A Novel Measure of Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Related Literature
3. Data and Variables
- DomCrdbyFin: domestic credit provided by the financial sector as a percentage of GDP;
- LogCellphones: natural log of mobile cellular subscriptions per 100 people;
- CapForm: gross fixed capital formation as a percentage of GDP;
- Trade: the sum of exports of goods and services (as a percentage of GDP) and imports of goods and services (as a percentage of GDP);
- LogGDP_PerCap10: the natural log of GDP per capita in constant 2010 US dollars;
- Infl_deflator: the annual GDP deflator in percentage;
- NatAgric: the sum of fuel exports, agricultural raw materials exports and ores and metals exports as a percentage of merchandise exports of a country. A country is classified as natural resource exporting if this variable is greater than or equal to 50%.
4. Empirical Methodology and Results
4.1. Fama-Macbeth-Type Regressions
- Let us compare Guinea Bissau, the country with the second worst corruption score in Sub-Saharan Africa to Botswana, the least corrupt in 2015 with normalized corruption scores of 0.016 and 0.679 respectively. An improvement in corruption from the level of Guinea Bissau to that of Botswana will increase FDI by approximately 2.49%, i.e., . The above potential increase in net FDI flows is economically significant. For example, according to the 2017 World Investment Report published by UNCTAD, net FDI flows to Guinea Bissau increased by approximately 5.3% from 2015 to 2016. Another 2.5% increase in net FDI flows due to an improvement in their corruption score would have increased FDI flows to Guinea Bissau by almost 50%.
- Let us compare Zimbabwe, the second worst-performing country in Sub-Saharan Africa in terms of rights and freedoms to Ghana, the second best-performing country in 2015 with normalized rights and freedom scores of 0.112 and 0.782, respectively. An improvement in rights and freedoms from the level of Zimbabwe to that of Ghana will increase FDI by approximately 3.12%, i.e., .
- Finally, let us compare Swaziland, the second worst performing country in Sub-Saharan Africa in terms of political constraints to South Africa, the third best-performing country in 2015 with normalized political constraint scores of 0.031 and 0.590, respectively. An improvement in political constraints from the level of Swaziland to that of South Africa will increase FDI by approximately 2%, i.e., .
4.2. Dynamic Panel Data Regressions
4.3. Informational Content of the Political Stability Index
- Models [1] and [2] include PolStability and PR_ICRG, respectively separately while model [3] includes both of them. We find that including the measures separately, the coefficient on both are statistically significant at the 1% level. When we include both measures in the same regressions, the coefficient on the political stability index is positive and statistically significant at the 1% level while that of PR_ICRG is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level. While the results so far are encouraging for our political stability index, we carry out further tests to determine whether it contains unique information.
- In Model [4] we start by estimating OLS regressions with PolStability as the dependent variable and PR_ICRG as the independent variable by year from 2000 to 2015 and we save the predicted values and the residual (both are orthogonal). Next, we include the predicted values and residuals in model [4]. The predicted values should have political risk information that is common to both risk measures while the residuals should have political risk information that is unique to the political stability index proposed in this study. The coefficient on the residual is positive (3.478) and significant at the 1% level and it is the same coefficient on the PolStability variable in model [3]. The coefficient of the predicted values is also positive and statistically significant. This would suggest that although the common information set between this paper’s political stability index and the ICRG’s political risk rating does explain net FDI inflows, the unique and incremental information contained in the political stability index has the ability to explain net FDI flows beyond that explained by the ICRG’s political risk index.
- Similarly in Model [5], we start by estimating OLS regressions with PR_ICRG as the dependent variable and PolStability as the independent variable by year from 2000 to 2015 and we save the predicted values and the residual (both are orthogonal). Next, we include the predicted values and residuals in model [5]. The predicted values should have political risk information that is common to both risk measures while the residuals should have political risk information that is unique to PR_ICRG. This time the coefficient on the predicted value is positive and significant at the 1% level while the coefficient on the residual is positive and significant at the 5% level.
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
The Political Stability Index
- Center for Systemic Peace
- Corruption Perceptions Index—Transparency International
- Database of Political Institutions—World Bank (Beck et al. 2001; Keefer and Stasavage 2003; Pagano and Volpin 2005)
- Ethnic and Cultural Diversity by Country (Fearon 2003)
- Fractionalization (Alesina et al. 2003)
- Fragile States Index—Fund for Peace
- Freedom of the World—Freedom House
- Global Terrorism Index—Vision of Humanity
- Human Development Index—United Nations Development Program
- Index of Economic Freedom—Heritage Foundation
- Press Freedom—Reporters Sans Frontières
- Political Terror Scale Dataset (Gibney 2002)
- The Cingranelli-Richards (CIRI) human rights dataset (Cingranelli and Richards 2010)
- The Quality of Government Institute (Dahlberg et al. 2017)
- The Political Constraint Index (POLCON) Dataset (Henisz 2000)
- The Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) project
- Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project (Coppedge et al. 2016)
- World Development Indicators (WDI)—World Bank
- Conflict and Violence: The Conflict and Violence Subcomponent focuses on: (1) the existence of, (2) the likelihood of, and (3) the residual effect of past conflict and violence in a country (both internally and externally) and in surrounding countries. It includes the following:
- The perception of the likelihood of politically-motivated violence, including terrorism
- The fractionalization of the country’s territory
- The state’s capacity to manage conflict
- The incidence of terrorism
- The country’s involvement in international war and violence
- Civil violence, civil war, ethnic violence and ethnic war involving the state
- Conflict and violence in bordering states
- Political terror including political imprisonment, political torture and political disappearance.
- Corruption: The Corruption subcomponent measures the extent of corruption in a political system. It is based on the perceived level of corruption and the prevalence of political corruption within the executive, legislative and judiciary branches. It captures different facets of corruption including bribery, embezzlement, exercise of power for private gain and the influence of the law making process and the exercise of law.
- Ethnocultural Fragilities: The Ethnocultural Fragilities subcomponent focuses on ethnic, linguistic, religious and other cultural fractionalization. It is based on cultural distances across different ethnic, linguistic and religious groups as well as the likelihood of people being from different ethnic, linguistic and religious groups within a country.
- Political Constraints: The Political Constraints subcomponent focuses on the presence and effectiveness of checks and balances as well as the independence of the branches of government within a political system. It is based on constraints on the executive, entrenchment of the executive, control or influence of the legislature by the ruling party, the effectiveness of the opposition in the legislature, independence of the judiciary, electoral competitiveness and the overall quality and extent of democracy.
- Quality of Political Governance: The Quality of Political Governance subcomponent reflects the people’s perception of how confident they are in their government’s capacity to provide quality public and civil services, the ability of the government to formulate and implement policies that can foster private sector growth and confidence in their government guaranteeing the rule of law.
- Rights and Freedom: The Rights and Freedom subcomponent focuses on the availability and protection of human rights, political rights and civil liberties. It includes:
- Freedom of speech and of expression
- Freedom of belief and religion
- Freedom of the press
- Freedom of academic and cultural expression
- The rule of law and access to justice
- Freedom from torture and executions
- Freedom of assembly and association (in political parties, trade unions, cultural organizations, or other special-interest groups and organizations)
- The ability to participate freely in the political process (including the right to vote freely in legitimate elections, compete for public office, and elect representatives who are accountable to the electorate)
- Personal autonomy without interference from the state, freedom of domestic and foreign movement, and freedom from political killings.
- Welfare and Socioeconomic Conditions: The Welfare and Socioeconomic Conditions subcomponent is based on the interaction of living standards, poverty levels, income disparities and availability and access to social welfare programs.
Australia | Finland | Luxembourg | Sweden |
Austria | France | Netherlands | Switzerland |
Belgium | Germany | New Zealand | United Kingdom |
Canada | Greece | Norway | United States |
Cyprus | Ireland | Portugal | |
Denmark | Italy | Spain |
Argentina | Costa Rica | Guatemala | Paraguay |
Bolivia | Cuba | Honduras | Peru |
Brazil | Dominican Republic | Mexico | Uruguay |
Chile | Ecuador | Nicaragua | Venezuela |
Colombia | El Salvador | Panama |
Albania | Estonia | Macedonia | Slovenia |
Armenia | Georgia | Moldova | Tajikistan |
Azerbaijan | Hungary | Mongolia | Turkmenistan |
Belarus | Kazakhstan | Poland | Ukraine |
Bulgaria | Kyrgyzstan | Romania | Uzbekistan |
Croatia | Latvia | Russia | |
Czech Republic | Lithuania | Slovakia |
China | Laos | Thailand | Pakistan |
Japan | Malaysia | Vietnam | Sri Lanka |
South Korea | Myanmar | Bangladesh | Papua New Guinea |
Cambodia | Philippines | India | |
Indonesia | Singapore | Nepal |
Algeria | Jordan | Oman | Turkey |
Bahrain | Kuwait | Qatar | UAE |
Egypt | Lebanon | Saudi Arabia | Yemen |
Iran | Libya | Syria | |
Israel | Morocco | Tunisia |
Angola | Djibouti | Madagascar | Sierra Leone |
Benin | Equatorial Guinea | Malawi | South Africa |
Botswana | Ethiopia | Mali | Sudan |
Burkina Faso | Gabon | Mauritania | Swaziland |
Burundi | Gambia | Mauritius | Tanzania |
Cameroon | Ghana | Mozambique | Togo |
Central African Republic | Guinea | Namibia | Uganda |
Chad | Guinea-Bissau | Niger | Zambia |
Congo Brazzaville | Kenya | Nigeria | Zimbabwe |
Congo Kinshasa | Lesotho | Rwanda | |
Cote D’Ivoire | Liberia | Senegal |
Guyana |
Haiti |
Jamaica |
Suriname |
Trinidad |
1 | As Busse and Hefeker (2007) point out, this result aligns with the findings of some studies that examine the linkages between ethnic tensions and economic growth. These studies, e.g., Easterly and Levine (1997), suggest that a high degree of conflicts attributable to racial nationality and language divisions might negatively affect economic development on average. |
2 | For instance, there are several papers on how democracy, law and order, government stability and the other political risk metrics affect FDI [e.g., Asiedu (2006); Asiedu and Lien (2011); Ali et al. (2010); Wei (2000)], yet very little has been said on how the degree of ethnocultural fractionalization influences FDI decisions of multinationals. |
3 | For example, see pages 57 to 60. |
4 | This is because people may tend to identify more with their group instead of with the society as a whole. They may be inclined to dislike other groups even if such disharmony may not tip over into an all-out civil war. |
5 | The argument is democratic institutions may have a positive impact on FDI because democracy provides checks and balances on elected officials and therefore reduces arbitrary government intervention, lowers the risk of policy reversal and strengthens property rights protection. |
6 | Li and Resnick (2003) argue that autocratic governments may be in a better position to provide more generous incentive packages and offer protection from labor unions since autocratic governments are not accountable to the citizens. |
7 | The number of forced changes in the top government; number of politically motivated assassinations or attempted assassinations of a high government official; and the number of illegal or forced changes in the ruling government. |
8 | See pages 222–25 of UNCTAD World Investment Report 2017 (https://unctad.org/webflyer/world-investment-report-2017, accessed date 4 June 2021). |
9 | Out of curiosity, we also test for non-linearity in other sub-components of the political stability index by introducing quadratic terms and interact their quadratic terms with natural resource variable, but they are insignificant. |
10 | The results on the control variables hold and the full estimation results are available from the authors upon request. |
11 | The results on the control variables hold and the full estimation results are available from the authors upon request. |
12 | Appendix A provides information on the sub-components of the political stability index and the data sources from which the index is constructed. Further information on how the index is constructed is available upon request from the authors. |
13 | Bahamas, Brunei, Hong Kong, Iceland, Iraq, North Korea, Malta, Serbia, Somalia, and Taiwan. |
14 | Benin, Burundi, Cambodia, Central African Republic, Chad, Djibouti, Equatorial Guinea, Georgia, Kyrgyzstan, Laos, Lesotho, Macedonia, Mauritania, Mauritius, Nepal, Rwanda, Swaziland, Tajikistan, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan. |
15 | The following 13 countries are not included in this study since they do not have the required FDI data and other control variables leaving us with 137 countries: Congo Kinshasa, Cuba, Djibouti, Dominican Republic, Ethiopia, Myanmar, Nepal, Qatar, Romania, Sudan, Syria, Turkmenistan, and Uzbekistan. |
References
- Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, James Robinson, and Pierre Yared. 2005. From education to democracy? The American Economic Review 95: 44–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Akbar, Mashfique Ibne, and Mashrur Mustaque Khan. 2013. The Impact of Political Risk on Foreign Direct Investment. International Journal of Economics and Finance 5: 147–56. [Google Scholar]
- Alesina, Alberto, Arnaud Devleeschauwer, William Easterly, Sergio Kurlat, and Romain Wacziarg. 2003. Fractionalization. Journal of Economic Growth 8: 155–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ali, Fathi, Norbert Fiess, and Ronald MacDonald. 2010. Do institutions matter for foreign direct investment? Open Economies Review 21: 201–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58: 277–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Asiedu, Elizabeth. 2002. On the determinants of foreign direct investment to developing countries: Is Africa different? World Development 30: 107–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Asiedu, Elizabeth. 2006. Foreign direct investment in Africa: The role of natural resources, market size, government policy, institutions and political instability. The World Economy 29: 63–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Asiedu, Elizabeth, and Donald Lien. 2011. Democracy, foreign direct investment and natural resources. Journal of International Economics 84: 99–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Beck, Thorsten, George Clarke, Alberto Groff, Philip Keefer, and Patrick Walsh. 2001. New tools in comparative political economy: The Database of Political Institutions. World Bank Economic Review 15: 165–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Blundell, Richard, and Stephen Bond. 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Journal of Econometrics 87: 115–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Blundell, Richard, Stephen Bond, and Frank Windmeijer. 2003. Estimation in Dynamic Panel Data Models: Improving on the Performance of the Standard GMM Estimator. Nonstationary Panels, Panel Cointegration, and Dynamic Panels, edited by Badi Baltagi. Advances in Econometrics 15: 53–91. [Google Scholar]
- Bobba, Matteo, and Decio Coviello. 2007. Weak instruments and weak identification, in estimating the effects of education, on democracy. Economics Letters 96: 301–6. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bowsher, Clive. 2002. On testing overidentifying restrictions in dynamic panel data models. Economics Letters 77: 211–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Busse, Matthias, and Carsten Hefeker. 2007. Political risk, institutions and foreign direct investment. European Journal of Political Economy 23: 397–415. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cingranelli, David L., and David L. Richards. 2010. The Cingranelli and Richards (CIRI) human rights data project. Human Rights Quarterly 32: 401–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Collier, Paul, Vl Elliot, Havard Hegre, Anke Hoeffler, Marta Reynal-Querol, and Nicholas Sambanis. 2003. Breaking the Conflict Trap. Civil War and Development Policy. A World Bank Policy Research Report. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Coppedge, M., J. Gerring, S. I. Lindberg, S.-E. Skaaning, J. Teorell, D. Altman, M. Bernhard, M. M. S. Fish, A. Glynn, A. Hicken, and et al. 2016. V-Dem [Country-Year/Country-Date] Dataset v6.2. Varieties of Democracy (V-Dem) Project. Available online: https://www.v-dem.net/en/data/archive/previous-data/data-version-6-2/ (accessed on 4 June 2021).
- Cukierman, Alex, Sebastian Edwards, and Guido Tabellini. 1989. Seigniorage and Political Instability. National Bureau of Economic Research No. w3199. Cambridge: Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- Dahlberg, Stefan, Sören Holmberg, Bo Rothstein, Anna Khomenko, and Richard Svensson. 2017. The Quality of Government Basic Dataset, Version Jan17. University of Gothenburg, The Quality of Government Institute. Available online: http://www.qog.pol.gu.se (accessed on 4 June 2021). [CrossRef]
- Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 1997. Africa’s Growth Tragedy: Policies and Ethnic Divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics 112: 1203–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Edwards, Sebastian. 1990. Capital Flows, Foreign Direct Investment, and Debt-Equity Swaps in Developing Countries. National Bureau of Economic Research No. w3497. Cambridge: Bureau of Economic Research. [Google Scholar]
- Fearon, James. 2003. Ethnic and cultural diversity by country. Journal of Economic Growth 8: 195–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gastanaga, Victor, Jeffrey Nugent, and Bistra Pashamova. 1998. Host country reforms and FDI inflows: How much difference do they make? World Development 26: 1299–314. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gellner, Ernest. 1991. Nationalism and politics in Eastern Europe. New Left Review 189: 127–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gibney, Mark. 2002. Political Terror Scales Dataset. Asheville: University of North Carolina at Asheville. [Google Scholar]
- Habib, Mohsin, and Leon Zurawicki. 2002. Corruption and Foreign Direct Investment. Journal of International Business Studies 33: 291–307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hayakawa, Kazunobu, Fukunari Kimura, and Hyun-Hoon Lee. 2013. How Does Country Risk Matter for Foreign Direct Investment? The Developing Economies 51: 60–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Henisz, Witold. 2000. The Institutional Environment for Economic Growth. Economics and Politics 12: 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Karolyi, Andrew. 2015. Cracking the Emerging Markets Enigma. Oxford: Oxford University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Keefer, Philip, and David Stasavage. 2003. The Limits of Delegation: Veto Players, Central Bank Independence and the Credibility of Monetary Policy. American Political Science Review 97: 407–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Li, Quan. 2009. Democracy, autocracy, and expropriation of foreign direct investment. Comparative Political Studies 42: 1098–127. [Google Scholar]
- Li, Quan, and Adam Resnick. 2003. Reversal of fortunes: Democratic institutions and FDI inflows to developing countries. International Organization 57: 175–211. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Loree, David, and Stephen Guisinger. 1995. Policy and non-policy determinants of US equity foreign direct investment. Journal of International Business Studies 26: 281–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Montalvo, Jose, and Marta Reynal-Querol. 2002. Why Ethnic Fractionalization? Polarization, Ethnic Conflict and Growth. UPF Economics and Business Working Paper 660. [Google Scholar]
- Noorbakhsh, Farhad, Alberto Paloni, and Ali Youssef. 2001. Human Capital and FDI inflows to Developing Countries: New Empirical Evidence. World Development 29: 1593–610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- North, Douglass, and Barry Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and Commitment: The evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth-century England. Journal of Economic History 49: 803–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Pagano, Marco, and Paolo Volpin. 2005. The political economy of corporate governance. The American Economic Review 95: 1005–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sambanis, Nicholas. 2001. Do ethnic and non-ethnic civil wars have the same causes? Journal of Conflict Resolution 45: 259–82. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Vanhanen, Tatu. 1999. Domestic ethnic conflict and ethnic nepotism: A comparative analysis. Journal of Peace Research 36: 55–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wei, Shang-Jin. 2000. How Taxing is corruption on international investors? The Review of Economics and Statistics 82: 1–11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
All | Non Natural Resource | Natural Resource | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Countries | Exporting Countries | Exporting Countries | ||||
Variables | Mean | Std. Dev. | Mean | Std. Dev. | Mean | Std. Dev. |
FDI | 4.923 | 10.324 | 5.148 | 11.385 | 4.316 | 6.641 |
PolStability | 0.515 | 0.258 | 0.563 | 0.257 | 0.389 | 0.212 |
Corruption | 0.397 | 0.269 | 0.433 | 0.272 | 0.303 | 0.235 |
EthnoCultural | 0.523 | 0.252 | 0.525 | 0.244 | 0.519 | 0.273 |
RightsFreedom | 0.583 | 0.256 | 0.630 | 0.249 | 0.460 | 0.233 |
PolConstraints | 0.507 | 0.265 | 0.556 | 0.259 | 0.378 | 0.233 |
ConflictViol | 0.619 | 0.231 | 0.655 | 0.230 | 0.522 | 0.203 |
WelfareSocioEco | 0.576 | 0.265 | 0.598 | 0.257 | 0.519 | 0.276 |
GvceQuality | 0.474 | 0.251 | 0.516 | 0.252 | 0.365 | 0.212 |
DomCrdtoPriv | 49.902 | 45.630 | 57.099 | 48.868 | 31.114 | 28.231 |
LogCellphones | 3.644 | 1.515 | 3.761 | 1.389 | 3.338 | 1.766 |
CapForm | 22.685 | 8.336 | 23.009 | 8.436 | 21.790 | 7.995 |
Trade | 88.092 | 50.457 | 92.437 | 55.077 | 76.494 | 32.590 |
LogGDP_PerCap10 | 8.452 | 1.563 | 8.539 | 1.570 | 8.222 | 1.520 |
Infl_deflator | 7.129 | 14.415 | 6.256 | 10.029 | 9.430 | 21.992 |
NatRscWagric | 31.053 | 28.806 | - | - | - | - |
FDI | PolStability | Corruption | EthnoCultural | RightsFreedom | PolConstraints | ConflictViol | WelfareSocioEco | GvceQuality | DomCrdtoPriv | LogCellphones | CapForm | Trade | LogGDP_PerCap10 | Infl_deflator | NatRscWagric | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
FDI | 1.000 | |||||||||||||||
PolStability | 0.070 | 1.000 | ||||||||||||||
Corruption | 0.085 | 0.834 | 1.000 | |||||||||||||
EthnoCultural | −0.015 | −0.040 | −0.028 | 1.000 | ||||||||||||
RightsFreedom | 0.076 | 0.960 | 0.710 | −0.025 | 1.000 | |||||||||||
PolConstraints | 0.040 | 0.963 | 0.708 | −0.040 | 0.940 | 1.000 | ||||||||||
ConflictViol | 0.089 | 0.829 | 0.782 | −0.084 | 0.756 | 0.705 | 1.000 | |||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | 0.041 | 0.676 | 0.721 | −0.186 | 0.524 | 0.549 | 0.702 | 1.000 | ||||||||
GvceQuality | 0.086 | 0.872 | 0.930 | −0.052 | 0.749 | 0.745 | 0.812 | 0.796 | 1.000 | |||||||
DomCrdtoPriv | 0.065 | 0.628 | 0.708 | −0.016 | 0.518 | 0.521 | 0.557 | 0.651 | 0.748 | 1.000 | ||||||
LogCellphones | 0.069 | 0.394 | 0.440 | −0.081 | 0.335 | 0.315 | 0.433 | 0.430 | 0.417 | 0.437 | 1.000 | |||||
CapForm | 0.183 | 0.008 | 0.034 | −0.078 | −0.016 | −0.027 | 0.098 | 0.120 | 0.050 | 0.057 | 0.183 | 1.000 | ||||
Trade | 0.340 | 0.100 | 0.216 | 0.029 | 0.057 | −0.011 | 0.310 | 0.214 | 0.226 | 0.132 | 0.180 | 0.225 | 1.000 | |||
LogGDP_PerCap10 | 0.058 | 0.708 | 0.790 | −0.149 | 0.564 | 0.576 | 0.745 | 0.904 | 0.815 | 0.686 | 0.573 | 0.109 | 0.253 | 1.000 | ||
Infl_deflator | −0.004 | −0.215 | −0.207 | 0.032 | −0.202 | −0.186 | −0.202 | −0.127 | −0.240 | −0.224 | −0.228 | −0.060 | −0.009 | −0.156 | 1.000 | |
NatRscWagric | −0.038 | −0.413 | −0.304 | 0.055 | −0.410 | −0.414 | −0.311 | −0.201 | −0.366 | −0.308 | −0.134 | −0.063 | −0.152 | −0.146 | 0.110 | 1.000 |
Dependent Variable = FDI | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | [6] | [7] | [8] | [9] | ||
Intercept | 5.141 | 1.885 | 5.764 | 5.629 | 3.834 | 4.342 | 4.751 | 2.663 | 5.419 | |
Financial Devt | DomCrdtoPriv (+) | 0.01 | 0.006 | 0.01 | 0.016 | 0.01 | 0.012 | 0.015 | 0.016 | 0.009 |
Infrastructure | LogCellphones (+) | −1.502 | −1.449 * | −1.276 | −1.661 | −1.577 | −1.443 | −1.547 | −1.297 | −1.496 |
CapForm (+) | 0.135 ** | 0.140 ** | 0.132 ** | 0.128 ** | 0.139 ** | 0.135 ** | 0.127 ** | 0.132 ** | 0.128 ** | |
Trade | Trade (+) | 0.068 *** | 0.073 *** | 0.066 *** | 0.068 *** | 0.068 *** | 0.070 *** | 0.067 ** | 0.067 ** | 0.066 *** |
Mkt size/attractives | LogGDP_PerCap10 (+) | −0.684 ** | −0.193 | −0.714 *** | −0.307 | −0.545 * | −0.568 ** | −0.376 * | −0.114 | −0.607 *** |
Overall economic stability | Infl_deflator (−) | 0.042 ** | 0.046 *** | 0.034 *** | 0.021 * | 0.041 ** | 0.036 ** | 0.025 ** | 0.018 | 0.041 *** |
Political Risk—Composite | PolStability | 4.740 *** | ||||||||
Political Risk Components | Corruption | 1.972 | 3.761 *** | |||||||
EthnoCultural | −1.185 | −0.854 | ||||||||
RightsFreedom | 10.877 *** | 4.655 *** | ||||||||
PolConstraints | −3.840 ** | 3.604 *** | ||||||||
ConflictViol | −6.511 *** | 1.171 | ||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | −0.536 | −1.349 | ||||||||
GvceQuality | 0.453 | 3.914 *** | ||||||||
N = # of years | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | |
Total Sample Size | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 |
Dependent Variable = FDI | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | [6] | [7] | [8] | [9] | ||
Intercept | 3.352 | 4.715 | 3.582 | 7.231 | 1.791 | 3.004 | 2.942 | 0.213 | 3.594 | |
Financial Devt | DomCrdtoPriv (+) | 0.011 | 0.008 | 0.007 | 0.014 | 0.012 | 0.012 | 0.011 | 0.008 | 0.004 |
Infrastructure | LogCellphones (+) | −1.58 | −1.939 | −1.351 | −2.357 * | −1.63 | −1.676 | −1.972 | −1.717 * | −1.488 |
CapForm (+) | 0.097 | 0.090 * | 0.097 | 0.101 | 0.103 | 0.095 | 0.09 | 0.091 | 0.089 | |
Trade | Trade (+) | 0.068 *** | 0.071 *** | 0.064 *** | 0.067 *** | 0.068 *** | 0.069 *** | 0.065 *** | 0.065 *** | 0.063 *** |
Mkt size/ attractives | LogGDP_PerCap10 (+) | −0.499 | −0.281 | −0.452 ** | 0.164 | −0.413 | −0.256 | 0.114 | 0.316 | −0.493 ** |
Overall economic stability | Infl_deflator (−) | 0.026 | 0.061 | 0.021 | 0.023 | 0.027 | 0.018 | 0.011 | 0.008 | 0.036 |
NatRscWagric | 0.052 *** | −0.040 * | 0.055 *** | −0.058 *** | 0.056 *** | 0.037 *** | 0.037 *** | 0.042 *** | 0.057 *** | |
Political Risk—Composite | PolStability | 6.203 *** | ||||||||
natAg_PolStab | −0.056 ** | |||||||||
Political Risk sub index | Corruption | 11.183 * | 6.416 *** | |||||||
natAg_Corrupt | −0.426 *** | −0.105 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCultural | −4.206 | −5.898 ** | ||||||||
EthnoCulturalsq | −0.835 | 0.96 | ||||||||
natAg_EthnoCul | 0.268 *** | 0.241 *** | ||||||||
natAg_EthnoCulSq | −0.178 ** | −0.143 *** | ||||||||
RightsFreedom | 20.687 * | 6.554 *** | ||||||||
natAg_RghtFree | −0.167 | −0.053 ** | ||||||||
PolConstraints | −11.358 | 3.816 *** | ||||||||
natAg_PolCons | 0.124 | −0.029 | ||||||||
ConflictViol | −10.984 * | 1.638 | ||||||||
natAg_ConfViol | 0.106 | −0.035 | ||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | −0.195 | 1.246 | ||||||||
natAg_SocEcWelf | 0.035 | −0.048 *** | ||||||||
GvceQuality | −2.032 | 7.484 *** | ||||||||
natAg_GovQual | 0.247 | −0.082 *** | ||||||||
N = # of years | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | |
Total Sample Size | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 | 1984 |
Panel a: Difference GMM | ||||||||||
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | [6] | [7] | [8] | [9] | ||
Political Risk—Composite | PolStability | 11.853 *** | ||||||||
Political Risk Components | Corruption | 0.916 *** | 6.244 *** | |||||||
EthnoCultural | 26.317 *** | 14.100 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCulturalsq | −18.639 *** | −9.723 *** | ||||||||
RightsFreedom | 14.512 *** | 11.232 *** | ||||||||
PolConstraints | −7.713 *** | 0.272 | ||||||||
ConflictViol | −3.208 *** | 0.828 | ||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | 4.213 *** | 7.939 *** | ||||||||
GvceQuality | 21.012 *** | 20.901 *** | ||||||||
Serial correlation test (p-value) | 0.210 | 0.202 | 0.226 | 0.212 | 0.216 | 0.216 | 0.212 | 0.204 | 0.201 | |
Number of observations | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | |
Number of countries, n | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | |
Panel b: System GMM | ||||||||||
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | [6] | [7] | [8] | [9] | ||
Political Risk—Composite | PolStability | 3.789 *** | ||||||||
Political Risk Components | Corruption | 1.598 *** | 2.280 *** | |||||||
EthnoCultural | −0.775 *** | 0.360 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCulturalsq | −1.547 *** | −1.885 *** | ||||||||
RightsFreedom | 9.393 *** | 4.267 *** | ||||||||
PolConstraints | −3.312 *** | 2.982 *** | ||||||||
ConflictViol | −6.103 *** | 0.867 *** | ||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | −1.306 *** | 0.667 | ||||||||
GvceQuality | 0.741 *** | 3.278 *** | ||||||||
Serial correlation test (p-value) | 0.231 | 0.233 | 0.233 | 0.228 | 0.232 | 0.232 | 0.230 | 0.228 | 0.230 | |
Number of observations | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | 680 | |
Number of countries, n | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 | 136 |
Panel a: Difference GMM | ||||||||||
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | [6] | [7] | [8] | [9] | ||
NatRscWagric | 0.003 *** | 0.006 *** | 0.004 *** | 0.002 *** | 0.002 *** | 0.001 *** | 0.003 *** | 0.002 *** | 0.004 *** | |
Political Risk—Composite | PolStability | 7.543 *** | ||||||||
natAg_PolStab | −0.005 *** | |||||||||
Political Risk sub index | Corruption | −9.314 *** | 0.460 *** | |||||||
natAg_Corrupt | 0.008 *** | −0.008 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCultural | 21.999 *** | 7.473 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCulturalsq | −14.089 *** | 0.519 * | ||||||||
natAg_EthnoCul | 0.009 *** | 0.013 *** | ||||||||
natAg_EthnoCulSq | −0.007 *** | −0.014 *** | ||||||||
RightsFreedom | 10.875 *** | 7.840 *** | ||||||||
natAg_RghtFree | 0.002 *** | −0.004 *** | ||||||||
PolConstraints | −0.799 *** | −1.153 *** | ||||||||
natAg_PolCons | −0.002 *** | 0.002 | ||||||||
ConflictViol | −1.882 *** | −6.106 * | ||||||||
natAg_ConfViol | 0.000 | 0.005 ** | ||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | 11.725 *** | 4.206 *** | ||||||||
natAg_SocEcWelf | −0.004 *** | −0.003 *** | ||||||||
GvceQuality | 16.157 *** | 11.903 *** | ||||||||
natAg_GovQual | 0.003 *** | −0.007 *** | ||||||||
Serial correlation test (p-value) | 0.213 | 0.211 | 0.231 | 0.224 | 0.218 | 0.220 | 0.216 | 0.202 | 0.196 | |
Number of observations | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | |
Number of countries, n | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | |
Panel b: System GMM | ||||||||||
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | [6] | [7] | [8] | [9] | ||
NatRscWagric | 0.001 *** | 0.001 *** | 0.001 *** | 0.001 *** | 0.001 | 0.001 *** | 0.001 *** | 0.001 *** | 0.001 *** | |
Political Risk—Composite | PolStability | 4.693 *** | ||||||||
natAg_PolStab | −0.002 *** | |||||||||
Political Risk sub index | Corruption | 5.177 *** | 3.657 *** | |||||||
natAg_Corrupt | −0.003 *** | −0.003 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCultural | −2.192 *** | 2.233 *** | ||||||||
EthnoCulturalsq | 0.359 ** | −3.526 *** | ||||||||
natAg_EthnoCul | 0.002 *** | 0.001 *** | ||||||||
natAg_EthnoCulSq | −0.001 *** | −0.001 *** | ||||||||
RightsFreedom | 12.683 *** | 4.109 *** | ||||||||
natAg_RghtFree | −0.002 *** | −0.001 *** | ||||||||
PolConstraints | −6.104 *** | 3.607 *** | ||||||||
natAg_PolCons | 0.002 *** | −0.001 *** | ||||||||
ConflictViol | −8.695 *** | 1.414 *** | ||||||||
natAg_ConfViol | 0.002 *** | −0.001 *** | ||||||||
WelfareSocioEco | 6.617 *** | 2.599 *** | ||||||||
natAg_SocEcWelf | −0.004 *** | −0.002 *** | ||||||||
GvceQuality | −5.895 *** | 4.004 *** | ||||||||
natAg_GovQual | 0.004 *** | −0.006 *** | ||||||||
Serial correlation test (p-value) | 0.225 | 0.227 | 0.229 | 0.223 | 0.226 | 0.224 | 0.224 | 0.222 | 0.223 | |
Number of observations | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | 665 | |
Number of countries, n | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 | 133 |
Hypotheses | Variables | Dependent Variable = FDI | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
[1] | [2] | [3] | [4] | [5] | ||
Intercept | 8.290 | 5.566 | 6.62 | 9.547 | 2.165 | |
Financial Devt | DomCrdtoPriv | 0.009 | 0.009 | 0.008 | 0.008 | 0.008 |
Infrastructure | logCellphones | −2.214 * | −2.484 * | −2.302 * | −2.302 * | −2.302 * |
CapForm | 0.101 * | 0.089 | 0.095 | 0.095 | 0.095 | |
Trade | trade | 0.072 *** | 0.067 *** | 0.069 *** | 0.069 *** | 0.069 *** |
Mkt size/ attractives | logGDP_PerCap10 | −0.633 * | −0.723 * | −0.853 ** | −0.853 ** | −0.853 ** |
Overall economic stability | Infl_deflator | 0.0470 ** | 0.036 ** | 0.051 ** | 0.051 ** | 0.051 ** |
Political Risk | PolStability | 5.188 *** | 3.478 *** | |||
PR_ICRG | 11.538 *** | 7.376 ** | ||||
pred: y = polStab, X = ICRG | 8.010 *** | |||||
resid: y = polStab, X = ICRG | 3.478 *** | |||||
pred: y = ICRG, X = PolStability | 16.075 *** | |||||
resid: y = ICRG, X = PolStability | 7.376 ** | |||||
N = # Years | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | 16 | |
# Countries | 121 | 121 | 121 | 121 | 121 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Jeutang, P.; Kesse, K. A Novel Measure of Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2021, 14, 482. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14100482
Jeutang P, Kesse K. A Novel Measure of Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2021; 14(10):482. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14100482
Chicago/Turabian StyleJeutang, Pavel, and Kwabena Kesse. 2021. "A Novel Measure of Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 14, no. 10: 482. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14100482
APA StyleJeutang, P., & Kesse, K. (2021). A Novel Measure of Political Risk and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 14(10), 482. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm14100482