with these two weights. Specifically, setting the weight derived from ANP model as the subjective weight of indicator i, with the entropy of indicator i as the objective weight, a synthetic weight of indicator i can be obtained with Equation (13) [56]:
ω i = ω 1 i ω 2 i i = 1 n ω 1 i ω 2 i
where ω 1 i is the subjective weight, ω 2 i is the objective weight ( ω 2 i = h i ) , and ω i is the synthetic weight of indicator i. with the evaluation matrix R and the synthetic weight vector W formed with ω i , the value of groundwater rights V is calculated.

2.3.3. Price Calculation Model

The next step is to determine the price vector, which is usually obtained by equally dividing the range of water prices corresponding to the evaluation grades, based on the actual situation. The lower limit of groundwater price is 0, and the upper limit of groundwater price is affordability for water users. Traditionally, the affordability for water users is calculated based on the proportion of an urban resident’s living water expenditure to their income. This is called the water rate affordability index [57]. Similarly, the affordability is calculated as Equation (14):
P = A × E / Q C D T
In this formula, P is the upper limit of groundwater price; A is the water rate affordability indicator; E is the per capita disposable income of residents; Q is the annual per capita water consumption (In fact, per capita water requirement is better. However, it is difficult to accurately quantify the per capita water requirement due to the difference of water resources endowment and water use habits in subordinate regions. Referring to similar literature, this paper selects per capita water consumption as an alternative); C is the water supply cost and normal profit; D is the sewage treatment fee; and T is the water resource fee. This fee is charged in China due to the scarcity of water resources and the upfront protection input of the government. This study selected price affordability as a key factor, for which there is little difference between surface water and groundwater. As such, this equation does not distinguish between these two kinds of water resources. The water rate affordability index is usually set by researchers depending on the region being studied. Research by the World Bank shows that 5% is the maximum affordability index for developing countries. Most scholars believe that 3–5% is a reasonable ratio; as such, 3% is a realistic and feasible ratio for developing countries [58].
Also, the water rate affordability index can be evaluated with the proportion of water fee expenditure to per capita real disposable income, as expressed in Equation (15):
A = C W / A I
where A is the water rate affordability index; CW is the per capita water fee expenditure; and AI is the per capita real disposable income. The per capita disposable income excludes price effects. By comparing the calculated result with the set ratio, whether the current water rate is high or not can be judged.
Then, the groundwater rights price vector S is obtained as Equation (16):
S = [ P ,   0.75 P ,   0.5 P ,   0.25 P ,   0 ] T
This vector measures the affordability of groundwater rights prices. The five elements in the vector correspond to the five grades in the evaluation vector. Finally, the price of groundwater rights can be calculated by combining the fuzzy value V and the price vector S as Equation (17):
G P = ( 1 + α ) V · S ,
where, GP is the price of groundwater rights, S is the price vector, V is the value of groundwater rights, and “α” is a parameter reflecting government regulation. These include extra fees for highly polluted industries, prohibition of trade in groundwater reserves, and support for vulnerable industries such as agriculture.

3. Results and Discussion

3.1. Evaluation Indicators and Actual Value

Based on the principles in Section 2.3.1 and referring to studies on the evaluation of other resources by ANP [59,60,61], three kinds of indicators were selected for this study: environment, society, and economy. Data of all the indicators were obtained from the government bulletin in Section 2.2, which can be seen in Table 2.
Environmental indicators characterize factors associated with the groundwater environment. These indicators are critical, because one of the major objectives of water pricing is to protect the groundwater environment. Specifically, for groundwater resources, the main objective is to prevent pollution and reduce overexploitation. Groundwater quality grade, per capita groundwater resources, groundwater resources per unit area, average depth of shallow groundwater, and the proportion of overexploited groundwater area were selected as indicators to reflect the environmental factors impacting groundwater rights pricing. The groundwater quality grade is an indicator reflecting groundwater quality, defined based on Specification GB/T14848-2017, “Standard for Groundwater Quality”. The better the water quality is, the higher the water price is. Per capita groundwater resources and groundwater resources per unit area reflect the degree of regional scarcity in groundwater resources, from the perspectives of population and region. In areas with abundant groundwater resources, the price of water rights is low. Conversely, in areas where groundwater is relatively scarce, if groundwater rights are tradable (in certain areas, such as protected areas and reserved areas of groundwater, the policy may prohibit or restrict groundwater exploitation and groundwater right transactions. These areas were excluded from the scope of the study), the price of water rights is high. The average depth of shallow groundwater reflects the groundwater storage in plain areas. The deeper the average shallow groundwater depth is, the more difficult it is to exploit the groundwater. As a result, the price of groundwater rights is higher.
Social indicators characterize factors reflecting groundwater demand, and mainly include population and water withdrawal. Population density, per capita groundwater withdrawal, agricultural water withdrawal, industrial water withdrawal, and withdrawal for residential living use were selected as indicators to reflect the social factors impacting groundwater right pricing. Population density is an indicator reflecting the local population size. In general, the higher the population density is, the more water consumption there is, and the higher the water price is. The per capita groundwater withdrawal is an indicator reflecting the overall market demand. The larger per capita groundwater consumption will raise the demand for groundwater rights, which eventually leads the higher the price of groundwater rights. Therefore, agricultural groundwater withdrawal, industrial groundwater withdrawal, and the withdrawal of groundwater for residential living were selected to reflect groundwater demand of different industries.
Economic indicators characterize macroeconomic conditions that impact water prices. Per capita GDP, per 104-yuan-GDP water consumption, the proportion of the groundwater supply, and wastewater discharge were selected as indicators to reflect the economic factors impacting groundwater right prices. Per capita GDP is a common indicator reflecting regional economic level. The reason why we use this indicator is that could have a positive on groundwater price. In general, a higher regional economy will lead to an increase in per capita water consumption, which will be reflected in an increase of groundwater price. The per 104-yuan-GDP water consumption is an indicator reflecting the water use efficiency of regional economic sectors. Similar to per capita GDP, there is a positive correlation between water consumption and water price. If the value of water consumption per unit GDP is lower, the higher water use efficiency will decrease the groundwater price. The proportion of groundwater supply (groundwater supply/total water supply) reflects the degree of reliance on groundwater in the region, compared with surface water. The higher the proportion of groundwater supply is, the higher the price of groundwater rights is. Lastly, the wastewater discharge is an indicator reflecting the negative externality of the economy. It is worth noting that groundwater trade needs to account for environmental protection requirements. Hence, when the groundwater is used in industries with serious pollution, an additional price needs to be charged. Table 3 lists the indicators and the data.

3.2. Evaluation Criteria of Indicators

The evaluation criteria of groundwater rights value were divided into five grades as shown in Equation (3): High, Relatively High, Common, Relatively Low, and Low. All grades are qualified by referring to the annual average data of every provinces in China [62,63]. Specifically, the upper and lower limits are determined according to the annual average provincial data. Then, the criterion values can be calculated by the interval arithmetic method after the highest criterion and lowest criterion are set.
In addition, there is no quantitative statistics of the indicator “groundwater quality grade” in the bulletin, which means the provincial data of this indicator cannot be averaged. Thus, the evaluation criterion of this indicator had to be determined according to classification in the national standard of groundwater quality (Specification GB/T14848-2017, “Standard for Groundwater Quality”).
There are two kinds of indicators: positive indicators and negative indicators. For positive indicators, the bigger the number is, the higher the value it reflects. In contrast, for negative indicators, the greater the number is, the lower the value it reflects, and vice versa, as shown in Table 4.

3.3. The Network Structure and Weights

As mentioned above, according to the ANP model, the indicators form a network structure which makes the model more realistic than models such as AHP. Figure 2 shows the network structure associated with this research. Each node in the network represents a cluster of indicators. Considering that there is a certain correlation between each cluster of indicators, the change of each indicator may cause the change of another indicator. There are 3 clusters in the network: environment, society, and economy. Interactions are represented by “ ”, and “A→B” means that cluster (or factor) A is affected by the cluster (or element) B.
Based on this structure, the indicators are compared pairwise to obtain the subjective weights following the steps in Section 2.3.2. Then, the objective weights of all the indicators are calculated and combined with the entropy method according to Equations (9)–(12). In these equations, the values of parameters n and m in the equations are determined according to the set of this study: n is the total number of indicators and m is the total number of items, namely, n = 14 and m = 5. Table 5 shows the calculated result of the weights.
By combining these two weights, the synthetic weights are calculated as Equation (13). The synthetic weight vector W is:
W = [0.0255, 0.2583, 0.2030, 0.0150, 0.0107, 0.1317, 0.0191, 0.0502, 0.0281, 0.0056, 0.1765, 0.0782, 0.0044, 0.0190]

3.4. Fuzzy Synthetic Evaluation of Groundwater Rights Price

The evaluation matrix R is constructed from Equations (5)–(8). In addition, as the indicator “Groundwater quality grade” could not be quantified directly, the proportion of groundwater resources with different grades was applied to calculate the membership degree of corresponding evaluation grades, applying the principle of fuzzy statistics.
For example, the fuzzy synthetic evaluation matrix of groundwater rights for 2013 was determined as follows:
R = | R 1 R 2 R 3 R 4 R 5 R 6 R 7 R 8 R 9 R 10 R 11 R 12 R 13 R 14 | = [ 0 1 0 0 0 0.6809 0.3191 0 0 0 0.3243 0.6757 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.1848 0.8152 0 0 0 0.5720 0.4280 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0.7000 0.3000 0 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0.6104 0.3896 0 0 0 0.5180 0.4820 0 0 0 0.5486 0.4514 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0.4750 0.5250 0 0 0 0 1 ]
As a result, the value of groundwater rights V in 2013 can be evaluated according to Equation (4), using the calculation results from Equations (18)–(19):
V = W · R = [ 0.3119 ,   0.2451 ,   0.0134 ,   0.1337 ,   0.3135 ]
The value of groundwater rights V in other years can be calculated with the same approach.

3.5. Calculation of Groundwater Rights Price

The price of groundwater rights is determined by Equations (14)–(17). The numerical results of the necessary parameters can be determined by referring to the government gazette listed in Section 2.2. For the water rate affordability indicator, this paper selects 2% as a sound ratio, based on the actual situation of Ningxia. In addition, the tap water price in China varies for different users. The data related to urban resident water use were adopted in this study, as urban residents have lower affordability levels with respect to water prices than nonresidents and special industries. “Water supply cost and normal profit” is difficult to directly count; in China, this parameter is generally calculated as the residential tap water price reduces the sewage treatment fee and water resources fee. Parameter α was determined through interviews with experts. Experts believed that Ningxia has a significant water resources shortage and needs to appropriately raise the price of groundwater rights. Ningxia’s economy is underdeveloped, and an extravagant price would create burden for residents. After comprehensive consideration, the value of the parameter was set at 4% in this study.
For example, for 2013, the upper limit of the groundwater rights price in Ningxia can be calculated as Equation (14):
P = A × E / Q C D T = 2 % × 14565.78 / 26.28 0.90 0.85 0.31 = 9.03
Then, the groundwater rights price vector S is calculated as Equation (16):
S = [ P ,   0.75 P ,   0.5 P ,   0.25 P ,   0 ] T = [ 9.03 ,   6.77 ,   4.52 ,   2.26 , 0 ] T
Finally, the price of groundwater rights is calculated as Equation (17):
GP = ( 1 + α ) V · S = ( 1 + 4 % ) × [ 0.3199 ,   0.2451 ,   0.0134 ,   0.1337 ,   0.3135 ] × [ 9.03 ,   6.77 ,   4.52 ,   2.26 , 0 ] T = 5.11
Table 6 shows the parameter values and final calculation results of all the years in the study period.
Table 6 shows that the price of groundwater rights in Ningxia increased from 5.11 yuan/m3 to 5.73 yuan/m3 between 2013 and 2017, which is basically stable with a slight increase. This calculation result is much higher than the current actual water price (around 2.00 yuan/m3).
In addition, the ratio of residents’ water fee expenditure to real disposable income was also basically stable, fluctuating around 0.37%. This figure is lower than the domestic average and the international standard. Previous research indicates that different ratios will have different impacts on residents’ psychology and on the bearing capacity of water usage. A ratio of 1% or less had little impact on the psychology of residential water use. As the ratio increases, so does the impact on residents. When the water fee expenditure exceeds 2% of personal disposable income, it has a stronger impact and causes people to begin to care about water consumption. When the water fee expenditure accounts for 3–5% of personal disposable income, the impact is sufficient for residents to pay more attention to water usage and the economical utilization of water resources. When the ratio is 5% or more, the influence is sufficiently strong to make residents think about water reuse [64]. In other words, Ningxia’s water fee is too low to incentivize residents to save water, which is unscientific and unreasonable in such an arid area. This shows that the price policy for water resources in Ningxia has significant room for improvement.
The low price of water in Ningxia is mainly caused by both historical reasons and practical reasons. Because of the backward economic development of Ningxia, the lower water price has helped to maintain social stability. From the perspective of practical reasons, the lack of relatively advanced water management policies and water price policies leads to the low price of water resources. Hence, the Ningxia’s pricing policies are only based on economic benefits without considering environmental factors. To make matters worse, the price reform has been slow because people have become accustomed to low water prices.
In Ningxia, approximately 89% of residents rely on groundwater for living. A long-term low water price does not serve to protect groundwater resources. Although the government has adopted methods such as ladder pricing to explore reasonable water pricing, the calculations show that the effect is not significant. At present, groundwater in Ningxia is seriously overexploited due to lack of water resources. As a result, the regional economic development is restricted, and people’s lives are adversely affected. Conflicts arising from water resources occur from time to time, and sustainable development is gravely impeded. Therefore, Ningxia’s problem, common in many districts of China, needs to be solved as soon as possible.
As mentioned above, the Coase theorem suggests that by clearly defining groundwater rights and establishing a groundwater rights market to raise the price to normal levels [65], the government can effectively incentivize residents to save water and solve certain water shortage problems [66,67]. At present, the implementation of this policy faces two major obstacles. First, the relevant laws and regulations are not perfect. This is because studies on water rights and water rights trading started late in China, and the experience of other countries is not fully compatible. This problem can only be solved by practicing while studying. Another issue is public acceptance. As mentioned above, people have become accustomed to low water prices. Therefore, by introducing water rights, raising water prices may be opposed by the public, even if the price is still within the range of affordability. Therefore, when raising water prices, it is necessary to conduct hearings to fully communicate with the public, and gradually raise water prices by stages and by industry. Moreover, because of the characteristics of groundwater itself, it is necessary to adopt differential pricing among industrial water, agricultural water, and residential water.
While the pricing of groundwater rights in this paper is based on the value of groundwater resources, pricing methods and theories related to water rights are not unique. As mentioned above, the study adopted a pricing method based on the cost of groundwater supply or welfare water prices as a quasipublic product. In China, different regions adopt different pricing methods according to their own degree of economic development and groundwater resources. The pricing of groundwater rights is quite individualized and regional.

4. Conclusions and Recommendations

This study focused on Ningxia, China, and calculated the price of groundwater rights for the region based on the value of groundwater resources. An evaluation indicator system with 14 indicators was developed based on a fuzzy mathematics model with three dimensions: environment, society, and economy. The weight of each indicator was determined with the ANP and entropy method. This process generated pricing for groundwater rights in Ningxia from 2013 to 2017. According to the calculation results, the price of groundwater rights was basically stable a slight increase from 5.11 yuan/m3 to 5.73 yuan/m3 from 2013 to 2017. This pricing was approximately twice the actual water price (around 2.00 yuan/m3) at that time. Also, during this period, water fee expenditures accounted for approximately 0.37% of residents’ disposable income, which was lower than the set value of 2%. That means that the current water price policy of Ningxia underestimates the current water value, and there is still much room for water price to rise.
Ningxia is a province short of water resources where the contradiction between supply and demand of water resources is very sharp. It is particularly important to optimize the allocation of limited water resources and reasonable water price is the basis of realizing optimal allocation. In Ningxia, the long-term low water price policy has resulted in low water costs, thus the water users waste water resources, which aggravates the water supply and demand crisis and aggravates water pollution.
After the formation of the water price mechanism that meets the requirements of the market, the local government can make full use of price leverage to adjust groundwater demand, allocate groundwater resources, and promote water saving. Water price leverage is more powerful than many administrative measures, and it is conducive to the rational allocation of groundwater resources, the sustainable utilization of groundwater resources, and the protection of the ecological environment.
By reflecting the value of groundwater as a scarce resource, the groundwater rights price can fully adjust the relationship between supply and demand of groundwater resources. When the price of water supply is raised to a certain extent, it can form a reasonable price relative to the price used for sewage treatment and regeneration, and then form an effective incentive mechanism for sewerage recycling, so as to increase the amount of available water and reduce the dependence on external water resources. Therefore, it is necessary to propose relevant policies to improve the current water resource pricing policy in Ningxia.
First, central government should amend and improve laws and policies related to water rights, making principles and methods of water rights pricing to abide by. Second, by introducing a water rights system, the government should construct a water resources allocation mode combining administrative means with market means. Third, the government should push forward water price reform step by step. The government should decentralize the power of pricing step by step, set the water price according to different regions and uses, and gradually raise current water price standards without arousing opposition from the people to ensure that water resources prices conform to market rules. Last, the government should strengthen the supervision and management of water price policy implementation. Without strict and effective supervision, no matter how good the policy is, it will not work. This would help the realization of sustainable development and utilization of water resources and increase public awareness of the need for water savings and could improve water use efficiency.
The main innovations of this study are summarized as follows: First, this study has proposed a groundwater rights pricing method combining natural, economic, and social factors, which comprehensively reflects the economic and social attributes of groundwater resources and aligns better with reality. Second, this study has calculated the price of groundwater rights in Ningxia from 2013 to 2017, and pointed out that the current water price needs to be improved. Third, it puts forward specific suggestions for water resources governance and water price reform in Ningxia, which might be favorable four saving groundwater resources and the sustainable development of water resources in China.
This paper highlights a number of areas for further research. First, the indicator system should be refined. The factors influencing groundwater rights pricing reflect a complex system integrating natural, social, and economic factors. This inevitably leads to the simplification of the indicator system. Second, when calculating the affordability of water price, this study only accounted for urban residents, and did not consider agricultural, industrial, and ecological water use. Further study is needed to calculate groundwater rights pricing for these uses, based on a comprehensive consideration of industry characteristics and influencing factors. Third, future study is needed on the transaction pricing of groundwater rights among water users. The paper informs the pricing of groundwater rights by government departments, based on groundwater value. Scientifically and rationally allocating groundwater resources requires the opening of the water rights market. Establishing methods for conducting the transaction and determining the transaction price for water users with groundwater rights is a future research focus. Last, differential pricing according to regions and uses can be calculated based on this study.

Author Contributions

Z.W. and J.S. proposed the research ideas and methods. F.S. and Z.Z. revised the paper, Y.J. drew the figures. D.Z. and K.Z. were responsible for data collection and creating the figures.

Funding

This research was supported by “the Fundamental Research Funds for the Central Universities”-A Pricing Method of Groundwater Rights Transaction Based on the Environment Protection (No. 2018B712X14);

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Yue, C.; Wang, Q.; Li, Y. Evaluating water resources allocation in arid areas of northwest China using a projection pursuit dynamic cluster model. Water Supply 2019, 19, 762–770. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Zhang, J.; Lin, X.; Guo, B. Multivariate Copula-Based Joint Probability Distribution of Water Supply and Demand in Irrigation District. Water Resour. Manag. 2016, 30, 2361–2375. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Custodio, E. Aquifer overexploitation: What does it mean? Hydrogeol. J. 2002, 10, 254–277. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Goldfarb, W. Water Law, 2nd ed.; Lewis publishers, Inc.: Boca Raton, FL, USA, 1988. [Google Scholar]
  5. Ostrom, V.; Ostrom, E. Legal and Political Conditions of Water Resource Development. Land Econ. 1972, 48, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Coase, R.H. The Nature of the Firm. In Essential Readings in Economics; Estrin, S., Marin, A., Eds.; Macmillan Education: London, UK, 1995; pp. 37–54. [Google Scholar]
  7. Bjornlund, H. Efficient Water Market Mechanisms to Cope with Water Scarcity. Int. J. Water Resour. Dev. 2003, 19, 553–567. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Grafton, R.; Libecap, G.; McGlennon, S.; Landry, C.; OBrien, B. An Integrated Assessment of Water Markets: A Cross-Country Comparison. Rev. Environ. Econ. Policy 2011, 5, 219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Brooks, R.; Harris, E. Efficiency gains from water markets: Empirical analysis of Watermove in Australia. Agric. Water Manag. 2008, 95, 391–399. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Bauer, C.J. Bringing water markets down to earth: The political economy of water rights in Chile, 1976–1995. World Dev. 1997, 25, 639–656. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Boyd, T.; Brumley, J. Advancing the trade of groundwater entitlements in Australia. In WIT Transactions on Ecology and the Environment; Cunha, M., Brebbia, C.A., Eds.; WIT Press: Ashurst, UK, 2005; Volume 80, pp. 403–411. [Google Scholar]
  12. Khair, S.M.; Mushtaq, S.; Culas, R.J.; Hafeez, M. Groundwater markets under the water scarcity and declining watertable conditions: The upland Balochistan Region of Pakistan. Agric. Syst. 2012, 107, 21–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Manjunatha, A.V.; Speelman, S.; Aravindakshan, S.; Babu, A.T.S.; Mal, P. Impact of informal groundwater markets on efficiency of irrigated farms in India: A bootstrap data envelopment analysis approach. Irrig. Sci. 2016, 34, 41–52. [Google Scholar]
  14. Banerji, A.; Meenakshi, J.V.; Khanna, G. Social contracts, markets and efficiency: Groundwater irrigation in North India. J. Dev. Econ. 2012, 98, 228–237. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Zhang, L.; Wang, J.; Huang, J.; Rozelle, S. Development of Groundwater Markets in China: A Glimpse into Progress to Date. World Dev. 2008, 36, 706–726. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Skurray, J.H.; Pandit, R.; Pannell, D.J. Institutional impediments to groundwater trading: The case of the Gnangara groundwater system of Western Australia. J. Environ. Plan. Manag. 2013, 56, 1046–1072. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Feldman, M.; Lai, K.; Zhang, L. A Price-Anticipating Resource Allocation Mechanism for Distributed Shared Clusters. Comput. Sci. 2005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Gill, B.; Webb, J.; Stott, M.; Cheng, X.; Wilkinson, R.; Cossens, B. Economic, social and resource management factors influencing groundwater trade: Evidence from Victoria, Australia. J. Hydrol. 2017, 550, 253–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ioslovich, I.; Gutman, P.O. A model for the global optimization of water prices and usage for the case of spatially distributed sources and consumers. Math. Comput. Simul. 2001, 56, 347–356. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Sun, L.; Lu, W.; Yang, Q.; Martín, J.D.; Li, D. Ecological Compensation Estimation of Soil and Water Conservation Based on Cost-Benefit Analysis. Water Resour. Manag. 2013, 27, 2709–2727. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Tsitsifli, S.; Gonelas, K.; Papadopoulou, A.; Kanakoudis, V.; Kouziakis, C.; Lappos, S. Socially fair drinking water pricing considering the full water cost recovery principle and the non-revenue water related cost allocation to the end users. Desalin. Water Treat. 2017, 99, 72–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Gaydon, D.S.; Meinke, H.; Rodriguez, D.; McGrath, D.J. Comparing water options for irrigation farmers using Modern Portfolio Theory. Agric. Water Manag. 2012, 115, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Yuan, J.; Wang, B.; Zhang, L.; Liu, Y. Game Analysis on Urban Tap Water Price under the Condition of Incomplete Information; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2015; pp. 673–679. [Google Scholar]
  24. Lika, A.; Galioto, F.; Viaggi, D. Water Authorities’ Pricing Strategies to Recover Supply Costs in the Absence of Water Metering for Irrigated Agriculture. Sustainability 2017, 9, 2210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Martinez, M.T.; Rodriguez-Ferrero, N. Ramsey Pricing for Cost Recovery Applied to Reservoir Infrastructure in Andalucía (Spain). Water Econ. Policy 2017, 3, 1–27. [Google Scholar]
  26. Wasimi, S.A. Planning for a Large Dam Project: The Case of Traveston Crossing Dam. Water Resour. Manag. 2010, 24, 2991–3015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. DeNooyer, T.A.; Peschel, J.M.; Zhang, Z.; Stillwell, A.S. Integrating water resources and power generation: The energy-water nexus in Illinois. Appl. Energy 2016, 162, 363–371. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Truong, C.H. A Two Factor Model for Water Prices and Its Implications for Evaluating Real Options and Other Water Price Derivatives. Can. J. Agric. Econ. 2014, 62, 23–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Hölting, B.; Coldewey, W.G. Groundwater Exploitation. In Hydrogeology; Hölting, B., Coldewey, W.G., Eds.; Springer: Berlin, Germany, 2019; pp. 203–230. [Google Scholar]
  30. De Vries, J.J.; Simmers, I. Groundwater recharge: An overview of processes and challenges. Hydrogeol. J. 2002, 10, 5–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Hazarika, N.; Nitivattananon, V. Strategic assessment of groundwater resource exploitation using DPSIR framework in Guwahati city, India. Habitat Int. 2016, 51, 79–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Fenichel, E.P.; Abbott, J.K.; Bayham, J.; Boone, W.; Haacker, E.M.K.; Pfeiffer, L. Measuring the value of groundwater and other forms of natural capital. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2016, 113, 2382–2387. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  33. Abdelhafidh, H.; Bachta, M.S. Groundwater pricing for farms and water user association sustainability. Arab. J. Geosci. 2016, 9, 525. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Kerachian, R.; Fallahnia, M.; Bazargan-Lari, M.R.; Mansoori, A.; Sedghi, H. A fuzzy game theoretic approach for groundwater resources management: Application of Rubinstein Bargaining Theory. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2010, 54, 673–682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Aissaoui, O.E.; Madani, Y.E.A.E.; Oughdir, L.; Allioui, Y.E. A fuzzy classification approach for learning style prediction based on web mining technique in e-learning environments. Educ. Inf. Technol. 2019, 24, 1943–1959. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Ghomi-Avili, M.; Jalali Naeini, S.G.; Tavakkoli-Moghaddam, R.; Jabbarzadeh, A. A fuzzy pricing model for a green competitive closed-loop supply chain network design in the presence of disruptions. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 188, 425–442. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Zeng, W.; Li, D.; Yin, Q. Weighted Interval-Valued Hesitant Fuzzy Sets and Its Application in Group Decision Making. Int. J. Fuzzy Syst. 2019, 21, 421–432. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Fernandez, A.; Herrera, F.; Cordon, O.; Jesus, M.J.D.; Marcelloni, F. Evolutionary Fuzzy Systems for Explainable Artificial Intelligence: Why, When, What for, and Where to? IEEE Comput. Intell. Mag. 2019, 14, 69–81. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Madhoo, Y.N. Political economy of water pricing policy: Empirical evidence from public utilities in Mauritius. Water Resour. Res. 2004, 40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Mao, C.; Zhai, N.; Yang, J.; Feng, Y.; Cao, Y.; Han, X.; Ren, G.; Yang, G.; Meng, Q.X. Environmental Kuznets curve analysis of the economic development and nonpoint source pollution in the Ningxia Yellow River irrigation districts in China. Biomed. Res. Int. 2013, 2013, 267968. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Ningxia Water Resources Department. Ningxia Water Resources Bulletin (2013–2017); Ningxia Water Resources Department: Yinchuan, China, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  42. Gui-liang, T.; Chang-xin, X.; Wen-xuan, X.; Rong, P. Regional water right distribution model of multi-objective programming—An empirical study based on the data in Ningxia. In Proceedings of the 2010 International Conference on Management Science & Engineering 17th Annual Conference Proceedings, Melbourne, Australia, 24–26 November 2010; pp. 280–286. [Google Scholar]
  43. Xia, C.; Pahl-Wostl, C. The Development of Water Allocation Management in The Yellow River Basin. Water Resour. Manag. 2012, 26, 3395–3414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Sun, L.; Li, C.; Cai, Y.; Wang, X. Interval Optimization Model Considering Terrestrial Ecological Impacts for Water Rights Transfer from Agriculture to Industry in Ningxia, China. Sci. Rep. 2017, 7, 3465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Tang, L.; Zhang, W.J. Fuzzy Comprehensive Evaluation for Water Resources Sustainable Utilization of Ningxia. Adv. Mater. Res. 2012, 446, 2770–2775. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Ningxia Statistical Bureau. Ningxia Statistical Yearbook (2013–2017); China Statistics Press: Beijing, China, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  47. Ningxia Statistical Bureau. Ningxia Hui Autonomous Region Statistical Bulletin of National Economic and Social Development (2013–2017); Ningxia Statistical Bureau: Yinchuan, China, 2018. [Google Scholar]
  48. Hydrology Department. Monthly Report of Groundwater Regime in China; China Ministry of Water Resources: Beijing, China, 2018.
  49. China Water Web. China Tap Water Price 2013–2017. Available online: http://www.h2o-china.com/price/ (accessed on 17 March 2019).
  50. Guerrero García Rojas, H.R.; Garcia-Vega, D.; Herrera-Torres, H.A. Water Price Policy and Its Institutional Role as an Economic Instrument for Water Management. In Water Policy in Mexico: Economic, Institutional and Environmental Considerations; Guerrero García Rojas, H.R., Ed.; Springer International Publishing: Berne, Switzerland, 2019; pp. 137–152. [Google Scholar]
  51. Cooper, B.; Crase, L.; Pawsey, N. Best practice pricing principles and the politics of water pricing. Agric. Water Manag. 2014, 145, 92–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Ioris, A.A.R. The Value of Water Values: Departing from Geography towards An interdisciplinary Synthesis. Geogr. Ann. Ser. B Hum. Geogr. 2013, 95, 323–337. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Valmohammadi, C.; Dashti, S. Using interpretive structural modeling and fuzzy analytical process to identify and prioritize the interactive barriers of e-commerce implementation. Inf. Manag. 2016, 53, 157–168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Xu, S.; Wang, T.; Hu, S. Dynamic Assessment of Water Quality Based on a Variable Fuzzy Pattern Recognition Model. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2015, 12, 2230–2248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
  55. Liu, T.; Deng, Y.; Chan, F. Evidential Supplier Selection Based on DEMATEL and Game Theory. Int. J. Fuzzy Syst. 2018, 20, 1321–1333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Mei, Y.; Ye, J.; Zeng, Z. Entropy-weighted ANP fuzzy comprehensive evaluation of interim product production schemes in one-of-a-kind production. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2016, 100, 144–152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Molinos-Senante, M.; Donoso, G. Water scarcity and affordability in urban water pricing: A case study of Chile. Util. Policy 2016, 43, 107–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. García-Valiñas, M.A.; Martínez-Espiñeira, R.; González-Gómez, F. Affordability of residential water tariffs: Alternative measurement and explanatory factors in southern Spain. J. Environ. Manag. 2010, 91, 2696–2706. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  59. Jia, Y.; Shen, J.; Wang, H. Calculation of Water Resource Value in Nanjing Based on a Fuzzy Mathematical Model. Water 2018, 10, 920. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Iskin, I.; Daim, T.; Kayakutlu, G.; Altuntas, M. Exploring renewable energy pricing with analytic network process—Comparing a developed and a developing economy. Energy Econ. 2012, 34, 882–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Zhang, J. Weighing and realizing the environmental, economic and social goals of tourism development using an analytic network process-goal programming approach. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 127, 262–273. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Li, J.; Min, Q.; Li, W.; Bai, Y.; Yang, L.; Dhruba, B.G.C. Evaluation of water resources conserved by forests in the Hani rice terraces system of Honghe County, Yunnan, China: An application of the fuzzy comprehensive evaluation model. J. Mt. Sci. 2016, 13, 744–753. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Yanli, L.; DeLan, X. Environmental asset value of water resources in lake calculated in applying fuzzy mathematical method. In Proceedings of the 2nd International Conference on Information Science and Engineering, Hangzhou, China, 4–6 December 2010; pp. 2830–2833. [Google Scholar]
  64. Chica-Olmo, J.; González-Gómez, F.; Guardiola, J. Do neighbouring municipalities matter in water pricing? Urban Water J. 2013, 10, 1–9. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Beare, S.C.; Heaney, A.; Australian, B.O.A.A. Water Trade and the Externalities of Water use in Australia: Interim report: ABARE paper for Natural Resource Management Business Unit, AFFA; ABARE: Canberra, A.C.T., Australia, 2002; p. 5.
  66. Hamilton, J.R.; Whittlesey, N.K.; Halverson, P. Interruptible Water Markets in the Pacific Northwest. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 1989, 71, 63–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  67. Young, M.; Macdonald, D.H.; Stringer, R.; Bjornland, H. Interstate Water Trading: A 2-year Review; Policy and Economic Research Unit, CSIRO Land and Water: Adelaide, Australia, 2000; Available online: http:// www.clw.csiro.au/publications/consultancy/2000/inter_trading.pdf (accessed on 18 July 2018).
Figure 1. Location and region map of Ningxia.
Figure 1. Location and region map of Ningxia.
Ijerph 16 02176 g001
Figure 2. The network structure of clusters in the ANP model for groundwater rights pricing.
Figure 2. The network structure of clusters in the ANP model for groundwater rights pricing.
Ijerph 16 02176 g002
Table 1. Groundwater Resources in Ningxia Zoning by Basin Area for 2017.
Table 1. Groundwater Resources in Ningxia Zoning by Basin Area for 2017.
River BasinUnitGroundwater Resources in Mountainous AreasGroundwater Resources in Plain AreasDouble Counting between Mountainous Areas and Plain AreasGroundwater Resources in the Subregion
Precipitation RechargeSurface Water RechargeMountain Lateral Infiltration RechargeTotal
Areas Irrigated by the Yellow River108 m300.76814.4870.03815.2930.03815.255
Zuli River108 m30.033000000.033
Qingshui River108 m30.857000000.857
Hongliugou River108 m30.028000000.028
Kushui River108 m30.066000000.066
The Huangyou Area108 m30.046000000.046
The Huangzuo Area108 m30.9340.08600.7640.8500.7641.020
Hulu River108 m30.359000000.356
Jinghe River108 m31.667000001.667
Endorheic Drainage Area in Yanchi108 m30000000
Total108 m33.9900.85414.4870.80216.1430.80219.331
Table 2. The sources of the indicators.
Table 2. The sources of the indicators.
Ningxia Water Resources Bulletin 2013–2017 [48]; Monthly Report of Groundwater Regime in China January 2013–December 2017” [51]Groundwater quality grade, average depth of shallow groundwater, the proportion of the groundwater supply, per capita groundwater withdrawal, agricultural water withdrawal, industrial water withdrawal, withdrawal for residential living use, and the proportion of overexploited groundwater area
Ningxia Statistical Yearbook (2013–2017) [49]; China Tap Water Price 2013–2017” [52]Population density, per capita groundwater resources, groundwater resources per unit area, and wastewater discharge
Ningxia Autonomous Region Statistical Bulletin of National Economic and Social Development (2013–2017) [50]Per capita GDP and per 104-yuan-GDP water consumption
Table 3. Groundwater rights value evaluation indicators for 2013–2017.
Table 3. Groundwater rights value evaluation indicators for 2013–2017.
ClusterEvaluating IndicatorUnitDefinitionActual Number
20132014201520162017
EnvironmentGroundwater Quality Grade/Characterizes the quality of groundwaterIIIIIIIIIIIIIII
Per Capita Groundwater Resourcesm3Characterizes the scarcity of groundwater resources per capita338.30321.99312.60275.13283.45
Groundwater Resources Per Unit Area102 m3/ km2Characterizes the scarcity of groundwater resources regionally427412403359373
Average Depth of Shallow GroundwatermCharacterizes the accessibility of groundwater 2.342.262.292.302.41
Proportion of Overexploited Groundwater Area %Characterizes the severity groundwater overexploitation1.431.431.431.431.43
SocietyPopulation Densitypeople/km2Characterizes the level of local population size12531295133613431388
Per Capita Groundwater Withdrawalm3Characterizes the level of groundwater demand85.082.776.978.681.1
Agricultural Groundwater Withdrawal108 m3Characterizes the level of agricultural groundwater consumption1.1681.1421.2531.2961.567
Industrial Groundwater Withdrawal108 m3Characterizes the level of industrial groundwater consumption2.5942.4261.8471.6381.436
Residential Groundwater Use Withdrawal108 m3Characterizes the level of groundwater consumption in social life1.2951.3871.5001.9162.077
EconomyPer Capita GDP103 yuanCharacterizes the regional economic level39.641.843.847.250.8
Per 104-yuan-GDP Water Consumptionm3Characterizes water use efficiency of regional economic sectors311281260206194
Groundwater Supply Proportion%Characterizes the degree of reliance on groundwater7.77.87.38.28.4
Wastewater Discharge107 tonCharacterizes the negative externality of economy38.537.332.033.930.7
Table 4. Evaluation criteria of groundwater rights value.
Table 4. Evaluation criteria of groundwater rights value.
ClusterEvaluating IndicatorUnitCharacterEvaluation Criteria
HighRelatively HighCommonRelatively LowLow
EnvironmentGroundwater Quality Grade/+>IIIIIIVV<V
Per Capita Groundwater Resourcesm3-100.00450.00800.001150.001500.00
Groundwater Resources Per Unit Area102 m3/ km2-200900160023003000
Average Depth of Shallow Groundwaterm+30.0017.2515.508.251.00
Proportion of Overexploited Groundwater Area%+10.007.505.002.500.00
SocietyPopulation Densitypeople/km2+45003700290021001300
Per Capita Groundwater Withdrawalm3+200.0150.0100.050.00.0
Agricultural Groundwater Withdrawal108 m3+100.00075.50051.00026.5002.000
Industrial Groundwater Withdrawal108 m3+17.00012.2508.5004.2500.000
Groundwater for Residential Living Withdrawal108 m3+10.0007.5005.0002.5000.000
EconomyPer Capita GDP103 yuan+100.082.565.047.530.0
Per 104-yuan-GDP Water Consumptionm3+2001551106520
Groundwater Supply Proportion%+50.038.026.014.02.0
Wastewater Discharge107 ton+400.0325.0250.0175.0100.0
Table 5. Indicator weight of groundwater rights value.
Table 5. Indicator weight of groundwater rights value.
ClusterEvaluating IndicatorSubjective WeightObjective Weight
EnvironmentGroundwater Quality Grade0.02350.0736
Per Capita Groundwater Resources0.25150.0697
Groundwater Resources Per Unit Area0.19770.0697
Average Depth of Shallow Groundwater0.01450.0704
Proportion of Overexploited Groundwater Area 0.00990.0736
SocietyPopulation Density0.12810.0698
Per Capita Groundwater Withdrawal0.01780.0730
Agricultural Groundwater Withdrawal0.04920.0693
Industrial Groundwater Withdrawal0.02580.0740
Groundwater for Residential Living Withdrawal0.00550.0692
EconomyPer Capita GDP0.17240.0695
Per 104-yuan-GDP Water Consumption0.07170.0740
Groundwater Supply Proportion0.00420.0705
Wastewater Discharge0.01750.0738
Table 6. Indicators of groundwater rights pricing.
Table 6. Indicators of groundwater rights pricing.
IndicatorUnit20132014201520162017
Per Capita Disposable Income yuan14,565.7815,906.7817,329.0618,832.2820,561.66
Per Capita Water Consumption of Residentsm326.2828.2529.8232.5933.73
Residents’ Tap Water Price 1yuan/ m32.062.062.062.062.31
Sewage Treatment Feeyuan/ m30.850.850.850.850.85
Water Resources Feeyuan/ m30.310.410.570.720.72
Water Supply Cost and Normal Profityuan/ m30.900.800.640.490.74
Per Capita Water Fee Expenditureyuan54.1458.2061.4267.1377.92
Per Capita Real Disposable Income yuan14,086.8315,610.1917,140.5118,8553.9720,237.85
Water Rate Affordability Indicator%22222
Ratio of Residents’ Water Fee Expenditure to Real Disposable Income%0.380.370.360.360.39
Groundwater Rights Priceyuan/ m35.115.215.445.405.73
1 There is no uniform water price standard in Ningxia. These data are based on the water pricing of major cities in the district.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Wang, Z.; Shen, J.; Sun, F.; Zhang, Z.; Zhang, D.; Jia, Y.; Zhang, K. A Pricing Model for Groundwater Rights in Ningxia, China Based on the Fuzzy Mathematical Model. Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2019, 16, 2176. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph16122176

AMA Style

Wang Z, Shen J, Sun F, Zhang Z, Zhang D, Jia Y, Zhang K. A Pricing Model for Groundwater Rights in Ningxia, China Based on the Fuzzy Mathematical Model. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health. 2019; 16(12):2176. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph16122176

Chicago/Turabian Style

Wang, Zeyu, Juqin Shen, Fuhua Sun, Zhaofang Zhang, Dandan Zhang, Yizhen Jia, and Kaize Zhang. 2019. "A Pricing Model for Groundwater Rights in Ningxia, China Based on the Fuzzy Mathematical Model" International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health 16, no. 12: 2176. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph16122176

APA Style

Wang, Z., Shen, J., Sun, F., Zhang, Z., Zhang, D., Jia, Y., & Zhang, K. (2019). A Pricing Model for Groundwater Rights in Ningxia, China Based on the Fuzzy Mathematical Model. International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health, 16(12), 2176. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph16122176

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop