1. Introduction
After 40 years of reform and opening-up, China’s economy has entered a “new era” of pursuing high-quality growth. China’s GDP growth has been slowing down in recent years. Since 2011, GDP growth began to slow, and the growth was only 5.95% in 2019. Meanwhile, government spending on scientific and technology innovation, ecology, and education increased year by year. For example, from 2016 to 2018, the total amount of government spending on ecological and environmental protection was CNY 2.451 trillion, with an average annual growth rate of 14.8%. From 2012 to 2021, CNY 7.07 trillion was spent on science and technology in the national general public budget. This means that the economic development pattern has shifted from extensive growth of scale and speed to intensive growth of quality and efficiency. The driving force of economic growth has also changed from the factor-driven, investment-driven pattern to the innovation-driven pattern [
1]. A high-quality development goal of “innovation, coordination, sustainability, openness, and sharing” was established by the Chinese government in 2017. It calls for the establishment of an economic system that promotes green, low-carbon, and circular development, as well as economic growth that is commensurate with the country’s resource carrying capacity [
2]. From 1 January 2018, China’s first “green tax system,” the Environmental Protection Tax Law, came into effect, reflecting the strengthening trend of environmental regulation. In the Government Work Report in 2021, the State Council set the goal of achieving peak carbon dioxide emissions and carbon neutrality [
3]. Under such circumstances, enterprises must take measures to realize coordinated and sustainable economic and ecological development [
4].
Based on the Porter Hypothesis, environmental regulation will force enterprises to carry out technology innovation, which will help enterprises to obtain innovation compensation and a first-mover advantage [
5]. In the current context of strengthened environmental regulations, will enterprises carry out green technology innovation? If so, what is the relationship between the two? Considering the uneven regional development in China, does the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation vary from region to region?
Additionally, while firms’ technology innovation efforts have positive externalities such as increased resource efficiency and economic development (Long and Summers, 1991), there are also risks such as long investment return cycle and competitors’ imitation [
6,
7]. Government subsidies alleviate firms’ need to reduce pollution costs during the process of green technology innovation while also conveying information to the outside world via the “certification effect” of sponsored enterprises, thereby attracting external investment [
8,
9,
10]. If environmental regulation impacts technology innovation, what role will government subsidies play between them?
The answers to these questions will enrich the empirical research of the policy evaluation of environmental regulation. This paper also provides constructive suggestions to promote the further improvement and effective implementation of China’s environmental regulation policies, and to prompt enterprises to seize the opportunity of environmental tax reform to achieve high-quality development goals.
This study, therefore, contributes to the existing literature in three aspects. First, this paper integrated environmental regulation, government subsidies, and green technology innovation into the same research framework. Based on the Porter Hypothesis, the research demonstrated that government subsidies are not perfect auxiliary tools and should be withdrawn at the proper time. Second, this paper found that the influence of environmental regulation on green technology innovation is heterogeneous among the regions. Specifically, China’s central and central coast region has an inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation, whereas in the north region, southern coast, and southwest region, there is a “U” relationship between the two. In the Beijing-Tianjin area, the relationship is not significant. Third, based on the regional differences in environmental regulation affecting green technology innovation, and the limitations of government subsidies incentives, this paper provides strong support for the government to implement local policies and reasonable response subsidies and makes reliable suggestions for enterprises to respond positively to environmental regulation.
The rest of this paper is organized as follows.
Section 2 reviews the relevant literature.
Section 3 puts forward the hypothesis.
Section 4 details the model and data.
Section 5 presents the estimation techniques and empirical results.
Section 6 presents conclusions and policy implications.
2. Literature Review
Environmental regulation is an effective way to solve the negative externalities of enterprise environmental pollution. It can be divided into three types: command control type, market incentive type, and voluntary type [
11], and gradual changes from command type to market and voluntary type [
12,
13]. The impact of different types of environmental regulation on green technology innovation is heterogeneous. Compared with command-controlled environmental regulation, market-based environmental regulatory tools provide firms with higher incentives for green technology innovation [
12].
There are mainly two views on the relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation. The traditional view is that environmental regulation will increase the cost of production for polluters, thereby inhibiting green technology innovation [
14,
15,
16,
17]. However, this traditional paradigm has been challenged by many scholars. The Porter Hypothesis, which is the most well-known of such theories, asserts that environmental regulations may compel firms to innovate in order to offset the costs of pollution control [
5,
18]. Scholars have classified the Porter Hypothesis into two categories: “strong” and “weak,” to perform further research into it. According to the “weak” Porter Hypothesis, correctly conceived environmental regulation can drive innovation [
19,
20,
21,
22,
23]. In contrast, the “strong” Porter Hypothesis asserts that this innovation frequently outweighs any additional regulatory costs—in other words, environmental regulation frequently contributes to a rise in firm competitiveness [
15,
19]. Meanwhile, because the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation is dynamic and is the result of the combined effect of extrusion and stimulation [
10], some researchers have discovered nonlinear relationships, such as the “U” type [
3,
24,
25] and the inverted “U” type [
26].
The new growth theory emphasizes that knowledge and human capital are “engines of growth” and holds that it is the pursuit of monopoly profits and the temporary nature of monopoly profits that keeps innovation going, thus allowing the economy to enter a sustained long-term growth [
27,
28,
29]. Despite the obvious positive externalities associated with technology innovation activities [
30,
31], enterprises’ enthusiasm for R&D investment is diminished due to risks such as a lengthy investment return cycle, competitor imitation, and a high degree of uncertainty [
32,
33]. The government needs to take adequate measures to correct market failure, regain Pareto optimality, and internalize externalities [
32,
34]. Governments in various countries generally encourage private enterprises to increase research and development investment with innovative subsidy policies [
35]. Direct government subsidy is one of the typical subsidy tools, which is direct ex-ante support for long-term innovation projects, namely innovation input subsidy [
24]. Innovation input subsidies are a kind of supportive government subsidy that aims to promote the innovation behavior of enterprises and improve the initiative of innovation [
9,
10,
36]. In terms of the combined effect of government subsidies and environmental regulation on green technology innovation, some scholars believe that government subsidies can mitigate the negative impact of environmental regulation [
8,
37,
38], while others argue that government subsidies are not always effective [
39].
Based on the existing research, this paper concludes the following: First, the Porter Hypothesis is the mainstream theory to study the relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation, but it is controversial in terms of establishment conditions, content explanation, and scope of adaptation. Second, most of the current studies have used emission charges data or self-designed environmental regulation indicators, but few of them could fully reflect the degree of environmental regulation. Third, many scholars have defined “green technology innovation” with innovation output or input, but few have taken “green” into consideration. Fourth, government subsidies are widely regarded as an important tool to motivate technology innovation, but few researchers have explored its role in the path of the environmental regulation affecting green technology innovation.
3. Research Hypothesis
Environmental regulation has two effects on enterprise-level green technology innovation. The first is the incentive effect of “innovation compensation” [
5,
40], which refers to the fact that environmental regulation compels businesses to lead in green technology innovation [
41,
42]. It enables the firms to maintain a strong competitive edge in terms of consumer loyalty, market share, and so on. The second is the crowding-out effect described by the “compliance cost theory” [
14,
16]. This means that the adoption of advanced equipment and technologies to meet energy-saving and emission-reduction targets will crowd out green technology innovation and R&D investment [
15,
43]. The combined effect of extrusion and stimulation on green technology innovation is demonstrated in
Figure 1. The reduced cost of pollution management is within the enterprise’s budget during the early stages of environmental regulation. Simultaneously, the state emphasizes ecological protection, raising enterprise environmental awareness; and, due to “innovation compensation,” enterprises implement green technology innovations to offset costs and gain a first-mover advantage, implying that environmental regulation is beneficial. However, when environmental regulations become harsher, the stress associated with pollution control costs grows, and the innovation input exacerbates the cost. Meanwhile, businesses may face a situation where their innovation edge is dwindling, and competition is growing [
44]. In addition, as a result of the uncertainty surrounding innovation output and other features, businesses have reduced their drive to innovate, resulting in a slowdown in innovation compensation income growth. Thus, if the expense of pollution control exceeds the revenue generated by innovation compensation, further tightening environmental regulation is counterproductive [
26,
45,
46]. In other words, the effect of crowding out is more significant than the effect of incentives. The entire process exemplifies the relationship between environmental regulation and enterprise-led green technology innovation [
47,
48]. This paper presents hypothesis 1 based on the analysis presented above.
Hypothesis 1 (H1). There is an inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation.
Many factors influence the impact of environmental regulations on green technology innovation at the regional level, and these aspects are multifaceted. In terms of environmental conditions, environmental quality and regulatory rigor differ by area [
49]. Technically, there are also regional variances in industrial efficiency and pollution control approaches. Additionally, it cannot be disregarded that regional differences in economic development, industrial structure, energy consumption structure, and human capital exist. The disparate growth of different regions will affect the function of environmental regulation, which will affect green technology innovation in various locations. As a result, this article proposes the second hypothesis (H2).
Hypothesis 2 (H2). The impact of environmental regulations on green technology innovation varies by region.
Although environmental regulation, according to the Porter Hypothesis, will boost enterprise green technology innovation, it cannot be overlooked that the risks associated with technology innovation activities limit entrepreneurs’ enthusiasm for technology research and development [
32]. At this point, government intervention is critical in compensating for the expense of regulation to stimulate technological innovation [
34]. Increased government subsidies will foster green technology innovation under stronger environmental regulation [
10]. Additionally, according to the “threat-rigidity” theory, firms’ innovation activities tend to impose a financial burden on them, prompting them to pursue conservative R&D methods to avoid additional risks [
6,
7,
50]. Government direct subsidies lessen the capital constraint on innovative firms and boost their risk-bearing capacity [
37], and have an immediate and evident incentive effect on long-term innovation projects [
24]. Government R&D funding has a significant impact on enterprise green technology innovation [
8,
51]. Effective innovation input subsidies can assist businesses in covering expenses, enhancing their ability to manage risks, and then pursuing a first-mover advantage in the initial stage, hence increasing innovation output [
10]. Based on the foregoing analysis, this paper proposes hypothesis 3.
Hypothesis 3 (H3). Government subsidies have a mediating effect on the impact of environmental regulation and green technology innovation.
The relationship among environmental regulation, government subsidies, and green technology innovation is shown in
Figure 2.
4. Model Settings and Data Description
4.1. Model Settings
The purpose of this article was to examine the relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation, or, more precisely, to determine whether and how environmental regulation influences regional green technology innovation. As the relationship between the two is an inverted “U” in Hypothesis 1, the model includes the square of en_ru. The regression model (model 1), as described by Chen et al. (2019) [
10], is as follows:
where subscript
indicates province and
denotes time;
, and
. are the parameters to be estimated in the model;
denotes green technology innovation;
represents environmental regulation.
refers to all control variables including the size of regional industry, level of regional economic development, human capital, and foreign direct investment.
describes the individual fixed effect;
describes the time fixed effect;
and
denote the constant term and random error term, respectively. Based on the inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation, the coefficient of
. is expected to be negative.
In order to examine the regional heterogeneity of environmental regulations’ impact on green technology innovation, model 1 is regressed in groups.
This article introduces government subsidies as a mediator and adapts sequential regression models (models 2 and 3) to examine whether government subsidies have an intermediary influence on the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation. Thus, according to Kashdan and Breen (2007) [
52], the following models are proposed:
where
. denotes government subsidies. Due to the government subsidies that encourage enterprises to pursue a first-mover advantage in the initial stage, the coefficient of the square of
is expected to be negative, while the coefficient of interaction item is expected to be positive in model 3.
4.2. Data
To examine the impacts of the environmental regulation on green technology innovation and analyze the role of government subsidies, a balanced panel dataset of 25 provinces and 4 cities for 2003–2017 was utilized in this study. In addition, due to the uneven regional development in China, the 29 provinces (cities) were divided into eight regions, i.e., Beijing–Tianjin, North, Central, Central Coast, South Coast, Northwest, Southwest, and Northeast [
53,
54]. The detail of provinces (cities) in the eight regions are shown in
Table 1.
To avoid the influence of missing values, 435 samples were obtained by excluding Tibet, Qinghai, Hong Kong, Macao, and Taiwan. All the data used in this paper were taken from China Statistical Yearbook, China Science and Technology Statistical Yearbook, China Environment Statistical Yearbook, China Energy Statistical Yearbook, China Labor Statistical Yearbook, and China Industrial Statistical Yearbook.
The following is the description of the variables in this paper.
4.2.1. Dependent Variable
Green technology innovation. Green technology innovation is typically described in terms of innovation output indicators (such as the number of patents or the income generated by new products) or innovation input indicators (such as research and development input and investment in technological transformation funds). However, relying just on innovation output or input indicators fails to reflect “green.” On the other hand, output indicators can more adequately describe the transition from technology to innovation. Guo et al. (2018) [
25] expanded on Awasthi et al. (2010)’s [
55] and Yuan et al. (2010)’s [
56], definitions of green technology innovation by stating that green technology innovation may be classified into product innovation and technological process innovation [
57,
58,
59]. The term “new product” refers to an altogether novel concept developed employing a novel technical principle or design approach in this article. On the other hand, it includes advancements in design, material, and technology. As a result, the revenue earned by novel products accurately reflects the innovation in products and technological processes. In comparison to traditional innovation, green technology innovation places a higher premium on energy conservation and consumption reduction throughout the product’s life cycle and is committed to maximizing output per unit of energy consumed [
60,
61]. Thus, the output per unit of energy usage is frequently employed in research to quantify green technology advancement [
25]. As a result, to capture the “green” aspect of innovation output, this research uses the logarithm of innovation output per unit of energy consumption (new product sales revenue/total energy consumption) as the measurement index. The ratio means that the energy consumption, as input, drives the output of new product sales revenue, and can positively reflect green technology innovation. At the same time, the results in
Figure 3,
Figure 4 and
Figure 5 indicate that the index is affected by neither the price increase nor the reduction in energy consumption. The higher the index value, the greater the capacity for green technology innovation.
4.2.2. Independent Variable
Environmental regulation. There are numerous types of environmental regulation indices available at the moment. To define environmental regulation, some researchers began with the source of regulation, such as the change in the pollution emission baseline [
62] and the quantity of environmental regulation or law [
58]. However, as is frequently found in developing economies, the legislation does not always implement efficient environmental regulation. In other words, there is frequently a phenomenon known as “paper law” in those countries, showing a significant disconnect between legislation and enforcement [
63]. As a result, some scholars have turned to indicators that can accurately reflect the outcomes of environmental regulatory implementation, such as the cost of pollution control paid to specific trash [
64] and the quantity of pollution control investment made by the organization [
65]. In addition, Hernandez-Sancho et al. (2000) [
66] argued that the stronger the environmental regulation, the less pollution the enterprise will emit. Therefore, the pollutant emissions per unit of enterprise output [
67,
68] and the integrated pollutant removal efficiency index [
46,
63] become the proxy indicators for environmental regulation. Consequently, in terms of the selection of environmental regulation variables, this paper used the method of Yuan and Xie (2014) [
69] and Chen et al. (2019) [
10] to construct a comprehensive measurement system by using the ratio data of wastewater discharge, solid waste discharge, sulfur dioxide (SO
2), and soot emission to regional GDP. In other words, weights are assigned to different pollutants according to the formula,
.
represents the corresponding emissions of a certain pollutant in different regions in different years, and
represents the GDP of a certain region in corresponding years; then, the measures are normalized and reciprocal. The larger the index value, the stronger the degree of environmental regulation.
4.2.3. Intermediate Variable
Government subsidies. Most scholars have defined this indicator in terms of the amount of government assistance received by businesses during the present era. As a measurement index, the logarithm of government funds in internal R&D expenditures of industrial businesses is utilized. The expenditure of enterprise R&D funds is classified as internal and external. Internal expenditures include all costs incurred by the firm to conduct R&D activities. The term “external expenditure” refers to the amount paid to the enterprise for external research and development operations. Internal R&D expenditures are more directly tied to corporate development. Government grants in this category can indicate the government’s support for enterprise investment in green technology innovation: the greater the index value, the more robust the government’s support for corporate research and development.
4.2.4. Control Variables
Size of regional industry. The regional sewage discharge scale and governance capacity are closely related to the regional industrial scale, so we take it as one of the control variables. According to the National Bureau of Statistics of China, “above-scale” enterprise refers to an industrial legal entity with an annual income of CNY 20 million or more from its main business, and the reason why we use this indicator to measure regional industry size is that the output value of “above-scale” enterprises accounts for more than 90% of the total output value of provincial industrial enterprises, which plays a pivotal role in the provincial economy. Meanwhile, this part of the enterprise information data is also the focus of national statistics. Therefore, the number of above-scale industrial enterprises in each region after logarithm transformation is used to measure the regional industrial scale.
Level of regional economic development. The economic development level of each province is an important influencing factor of its regional green technology innovation ability. This paper uses the per capita GDP of 29 provinces to control the economic development difference of each province. The year 2000 is used as the base period, and the per capita gross domestic product over the years is deflated in order to counteract the effects of inflation.
Human capital. The human capital of each province has a significant difference. It is an important factor that affects the output of green technology innovation. This paper selects the number of years of education per capita as the proxy variable of human capital. According to the proportion of people in different stages of education, the corresponding number of years of education is empowered to obtain the number of years of education per capita.
Regional population. The population of each province is closely related to its economic and technological development. This indicator is the logarithm of the total population of a region.
Foreign direct investment. The more robust the green technology innovation, the more capable firms are of dealing with environmental regulations, and thus the more competitive enterprises are in attracting foreign investment [
49,
70]. The impact of foreign investment on firms’ green technology innovation should be controlled. As a result, the logarithm of foreign direct investment was utilized as the measuring index in this work.
Detailed descriptions of this study’s variables are also presented in
Table 2.
4.3. Descriptive Statistics
The descriptive statistics for variables are shown in
Table 3. The average value of green technological innovation (tec_ino) is found to be 7.016935, with a standard deviation of 1.272259. The general level of green technology innovation among industrial businesses greater than the scale of each province fluctuates slightly. Environmental regulation (en_ru) has a low standard deviation and an average, indicating that the general difference in environmental regulation is minimal. Government subsidies (gov-sub) have an average value of 12.36613 and a low standard deviation. Other control variables, such as regional economic development (per-GDP), the number of regional industries (size), and foreign direct investment (FDI), are relatively stable in aggregate (
Table 3).
To examine the influence of environmental regulation on green technology innovation across regions,
Figure 6 compares the mean of green technology innovation and environmental regulation in various regions. As illustrated in
Figure 6b, environmental regulation is more severe in Beijing and Tianjin, the central coast, and the southern coast than in other regions, although the distinction between environmental regulation in other regions is not entirely obvious. Similarly, as illustrated in
Figure 6a, Beijing and Tianjin, the central coast, and the southern coast all have a relatively high level of green technology innovation, followed by the northern and central regions. In contrast, the northeast and southwest regions outperform the northwest regions, basically consistent with the economic development. The level of green technology innovation varies significantly between regions when compared to environmental regulation. We can see from these figures that environmental regulation is also stricter in regions with a high level of green technology innovation. However, the relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation in various regions requires further verification.
5. Empirical Results and Analysis
5.1. Panel Unit Root Test and Cointegration Test
To avoid pseudo-regression, the LLC [
71] (Levin et al., 2002) and IPS [
72] tests were utilized in this research to examine whether the variables have a unit root. The result indicates that all variables are integrated on the order of zero, i.e., I (0), except for en_ru, which is integrated on the order of one, i.e., I (1). The panel data analyzed in this article are stable. Additionally, the cointegration test proves the existence of a cointegration relationship in long-run equilibrium by the use of the tests [
73,
74,
75].
5.2. Hausman Test
On the one hand, the data used in this article were provincial data from 2003 to 2017, which are relatively complete. Moreover, due to the distinct geopolitics of each province, some factors may be omitted that do not change over time. As a result, the fixed-effect model is appropriate for the data analysis in this work and also contributes to the consistency of estimation. Additionally, the F test
p value is 0.0000, indicating that the Hausman test results support the fixed-effect model’s suitability for the research [
9,
10].
5.3. Results
5.3.1. The Overall Impact of Environmental Regulation on Green Technology Innovation
As illustrated in
Table 4, panel regression was used to examine the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation. Increased regional green technology innovation may result in reduced pollutant emissions and a decrease in the level of environmental regulation. According to the study above, environmental regulation and green technology innovation are likely to have a mutual causal relationship. Endogeneity has an effect on the robustness of regression results. Our article argues that while regional environmental regulation is inextricably linked to provincial environmental regulation, regional environmental regulation cannot have a direct effect on provincial technology innovation. Thus, regional environmental regulation satisfies instrumental variable requirements. This research will further validate the fixed-effect results by utilizing regional environmental regulation as an instrumental variable. Column FE contains the regression findings for fixed effects, while column IV contains the regression results for instrumental variables.
Before examining the nonlinear relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation, this article examined the linear relationship between both, as illustrated in
Table 4, Column 1. Both the FE and IV regression results imply that environmental regulation promotes green technology innovation, but the sustainability of this relationship remains largely unknown. Column 2 of
Table 4 contains the regression results for Model 1. The coefficient of en_ru is positive, but the square term has a negative coefficient. Meanwhile, as illustrated in
Table 5, the
p-value for the Sasabuchi test of the inverse U-shape in PPC is 0.008, and the estimated extreme point (3.882) is within the 95% confidence interval. It demonstrates an inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation. Prior to the turning point, with the strengthening of environmental regulation, enterprises are forced to carry out green technology innovation and increase output. At this stage, the “innovation compensation effect” is dominant. Following the inflection point, when environmental regulation is strengthened further, the demand for businesses to sustain production increases, while the desire for innovation decreases. This tendency has demonstrated a greater degree of “innovative crowding-out effect”.
5.3.2. The Regional Impact of Environmental Regulation on Green Technology Innovation
Regression grouping was performed according to region, and the findings are summarized in
Table 6. The results of model 1’s regional regression reveal an inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation in the central region, a relationship that is also evident in the central coast region. Environmental regulation in these localities will incentivize firms to develop green technology innovations at an early stage. However, in the later stage, it will leave a burden to enterprises and diminish their innovative output. Compared to the center and central coast regions, the regression results indicate that the west’s environmental regulation and green technology innovation follow a “U” relationship. The reason could be that when environmental regulation is in its developing stage, cost pressures are relatively low, and government officials in the western region, for performance reasons, pay more attention to economic development indicators, implying a relative lack of environmental protection consciousness. Simultaneously, high-quality staff and other innovation resources are scarce, so they mainly rely on the extensive development pattern. As a result, when the western region of the enterprise is under the less stringent environmental regulation, they prefer to follow specific pollution spending to reduce pollutant emissions while squeezing some research and development funding rather than pursuing technology innovation. When environmental regulations become severe, the cost of pollution management will increase even more, compelling firms in the western region to achieve the goal of energy-saving and emission reduction through technology innovation. In the most economically developed (i.e., Beijing–Tianjin) and underdeveloped regions (i.e., Northwest and Northeast), the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation is not significant in these regions. The regression results indicate that the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation varies significantly by region.
5.3.3. The Mediating Effect of Government Subsidies
The regression results from models 2 and 3 imply that government subsidies play an intermediary role in the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation. As illustrated in
Table 7, environmental regulation affects green technology innovation by influencing government subsidies.
The results indicate a “U” relationship between environmental regulation and government subsidies in column 2 of
Table 7. After model fitting, we found that there is a positive correlation between environmental regulation and government subsidies when the value of environmental regulation is greater than 0. Thus, based on the practically meaningful part of the fitting results, with the strengthening of environmental regulation, the government may increase investment in subsidies.
The inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation is presented in Column 1 of
Table 7. Environmental regulation, before the inflection point, encourages green technology innovation through government subsidies. The strengthening of environmental regulation necessitates green technology innovation on the part of businesses. However, innovative efforts are associated with significant risks and lengthy durations, resulting in a lack of innovation motivation. As a result, government subsidies have become a critical instrument for stimulating enterprise innovation by effectively lowering the costs and risks associated with innovation. Additionally, the compensatory impact and first-mover advantage received by firms due to innovation will encourage enterprises to innovate further.
Following the inflection point, environmental regulation inhibits green technology innovation through government subsidies. Further investment in government subsidies may backfire as environmental regulation is strengthened. Excessive government subsidies would be squandered on various rent-seeking strategies [
76,
77]. Additionally, the ability of enterprises to transform their innovations affects the impact of government subsidies on green technology innovation [
78,
79]. When firms’ capacity for innovation transformation is exhausted, increasing government subsidies will have little effect on green technology innovation [
80]. Indeed, businesses cannot implement green technology innovation in this period just through government subsidies.
5.3.4. Further Research
According to the analysis of the regression results above, the present study indicates that environmental regulation has an inverted “U” relationship effect on green technology innovation. A robustness test was undertaken to further verify the conclusion. The logarithm of the annual number of invention patents granted in each province was used to determine the level of green technology innovation.
Table 8’s first column contains the results. The robustness test result agrees with the result in
Table 4. Environmental regulation’s primary term coefficient is positive, while its square term coefficient is negative, which is statistically significant at a 1% level of significance. The robustness test demonstrates that environmental regulation does have a considerable impact on green technology innovation. The inverted “U” relationship means green technology innovation can be accelerated during the earliest stages of environmental regulation strengthening.
6. Conclusions
The impact of environmental regulations on green technology innovation was examined in this article using data from China’s provincial panel from 2003 to 2017. Samples were grouped to investigate whether or not there is regional heterogeneity. The paper employed both a fixed effect and an intermediary effect model, and government subsidies were used as a mediating variable to examine the effect of government subsidies on green technology innovation. The following conclusions can be drawn from the findings:
Firstly, there is an inverted “U” relationship between environmental regulation and green technological innovation on a whole level. The pressure of rising pollutant discharge costs compels firms to invest in green technology innovation during the initial phase of environmental regulation strengthening. When environmental regulations are enforced further, enterprises face increased production pressure, resulting in diminished green technology innovation capacity and decreased output.
Secondly, because economic development levels vary at the regional level, the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation varies among regions. The results indicate an inverted U-shaped relationship between environmental regulation and green technology innovation in the eastern and central regions; environmental regulation initially stimulates and then inhibits green technology innovation. However, the relationship is more substantial in the East region. Given that the western and northeastern regions are developing, it is apparent that environmental regulation cannot stimulate green technology innovation. Even in the west, it will inhibit innovation in green technology innovation.
Thirdly, government subsidies have a mediating effect on the impact of environmental regulation on green technology innovation. Government subsidies assist by balancing R&D risk and lowering R&D costs. Enterprises will respond positively to environmental regulation if the government subsidizes them. They may carry out green technology innovation and scale-up innovation output. However, more government subsidies are not better sometimes. When environmental regulations are strengthened to a certain extent, government subsidies cannot drive enterprises to innovate.
To sum up, the following policy recommendations are put forward for reference:
To begin, environmental control cannot be completed overnight in China’s current stage, and relevant policies should not excessively pursue high standards. Prompt feedback on the efficacy of policies may be beneficial for policy implementation and improvement. It is possible to effectively enhance firms’ environmental regulation compliance and green technology innovation by gradually improving environmental regulation.
Second, environmental regulation policies should be implemented according to local conditions and the differences in regional economic development. It is necessary to develop appropriate environmental regulation policies in the economically developed eastern region and coastal region in order to promote green technology innovation of enterprises. Meanwhile, the developing region’s environmental regulation policy should be strengthened to improve the environmental protection consciousness of the western region of enterprises and make the innovative behavior strive to infinity. As a result, these underdeveloped regions will experience rapid economic and ecological development. Simultaneously, in the face of expanding environmental regulations, businesses can be incentivized to innovate by combining the characteristics of several policies, such as government subsidies and carbon trading permits.
Third, government subsidies are an effective means of regulating the environment. This policy combination can guide firms in the early stages of dealing with environmental regulation and increasing green technology innovation. At the same time, it should be highlighted that government subsidies are not a one-size-fits-all proposition and should be phased off gradually. Government subsidies come in a variety of forms. It is prudent to use them flexibly to encourage firms to innovate green technologies and avoid the negative consequences of blindly increasing subsidies.
However, further research questions require further discussion. First, due to data collecting constraints, this paper’s sample period spanned from 2003 to 2017. If additional data had been available, this article would have produced a more significant number of robust outcomes. Second, the paper focused exclusively on geographical disparities at the macro level, omitting the impact of micro-level variances in enterprise characteristics. The environmental regulation’s influence on green technology innovation needs to be thoroughly explored in order to provide a more practical and effective reference point for government policy reform. Third, we concur with some scholars in asserting that a region’s or country’s level of green technology innovation is contingent not only on its economic development but also on the structure of the productive regional system (what type of sectors predominate in the regional industry) [
81,
82,
83]. We did not validate this in our work, due to the difficulty in acquiring relevant data. However, a microscopic examination of the question is necessary to establish a direction for additional research.
Author Contributions
Conceptualization, P.W., C.D. and N.C.; methodology, N.C.; software, C.D. and S.Y.; validation, N.C., S.Y. and W.L.; formal analysis, P.W., C.D., N.C. and M.Q.; data curation, N.C. and S.Y.; writing—original draft preparation, P.W., N.C. and C.D.; writing—review and editing, P.W., C.D., M.Q., N.C., S.Y., A.B.N. and W.L.; visualization, N.C. and S.Y.; supervision, P.W., C.D. and M.Q.; project administration, P.W.; funding acquisition, M.Q. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.
Funding
This research was funded by National Social Science Foundation of China (20BJY233).
Institutional Review Board Statement
Not applicable.
Informed Consent Statement
Not applicable.
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
The authors declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship and/or publication of this article.
References
- Du, H. Research on the New Urbanization Transferring from Factor-Driven to Innovation-Driven. Reform. Strategy 2017, 1, 122–125. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Xi, J.P. Reports of 19th CPC National Congress; People’s Press: Beijing, China, 2017. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Li, J.Q.; Wang, C.Y. Impact of Environmental Regulation on Industrial Upgrading: Analysis Based on Panel Data of 30 Provinces in China. Meteorol. Environ. Res. 2020, 11, 21–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- GAO, K.; DU, Y.W.; LIU, Y.; Li, H. Prediction of coordinated development of marine eco-economic system in Tianjin under the background of building the leading maritime capitals of the world. J. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2021, 31, 171–180. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Porter, M.E.; Van Der Linde, C. Toward a New Conception of the Environment-Competitiveness Relationship. J. Econ. Perspect. 1995, 9, 97–118. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Staw, B.M.; Dutton, S.J.E. Threat Rigidity Effects in Organizational Behavior: A Multilevel Analysis. Adm. Q. 1981, 26, 501–504. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McKinley, W.; Latham, S.; Braun, M. Organizational Decline and Innovation: Turnarounds and Downward Spirals. Acad. Manag. Rev. 2014, 39, 88–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lach, S. Do R&D Subsidies Stimulate or Displace Private R&D? Evidence from Israel. J. Ind. Econ. 2002, 50, 369–390. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Sung, B. Do government subsidies promote firm-level innovation? Evidence from the Korean renewable energy technology industry. Energy Policy 2019, 132, 1333–1344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, X.; Li, M.L.; Zhang, Z.Z. Environmental Regulation, Government Subsidies and Green Technology Innovation——Empirical Research Based on the Mediation Effect Model. J. Ind. Technol. Econ. 2019, 38, 18–25. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Nelson, R.A.; Tietenberg, T.; Donihue, M.R. Differential Environmental Regulation: Effects on Electric Utility Capital Turnover and Emissions. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1993, 75, 368–373. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Walter, J.M. Comparing the effectiveness of market-based and choice-based environmental policy. J. Policy Model. 2020, 42, 173–191. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jiang, Z.; Wang, Z.; Zeng, Y. Can voluntary environmental regulation promote corporate technological innovation? Bus. Strat. Environ. 2019, 29, 390–406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jaffe, A.B.; Stavins, R.N. Dynamic Incentives of Environmental Regulations: The Effects of Alternative Policy Instruments on Technology Diffusion. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1995, 29, S43–S63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van Leeuwen, G.; Mohnen, P. Revisiting the Porter hypothesis: An empirical analysis of Green innovation for the Netherlands. Econ. Innov. New Technol. 2016, 26, 63–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Maryam, H.; Hossein, Z. Green product development and environmental performance: Investigating the role of government regulations. J. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2018, 204, 395–410. [Google Scholar]
- Yuan, B.; Xiang, Q. Environmental regulation, industrial innovation and green development of Chinese manufacturing: Based on an extended CDM model. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 176, 895–908. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Porter, M.E. America’s Green Strategy. Sci. Am. 1991, 264, 168. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jaffe, A.B.; Palmer, K. Environmental Regulation and Innovation: A Panel Data Study. Rev. Econ. Stat. 1997, 79, 610–619. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berrone, P.; Fosfuri, A.; Gelabert, L.; Gomez-Mejia, L.R. Necessity as the mother of ‘green’ inventions: Institutional pressures and environmental innovations. Strat. Manag. J. 2012, 34, 891–909. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qiu, L.D.; Zhou, M.; Wei, X. Regulation, innovation, and firm selection: The porter hypothesis under monopolistic competition. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2018, 92, 638–658. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mohr, L.A.; Webb, D.J.; Harris, K.E. Do Consumers Expect Companies to be Socially Responsible? The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Buying Behavior. J. Consum. Aff. 2001, 35, 45–72. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mulatu, A. Environmental regulation and international competitiveness: A critical review. Int. J. Glob. Environ. Issues 2018, 17, 41–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, L.J.; Zheng, X.F. Coupling induction of environmental regulation and government subsidy on enterprise technological innovation. Resour. Sci. 2017, 39, 911–923. [Google Scholar]
- Guo, Y.; Xia, X.; Zhang, S.; Zhang, D. Environmental Regulation, Government R&D Funding and Green Technology Innovation: Evidence from China Provincial Data. Sustainability 2018, 10, 940. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lou, Y.; Tian, Y.; Tang, X. Does Environmental Regulation Improve an Enterprise’s Productivity?—Evidence from China’s Carbon Reduction Policy. Sustainability 2020, 12, 6742. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grossman, G.; Helpman, E. Growth and Welfare in A Small Open Economy; NBER Working Papers: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1989. [Google Scholar]
- Romer, P.M. Endogenous Technological Change. J. Political Econ. 1990, 98, S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Grossman, G.M.; Helpman, E. Quality Ladders and Product Cycles. Q. J. Econ. 1991, 106, 557–586. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- De Long, J.B.; Summers, L.H. Equipment Investment and Economic Growth. Q. J. Econ. 1991, 106, 445–502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, W.; Zhang, R.; Chai, S. What Drives Green Innovation? A Game Theoretic Analysis of Government Subsidy and Cooperation Contract. Sustainability 2019, 11, 5584. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Nadiri, M.I. Innovations and Technological Spillovers; NBER Working Papers: Cambridge, MA, USA, 1993. [Google Scholar]
- Yang, R.; Tang, W.; Zhang, J. Technology improvement strategy for green products under competition: The role of government subsidy. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2020, 289, 553–568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arrow, K.J. The Economic Implications of Learning by Doing. Rev. Econ. Stud. 1971, 29, 131–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xin, S.U.; Zhou, S.S. Dual environmental regulation, government subsidy and enterprise innovation output. China Popul. Resour. Environ. 2019, 29, 31–39. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Wang, H.; Davidson, W.N.; Wang, X. The Sarbanes-Oxley Act and CEO tenure, turnover, and risk aversion. Q. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2010, 50, 367–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Falk, M. What drives business Research and Development (R&D) intensity across Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries? Appl. Econ. 2006, 38, 533–547. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hu, S.; Liu, S. Do the coupling effects of environmental regulation and R&D subsidies work in the development of green innovation? Empirical evidence from China. Clean Technol. Environ. Policy 2019, 21, 1739–1749. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jung, S.H.; Feng, T. Government subsidies for green technology development under uncertainty. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2020, 286, 726–739. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mohr, R.D. Environmental performance standards and the adoption of technology. Ecol. Econ. 2006, 58, 238–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sterner, T.; Turnheim, B. Innovation and diffusion of environmental technology: Industrial NOx abatement in Sweden under refunded emission payments. Ecol. Econ. 2009, 68, 2996–3006. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bergek, A.; Berggren, C. The impact of environmental policy instruments on innovation: A review of energy and automotive industry studies. Ecol. Econ. 2014, 106, 112–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Sinn, H.-W. Public policies against global warming: A supply side approach. Int. Tax Public Financ. 2008, 15, 360–394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, C.; Wang, T.; Guo, Q. Does Environmental Regulation Repress the International R&D Spillover Effect? Evidence from China. Sustainability 2019, 11, 4353. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- March, J.G.; Shapira, Z. Managerial Perspectives on Risk and Risk Taking. Manag. Sci. 1987, 33, 1404–1418. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Peng, X. Strategic interaction of environmental regulation and green productivity growth in China: Green innovation or pollution refuge? Sci. Total Environ. 2020, 732, 139200. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Weick, K.E. Theory Construction as Disciplined Imagination. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1989, 14, 516–531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Haans, R.F.J.; Pieters, C.; He, Z.-L. Thinking about U: Theorizing and testing U- and inverted U-shaped relationships in strategy research. Strat. Manag. J. 2015, 37, 1177–1195. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, W.; Li, G.; Uddin, K.; Guo, S. Environmental regulation, foreign investment behavior, and carbon emissions for 30 provinces in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 248, 119208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dan, J.L.; Payne, J.W.; Crum, R. Managerial Risk Preference for Below-Target Returns. Manag. Sci. 1980, 26, 1238–1249. [Google Scholar]
- Lichtenberg, F.R. The Private R&D Investment Response to Federal Design and Technical Competitions. Am. Econ. Rev. 1988, 78, 550–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kashdan, T.B.; Breen, W.E. Materialism and Diminished Well–Being: Experiential Avoidance as a Mediating Mechanism. J. Soc. Clin. Psychol. 2007, 26, 521–539. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Yi-Ming, W.; Meng, J.; Guan, D.; Shan, Y.; Song, M.; Wei, Y.-M.; Liu, Z.; Hubacek, K. Chinese CO2 emission flows have reversed since the global financial crisis. Nat. Commun. 2017, 8, 1712. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Z.; Li, Y.; Cai, H.; Yang, Y.; Wang, B. Regional difference and drivers in China’s carbon emissions embodied in internal trade. Energy Econ. 2019, 83, 217–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Awasthi, A.; Chauhan, S.S.; Goyal, S. A fuzzy multicriteria approach for evaluating environmental performance of suppliers. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2010, 126, 370–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, L.; Zhongfeng, S.; Yi, L. Can strategic flexibility help firms profit from product innovation? Technovation 2010, 30, 300–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Braun, E.; Wield, D. Regulation as a means for the social control of technology. Technol. Anal. Strat. Manag. 1994, 6, 259–272. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rennings, K.; Rammer, C. The Impact of Regulation-Driven Environmental Innovation on Innovation Success and Firm Performance. Ind. Innov. 2011, 18, 255–283. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Triguero, A.; Moreno-Mondéjar, L.; Davia, M.A. Drivers of different types of eco-innovation in European SMEs. Ecol. Econ. 2013, 92, 25–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sezen, B.; Çankaya, S.Y. Effects of Green Manufacturing and Eco-innovation on Sustainability Performance. Procedia-Soc. Behav. Sci. 2013, 99, 154–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wurlod, J.-D.; Noailly, J. The impact of green innovation on energy intensity: An empirical analysis for 14 industrial sectors in OECD countries. Energy Econ. 2018, 71, 47–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dasgupta, S.; Mody, A.; Roy, S.; Wheeler, D. Environmental Regulation and Development: A Cross-country Empirical Analysis. Oxf. Dev. Stud. 2001, 29, 173–187. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- He, W.; Tan, L.; Liu, Z.J.; Zhang, H. Property rights protection, environmental regulation and corporate financial performance: Revisiting the Porter Hypothesis. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 264, 121615. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cole, M.A.; Elliott, R.J.; Okubo, T. Trade, environmental regulations and industrial mobility: An industry-level study of Japan. Ecol. Econ. 2010, 69, 1995–2002. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Lanoie, P.; Patry, M.; Lajeunesse, R. Environmental regulation and productivity: Testing the porter hypothesis. J. Prod. Anal. 2008, 30, 121–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hernandez-Sancho, F.; Picazo-Tadeo, A.J.; Reig-Martinez, E. Efficiency and Environmental Regulation. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2000, 15, 365–378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cole, M.A.; Elliott, R. Do Environmental Regulations Influence Trade Patterns? Testing Old and New Trade Theories. World Econ. 2003, 26, 1163–1186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Domazlicky, B.R.; Weber, W.L. Does Environmental Protection Lead to Slower Productivity Growth in the Chemical Industry? Environ. Resour. Econ. 2004, 28, 301–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, Y.; Xie, R. Environmental regulation and industrial green productivity growth: A Reexamination of “Strong Porter Hypothesis”. China Soft Sci. 2016, 7, 144–154. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Li, G.X.; Zhang, W.; Wang, Y.J.; Business, S.O.; Jinan, U.O. OFDI, Environmental Regulation and Green Technology Innovation in China. Sci. Technol. Manag. Res. 2016, 36, 227–231. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Levin, A.; Lin, C.-F.; Chu, C.-S.J. Unit root tests in panel data: Asymptotic and finite-sample properties. J. Econ. 2002, 108, 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Im, K.S.; Pesaran, M.; Shin, Y. Testing for unit roots in heterogeneous panels. J. Econ. 2003, 115, 53–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kao, C. Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. J. Econ. 1999, 90, 1–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pedroni, P. Panel cointegration: Asymptotic and finite sample properties of pooled time series tests with an application to the ppp hypothesis. Econ. Theory 2004, 20, 597–625. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Westerlund, J. New Simple Tests for Panel Cointegration. Econ. Rev. 2005, 24, 297–316. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wei, J.; Zuo, Y. The certification effect of R&D subsidies from the central and local governments: Evidence from China. R D Manag. 2018, 48, 615–626. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, H.; Hu, S. The impact of synergy effect between government subsidies and slack resources on green technology innovation. J. Clean. Prod. 2020, 274, 122682. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cohen, W.M.; Levinthal, D. Innovation and Learning: The Two Faces of R&D. Econ. J. 1989, 99, 569–596. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Graevenittz, G. Spillovers Reconsidered: How Optimal R&D Subsidies Depend on the Spillover Process; Department of Economics, University College London: London, UK; Mimeo: New York, NY, USA, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Guisado-González, M.; González-Blanco, J.; Coca-Pérez, J.L.; Guisado-Tato, M. Assessing the relationship between R&D subsidy, R&D cooperation and absorptive capacity: An investigation on the manufacturing Spanish case. J. Technol. Transf. 2017, 43, 1647–1666. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Henriques, I.; Sadorsky, P. The Determinants of an Environmentally Responsive Firm: An Empirical Approach. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 1996, 30, 381–395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tilt, C.A. Environmental policies of major companies: Australian evidence. Br. Account. Rev. 1997, 29, 367–394. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Burgos Jíménez, J.; Céspedes Lorente, J.J. La protección ambiental y el resultado. Un análisis crítico de su relación. Eur. Res. Manag. Bus. Econ. 2001, 7, 93–108. [Google Scholar]
| Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).