Are Incurred Loss Standards Countercyclical? A Case Study Using U.S. Bank Holding Company Data
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
3. Materials and Methods: Data Description and Empirical Specification
γ1 RCAPit + γ2 EBPTit + γ3 WFUNDit + εit
- -
- NPLit is nonperforming loans7 divided by total loans,
- -
- RWACit is the ratio of risk-weighted assets for credit risk to total loans,8
- -
- GDPGt−1 is lagged real gross domestic product (GDP)9 growth, which is measured as an annual percent change based on seasonally adjusted information,
- -
- LEADt is the quarterly average of monthly values for the Leading Index with a measure of aggregate economic activities for the United States, also measured on a seasonally adjusted basis,10
- -
- VIXMAXt is the maximum value within each quarter of the Chicago Board Options Exchange’s CBOE Volatility Index, VIX, which is a measure of the stock market’s expectation of volatility that is based on S&P 500 index options,
- -
- RCAPit is the sum of actual tier 1 capital and the allowance for loan and lease loans divided by risk-weighted assets11 minus the required tier 1 risk-based capital ratio set for the bank holding company by the Federal Reserve (a size of tier 1 capital buffer above the minimum regulatory capital requirement),
- -
- EBPTit is earnings before provisions and taxes divided by average assets,12 and
- -
- WFUNDit is wholesale funding divided by total loans.13
4. Results: The Effects of Credit Risk, Capital Adequacy, Earnings and the Economic Cycle on Bank Provisioning and Loan Loss Allowances
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Testing Coefficient Differences from Provision Regressions
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.121 | 0.024 | 0.127 | 0.018 | −0.197 | 0.422 |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.001 | −0.001 | 0.001 | −0.130 | 0.448 |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | −0.213 | 0.416 |
RCAPit | −0.013 | 0.005 | −0.012 | 0.006 | −0.121 | 0.452 |
EBPTit | 0.126 | 0.089 | 0.177 | 0.106 | −0.367 | 0.357 |
GDPGt−1 | −0.005 | 0.002 | −0.004 | 0.001 | −0.708 | 0.240 |
LEADt | 0.002 | 0.013 | −0.012 | 0.011 | 0.821 | 0.206 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.541 | 0.294 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | T-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.195 | 0.054 | 0.152 | 0.065 | 0.506 | 0.307 |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.002 | −0.003 | 0.003 | 0.385 | 0.350 |
WFUNDit | 0.007 | 0.003 | 0.004 | 0.005 | 0.394 | 0.347 |
RCAPit | 0.021 | 0.020 | 0.050 | 0.025 | −0.924 | 0.179 |
EBPTit | −0.067 | 0.082 | −0.115 | 0.062 | 0.468 | 0.320 |
GDPGt−1 | −0.019 | 0.007 | −0.010 | 0.013 | −0.653 | 0.257 |
LEADt | 0.172 | 0.086 | 0.140 | 0.094 | 0.256 | 0.399 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.467 | 0.321 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.085 | 0.018 | 0.079 | 0.016 | 0.239 | 0.405 |
RWACit | 0.000 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.001 | −0.052 | 0.479 |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.003 | 0.001 | 0.003 | −0.036 | 0.485 |
RCAPit | −0.005 | 0.004 | −0.001 | 0.004 | −0.565 | 0.286 |
EBPTit | −0.020 | 0.037 | −0.020 | 0.025 | −0.013 | 0.495 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.005 | 0.005 | 0.005 | 0.005 | 0.012 | 0.495 |
LEADt | −0.268 | 0.043 | −0.277 | 0.042 | 0.147 | 0.442 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | −0.215 | 0.415 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.121 | 0.024 | 0.195 | 0.054 | −1.253 | 0.106 |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.001 | −0.001 | 0.002 | 0.190 | 0.425 |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.007 | 0.003 | −1.896 | 0.029 ** |
RCAPit | −0.013 | 0.005 | 0.021 | 0.020 | −1.680 | 0.047 ** |
EBPTit | 0.126 | 0.089 | −0.067 | 0.082 | 1.591 | 0.056 * |
GDPGt−1 | −0.005 | 0.002 | −0.019 | 0.007 | 1.946 | 0.026 ** |
LEADt | 0.002 | 0.013 | 0.172 | 0.086 | −1.952 | 0.026 ** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | −1.493 | 0.068 * |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.121 | 0.024 | 0.085 | 0.018 | 1.192 | 0.117 |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.001 | −0.246 | 0.403 * |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.003 | −0.154 | 0.439 * |
RCAPit | −0.013 | 0.005 | −0.005 | 0.004 | −1.320 | 0.094 * |
EBPTit | 0.126 | 0.089 | −0.020 | 0.037 | 1.523 | 0.064 * |
GDPGt−1 | −0.005 | 0.002 | 0.005 | 0.005 | −1.894 | 0.029 ** |
LEADt | 0.002 | 0.013 | −0.268 | 0.043 | 5.994 | 0.000 *** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 1.388 | 0.083 * |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.195 | 0.054 | 0.085 | 0.018 | 1.927 | 0.027 ** |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.002 | 0.000 | 0.001 | −0.363 | 0.358 |
WFUNDit | 0.007 | 0.003 | 0.001 | 0.003 | 1.386 | 0.083 * |
RCAPit | 0.021 | 0.020 | −0.005 | 0.004 | 1.275 | 0.101 |
EBPTit | −0.067 | 0.082 | −0.020 | 0.037 | −0.513 | 0.304 |
GDPGt−1 | −0.019 | 0.007 | 0.005 | 0.005 | −2.870 | 0.002 *** |
LEADt | 0.172 | 0.086 | −0.268 | 0.043 | 4.572 | 0.000 *** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 2.013 | 0.022 ** |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.127 | 0.018 | 0.152 | 0.065 | −0.372 | 0.355 |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.001 | −0.003 | 0.003 | 0.661 | 0.254 |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.004 | 0.005 | −0.684 | 0.247 |
RCAPit | −0.012 | 0.006 | 0.050 | 0.025 | −2.454 | 0.007 *** |
EBPTit | 0.177 | 0.106 | −0.115 | 0.062 | 2.384 | 0.009 *** |
GDPGt−1 | −0.004 | 0.001 | −0.010 | 0.013 | 0.445 | 0.328 |
LEADt | −0.012 | 0.011 | 0.140 | 0.094 | −1.598 | 0.055 * |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | −1.219 | 0.112 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.127 | 0.018 | 0.079 | 0.016 | 2.001 | 0.023 ** |
RWACit | −0.001 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.001 | −0.224 | 0.411 * |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.003 | −0.117 | 0.453 * |
RCAPit | −0.012 | 0.006 | −0.001 | 0.004 | −1.472 | 0.071 * |
EBPTit | 0.177 | 0.106 | −0.020 | 0.025 | 1.810 | 0.035 ** |
GDPGt−1 | −0.004 | 0.001 | 0.005 | 0.005 | −1.793 | 0.037 ** |
LEADt | −0.012 | 0.011 | −0.277 | 0.042 | 6.144 | 0.000 *** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.706 | 0.240 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.152 | 0.065 | 0.079 | 0.016 | 1.083 | 0.140 |
RWACit | −0.003 | 0.003 | 0.000 | 0.001 | −0.748 | 0.227 |
WFUNDit | 0.004 | 0.005 | 0.001 | 0.003 | 0.565 | 0.286 |
RCAPit | 0.050 | 0.025 | −0.001 | 0.004 | 2.066 | 0.020 ** |
EBPTit | −0.115 | 0.062 | −0.020 | 0.025 | −1.424 | 0.078 * |
GDPGt−1 | −0.010 | 0.013 | 0.005 | 0.000 | −1.045 | 0.148 |
LEADt | 0.140 | 0.094 | −0.277 | 0.042 | 4.047 | 0.000 *** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 1.485 | 0.069 * |
Appendix B. Testing Coefficient Differences from ALLL Regressions
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.477 | 0.107 | 0.636 | 0.091 | −1.132 | 0.129 |
RWACit | 0.008 | 0.004 | 0.007 | 0.004 | 0.058 | 0.477 |
WFUNDit | −0.003 | 0.002 | −0.001 | 0.002 | −0.694 | 0.244 |
RCAPit | 0.107 | 0.039 | 0.110 | 0.038 | −0.050 | 0.480 |
EBPTit | −0.130 | 0.140 | −0.174 | 0.166 | 0.204 | 0.419 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.008 | 0.015 | 0.007 | 0.011 | 0.046 | 0.482 |
LEADt | 0.100 | 0.105 | 0.103 | 0.091 | −0.026 | 0.490 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 1.017 | 0.155 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.315 | 0.060 | 0.325 | 0.051 | −0.138 | 0.445 |
RWACit | −0.003 | 0.002 | −0.002 | 0.002 | −0.023 | 0.491 |
WFUNDit | 0.006 | 0.005 | 0.012 | 0.007 | −0.696 | 0.244 |
RCAPit | 0.149 | 0.037 | 0.149 | 0.032 | 0.017 | 0.493 |
EBPTit | 0.050 | 0.053 | 0.024 | 0.061 | 0.319 | 0.375 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.019 | 0.008 | 0.026 | 0.015 | −0.459 | 0.324 |
LEADt | −0.063 | 0.054 | −0.086 | 0.085 | 0.225 | 0.411 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.328 | 0.372 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.377 | 0.039 | 0.390 | 0.035 | −0.234 | 0.408 |
RWACit | 0.004 | 0.004 | 0.001 | 0.004 | 0.488 | 0.313 |
WFUNDit | 0.016 | 0.010 | 0.019 | 0.010 | −0.266 | 0.395 |
RCAPit | 0.059 | 0.030 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 0.958 | 0.169 |
EBPTit | −0.388 | 0.184 | −0.258 | 0.152 | −0.546 | 0.292 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.047 | 0.481 |
LEADt | −0.191 | 0.072 | −0.181 | 0.065 | −0.100 | 0.460 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.445 | 0.328 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.477 | 0.107 | 0.315 | 0.060 | 1.329 | 0.092 * |
RWACit | 0.008 | 0.004 | −0.003 | 0.002 | 2.499 | 0.006 *** |
WFUNDit | −0.003 | 0.002 | 0.006 | 0.005 | −1.579 | 0.058 * |
RCAPit | 0.107 | 0.039 | 0.149 | 0.037 | −0.776 | 0.219 |
EBPTit | −0.130 | 0.140 | 0.050 | 0.053 | −1.202 | 0.115 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.008 | 0.015 | 0.019 | 0.008 | −0.630 | 0.265 |
LEADt | 0.100 | 0.105 | −0.063 | 0.054 | 1.377 | 0.085 * |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 3.326 | 0.000 *** |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.477 | 0.107 | 0.377 | 0.039 | 0.879 | 0.190 |
RWACit | 0.008 | 0.004 | 0.004 | 0.004 | 0.683 | 0.248 |
WFUNDit | −0.003 | 0.002 | 0.016 | 0.010 | −1.817 | 0.035 ** |
RCAPit | 0.107 | 0.039 | 0.059 | 0.030 | 0.991 | 0.161 |
EBPTit | −0.130 | 0.140 | −0.388 | 0.184 | 1.118 | 0.132 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.008 | 0.015 | 0.008 | 0.005 | −0.027 | 0.489 |
LEADt | 0.100 | 0.105 | −0.191 | 0.072 | 2.278 | 0.011 ** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 1.006 | 0.157 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.315 | 0.060 | 0.377 | 0.039 | −0.881 | 0.189 |
RWACit | −0.003 | 0.002 | 0.004 | 0.004 | −1.337 | 0.091 * |
WFUNDit | 0.006 | 0.005 | 0.016 | 0.010 | −0.850 | 0.198 |
RCAPit | 0.149 | 0.037 | 0.059 | 0.030 | 1.906 | 0.029 ** |
EBPTit | 0.050 | 0.053 | −0.388 | 0.184 | 2.292 | 0.011 ** |
GDPGt−1 | 0.019 | 0.008 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 1.045 | 0.148 |
LEADt | −0.063 | 0.054 | −0.191 | 0.072 | 1.425 | 0.077 * |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | −3.574 | 0.000 *** |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.636 | 0.091 | 0.325 | 0.051 | 2.975 | 0.002 *** |
RWACit | 0.007 | 0.004 | −0.002 | 0.002 | 2.026 | 0.022 ** |
WFUNDit | −0.001 | 0.002 | 0.012 | 0.007 | −1.793 | 0.037 ** |
RCAPit | 0.110 | 0.038 | 0.149 | 0.032 | −0.777 | 0.219 |
EBPTit | −0.174 | 0.166 | 0.024 | 0.061 | −1.120 | 0.132 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.007 | 0.011 | 0.026 | 0.015 | −1.034 | 0.151 |
LEADt | 0.103 | 0.091 | −0.086 | 0.085 | 1.524 | 0.064 * |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 3.029 | 0.001 *** |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.636 | 0.091 | 0.390 | 0.035 | 2.526 | 0.006 *** |
RWACit | 0.007 | 0.004 | 0.001 | 0.004 | 1.139 | 0.128 ** |
WFUNDit | −0.001 | 0.002 | 0.019 | 0.010 | −2.057 | 0.020 ** |
RCAPit | 0.110 | 0.038 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 1.954 | 0.026 ** |
EBPTit | −0.174 | 0.166 | −0.258 | 0.152 | 0.369 | 0.356 |
GDPGt−1 | 0.007 | 0.011 | 0.008 | 0.005 | −0.077 | 0.469 |
LEADt | 0.103 | 0.091 | −0.181 | 0.065 | 2.545 | 0.006 *** |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.229 | 0.410 |
Variable | Model1_ Coefficient | SE | Model2_ Coefficient | SE | t-Statistic | p-Value |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
NPLit | 0.325 | 0.051 | 0.390 | 0.035 | −1.043 | 0.149 |
RWACit | −0.002 | 0.002 | 0.001 | 0.004 | −0.805 | 0.211 |
WFUNDit | 0.012 | 0.007 | 0.019 | 0.010 | −0.594 | 0.276 |
RCAPit | 0.149 | 0.032 | 0.021 | 0.025 | 3.132 | 0.001 *** |
EBPTit | 0.024 | 0.061 | −0.258 | 0.152 | 1.715 | 0.043 ** |
GDPGt−1 | 0.026 | 0.015 | 0.008 | 0.005 | 1.177 | 0.120 |
LEADt | −0.086 | 0.085 | −0.181 | 0.065 | 0.894 | 0.186 |
VIXMAXt | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | −3.412 | 0.000 *** |
1 | Our sample omits savings and loan holding companies and intermediate holding companies of foreign banking organizations. These institutions began filing FR Y-9C Call Reports during our sample period. |
2 | Throughout our sample period, there were regulatory and supervisory reforms that required new entities to file FR Y-9C reports (e.g., Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley started filing FR Y-9C in 2008 and Intermediate Holding Companies of Foreign Bank Holding Companies started filing FR Y-9C in 2014). We excluded these new filers from our sample. |
3 | These mappings are provided when we describe each variable used in our specification. |
4 | The largest such thrift acquisition during the financial crisis was Washington Mutual, which was acquired by JPMorgan in September 2008. |
5 | Provisions for loan and lease losses (BHCK4230) and total loans (BHCK2122) are from the Consolidated Financial Statements for Bank Holding Companies report (FR Y-9C). The corresponding items from the Office of Thrift Supervision (OTS) Thrift Financial Report (OTS-1313) are SO321 and the sum of SC26 and SC31. |
6 | For bank holding companies, the allowance for loan and lease losses was measured using item BHCK3123 from the FR Y-9C. For thrifts, this allowance was measured using item SC023 from the OTS-1313. |
7 | Nonperforming loans include total loans, leases, and other assets either 90 days past due or worse and still accruing or in nonaccrual, debt securities, and other assets either past due 90 days or more and still accruing or in nonaccrual (items BHCK1407, BHCK1403, BHC3506, and BHCK3507 from the FR y-9C). Analogously, thrift nonperforming loans were measured using the sum of PD20 and PD30 from OTS-1313. |
8 | Risk-weighted assets are measured by BHCAA223 and CCR78 from FR Y-9C and OTS-1313, respectively. |
9 | Data on real GDP are from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (Federal Reserve Economic Data 2020). |
10 | The Leading Index for the United States is available from the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia (Federal Reserve Economic Data 2020). |
11 | Tier 1 capital is measured by item BHCA8274, ALLLit is measured by item BHCK3213, risk-weighted assets is measured by item BHCAA223 on the Y-9C. Thrift tier 1 capital is measured by item CCR20 and risk-weighted assets is measured by item CCR78 on the OTS-1313. |
12 | For bank holding companies the numerator of EBPTit is the sum of items BHCK4340, BHCK4230, and BHC4302; and the denominator is item BHCK3368 from the FR Y9-C. For thrifts, the numerator is the sum of items S091, SO321, and S071; and the denominator is item S1870 from the OTS-1313. |
13 | Wholesale funding includes securities sold under agreements to repurchase, commercial paper and other borrowed money with remaining maturity of one year or less (items BHCKB995, BHCK2309, and BHCK2332 from the Consolidated Financial Statements for Bank Holding Companies report). |
14 | The clustered standard errors are substantially larger than the errors for the same regressions with robust White-corrected standard errors. This result suggests that there are sufficient clusters in the bank dimension for the two-way clustering procedure to effectively correct the standard errors for heteroscedasticity. |
15 | Using a t-test, the statistical difference between pre-crisis and crisis periods (crisis and post-crisis periods) for this coefficient is statistically different at the five percent (10 percent) level. |
16 | The pre-crisis coefficient was statistically different from the crisis coefficient at the one percent level of confidence, the crisis coefficient was statistically different from the post-crisis coefficient at the five percent level, and the pre-crisis coefficient was statistically different from the post-crisis coefficient at the10 percent level. |
17 | The coefficients on lagged real GDP growth and the leading indicator during the crisis period are statistically larger than the corresponding coefficients during the pre-crisis period at the five percent confidence level when unadjusted bank holding company data are used. |
18 | Looking across the pre-crisis and crisis periods using forced merged (adjusted) data, the coefficients on the leading indicator are statistically different at the 5 percent confidence level. |
19 | Table A5 and Table A8 in Appendix A show the provision behavior change statistically significant at the five percent confidence level or better during pre- and post-crisis periods. |
20 | Cummings and Durrani (2016) reported positive but insignificant coefficients on the measure of market uncertainty they included in their empirical model of provisioning. |
21 | Cross-period tests for coefficient differences across periods were significant at the 10 percent confidence level or better when unadjusted data are used, but such differences were only significant across the crisis and post-crisis periods—and only at the 10 percent confidence level—when merger-adjusted data are used. |
22 | Table A4 and Table A7 in Appendix A show statistically insignificance of NPL coefficients estimates between pre-crisis and crisis periods. |
23 | Using a t-test, the coefficient for RCAPit is statistically higher in the pre-crisis period compared to the crisis period at a one (five) percent confidence level when unadjusted (adjusted) holding company are used. Comparing such coefficients across the crisis and post-crisis periods, the coefficient is significantly higher during the crisis period only when unadjusted data and a 10 percent confidence level are used. |
24 | The terminology of provisions used by Cummings and Durrani is equivalent to the loan loss allowances used in United States. |
25 | The t-tests for differences in coefficients on lagged real GDP growth across periods indicate that there are no statistical differences at the 10 percent level or better, regardless of whether adjusted or unadjusted holding company data are considered. |
References
- Abad, Jorge, and Javier Suarez. 2018. Assessing the Procyclicality of Expected Credit Loss Provisions. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 13135. CEPR Discussion Paper, March 18. [Google Scholar]
- Ahmed, Anwer S., Carolyn Takeda, and Shawn Thomas. 1999. Bank Loan Loss Provisions: A Reexamination of Capital Management, Earnings Management and Signaling Effects. Journal of Accounting and Economics 28: 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Balasubramanyan, Lakshmi, James B. Thomson, and Saeed Zaman. 2017. Evidence of Forward-Looking Loan Loss Provisioning with Credit Market Information. Journal of Financial Services Research 52: 191–223. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2017. Regulatory Treatment of Accounting Provisions. Issued for Comment. Discussion Paper, January 13. [Google Scholar]
- Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2021. The Pro-cyclicality of Loan Loss Provisions: A Literature Review. Working Paper 39. Working Paper, May 25. [Google Scholar]
- Beatty, Anne, and Scott Liao. 2011. Do Delays in Expected Loss Recognition affect Banks’ Willingness to Lend? Journal of Accounting and Economics 52: 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Beck, Paul S., and Ganapathi S. Narayanamoorthy. 2013. Did the SEC Impact Banks’ Loan Loss Reserve Policies and their Informativeness? Journal of Accounting and Economics 56: 42–65. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Berger, Allen N., and Gregory F. Udell. 2004. The Institutional Memory Hypothesis and the Procyclicality of Bank Lending Behavior. Journal of Financial Intermediation 13: 458–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bernanke, Ben S. 2009. The Financial Crisis and Community Banking. Phoenix: The Independent Community Bankers of America’s National Convention and Techworld, March 20. [Google Scholar]
- Bikker, Jacob Antoon, and Paul A. J. Metzemakers. 2005. Bank Provisioning Behaviour and Procyclicality. Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money 15: 141–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2018. Statement on the Current Expected Credit Loss Methodology (CECL) and Stress Testing. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December 21. [Google Scholar]
- Borio, Claudio, Craig Furfine, and Philip Lowe. 2001. Procyclicality of the financial system and financial stability: Issues and policy options. In BIS Papers Chapters, Marrying the Macro- and Micro-Prudential Dimensions of Financial Stability. Basel: Bank for International Settlements, vol. 1, pp. 1–57. [Google Scholar]
- Bouvatier, Vincent, and Laetitia Lepetit. 2012. Provisioning Rules and Bank Lending: A Theoretical Model. Journal of Financial Stability 8: 25–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cohen, Benjamin, and Gerald A. Edwards. 2017. The New Era of Expected Credit Loss Provisioning. BIS Quarterly Review, March 6, 38–56. [Google Scholar]
- Covas, Francisco, and William Nelson. 2018. Current Expected Credit Loss: Lessons from 2007–2009. Staff Working Paper 2018-1. Washington, DC: Bank Policy Institute, July 12. [Google Scholar]
- Craig, R. Sean, E. Philip Davis, and Antonio Garcia Pascual. 2006. Sources of Procyclicality in East Asian Financial Systems. In Procyclicality of Financial Systems in Asia. Edited by Stefan Gerlach and Paul Gruenwald. London: Palgrave Macmillan, pp. 55–123. [Google Scholar]
- Cummings, James R., and Kassim J. Durrani. 2016. Effect of the Basel Accord Capital Requirements on the Loan-loss provisioning Practices of Australian Banks. Journal of Banking and Finance 67: 23–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- DeRitis, Cristian, and Mark Zandi. 2018. Gauging CECL Cyclicality. Moody’s Analytics, December 3. [Google Scholar]
- English, William, and William Nelson. 1998. Profits and Balance Sheet Developments at U.S. Commercial Banks in 1997. Federal Reserve Bulletin 84: 391–419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation. 2020. Quarterly Banking Profile Fourth Quarter 2019. Washington, DC: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, vol. 14, pp. 1–30. [Google Scholar]
- Federal Reserve Economic Data. 2020. FRED Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Available online: https://fred.stlouisfed.org/ (accessed on 14 August 2020).
- Financial Accounting Standards Board. 2016. Credit Losses. Available online: https:fasb.org/creditlosses&pf=true (accessed on 14 August 2020).
- Gray, Robert P. 2004. The Allowance for Loan Losses and Earnings Management. Sydney: University of Sydney Working Paper. [Google Scholar]
- Handorf, William C., and Lili Zhu. 2016. US Bank Loan-Loss Provisions, Economic Conditions, and Regulatory Guidance. Journal of Applied Finance 16: 97–114. [Google Scholar]
- Kim, Myung-Sun, and William Kross. 1998. The Impact of the 1989 Change in Bank Capital Standards on Loan Loss Provisions and Loan Write-offs. Journal of Accounting and Economics 25: 69–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Laeven, Luc, and Giovanni Majnoni. 2003. Loan Loss Provisioning and Economic Slowdowns: Too Much, Too Late? Journal of Financial Intermediation 12: 178–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Loudis, Bert, and Ben Ranish. 2019. CECL and the Credit Cycle. Finance and Economic Discussion Series Working Paper #2019-061. Federal Reserve Board, May 30. [Google Scholar]
- Pérez, Daniel, Vincente Salas-Fumás, and Jesús Saurina. 2008. Earnings and Capital Management in Alternative Loan Loss Provision Regulatory Regimes. European Accounting Review 17: 423–45. [Google Scholar]
- Thompson, Samuel B. 2011. Simple Formulas for Standard Errors that Cluster by both Firm and Time. Journal of Financial Economics 99: 1–10. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Van den Heuvel, Skander. 2009. The Bank Capital Channel of Monetary Policy. Working Paper. Washington, DC: Federal Reserve Board. [Google Scholar]
- Wall, Larry D., and Timothy W. Koch. 2000. Bank Loan-Loss Accounting: A Review of Theoretical and Empirical Evidence. In Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review. Second Quarter. pp. 1–19. Available online: https://www.atlantafed.org/-/media/Documents/research/publications/economic-review/2000/vol85no2_wall-koch.pdf (accessed on 14 August 2020).
- Wheeler, P. Barrett. 2019. Loan Loss Accounting and Procyclical Bank Lending: The Role of Direct Regulatory Actions. Journal of Accounting and Economics 67: 463–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Author(s) | Title | Accounting Standards/LLP Regimes Covered | Time Periods, Countries Covered | Consideration of Mergers? | Could Procyclicality Vary Over Business Cycle? |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Abad and Suarez (2018) | Assessing the procyclicality of expected credit loss provisions | IL, EL (CECL, IFRS 9) | 1981–2015, EU countries | None | Considered probability that a bank needs to recapitalize to finance LLP. Demonstrated that there are more loan losses, or more sudden falls in regulatory capital, right at the beginning of contractionary phases of the business or credit cycle. |
Balasubramanyan et al. (2017) | Evidence of forward-looking loan loss provisioning with credit market information | IL | Q1 1997–Q3 2011, US | Kept observations with mergers that used pooling of interest accounting. Dropped observations corresponding to the quarter in which the merger took place and the accounting method used was purchase accounting. | Studied loan loss provisioning over the credit cycle using three distinct phases: pre-crisis, crisis, and post-crisis to control for structural breaks. Argued that the value of an additional dollar of equity is higher during an economic downturn than in an expansion. Distinguished between credit cycle and business cycle using Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey information. |
Beatty and Liao (2011) | Do delays in expected loss recognition affect banks’ willingness to lend? | IL | Q3 1993–Q2 2009, US | To address concerns that their analysis might be affected by mergers and acquisitions, excluded all observations with non-loan asset growth exceeding 10% in any quarter. | Exploited variation in the delay in expected loss recognition in IL regime to consider reductions in lending during recessionary periods relative to expansionary periods. These reductions are lower for banks that delay less. |
Berger and Udell (2004) | The institutional memory hypothesis and the procyclicality of bank lending behavior | IL | 1980–2000, US | To ensure that their results were not due to mergers, the authors ran their regressions with only non-merging banks (i.e., deleting observations on banks engaged in mergers over the [t − 10, t] interval. | Stylized fact: Past due, nonaccrual, provisions, and charge-offs are generally low during most of the expansion, start to appear at the end of the expansion, then rise dramatically during the downturn. Authors find support for the “institutional memory hypothesis” that is driven by the deterioration in the ability of loan officers over the bank’s lending cycle that results in an easing of credit standards. This deterioration is partly due to a proportional increase in officers that have never experienced a loan bust, and partly due to the atrophying skills of experienced officers as time passes since their last problem-loans experience. |
Bikker and Metzemakers (2005) | Bank provisioning behaviour and procyclicality | IL | 1991–2001, 45 OECD countries | None | Provisioning depends significantly on the business cycle as evidenced by the negative relation between GDP growth and provisioning. The procyclical effect—buffers need to grow during downturns—is mitigated by the impact of the banks’ earnings on provisions and by the positive effect of loan growth on provisioning. The data also support the capital management hypothesis: banks provision more when their capital ratio is low. |
Bouvatier and Lepetit (2012) | Provisioning rules and bank lending: a theoretical model | NA | NA | None | Developed a partial equilibrium model of the banking firm to show that a backward-looking provisioning system amplifies the procyclicality of loan market fluctuations. |
Covas and Nelson (2018) | Current expected credit loss: lessons from 2007–2009 | IL, CECL (US GAAP) | 1977–2017, US | None, but models are estimated using aggregated time-series for the entire U.S. banking system. | Utilized a top-down approach to estimate credit loss allowances under CECL methodology. The procyclicality of CECL using this approach is driven by the inaccuracy of forecasts around turning points of the business cycle and not by parameter uncertainty or by not including enough recessions in the estimation of loan loss models. |
Craig et al. (2006) | Sources of procyclicality in East Asia financial systems | IL | 1960–2004, 10 Asian Countries | None | Delayed recognition of, and provisioning for, nonperforming loans and regulatory forbearance were identified as sources of procyclicality. Banks tend to delay provisioning until the deterioration of loan quality becomes evident during downturns. Stronger banks with high earnings/higher capital ratios tend to provision more, which is consistent with forbearance by weak banks. The provisioning rate was procyclical; growth in GDP, credit, and property prices (i.e., increase in collateral values) lower provisioning. Banks tended to increase provisions when earning are declining or negative, rather than when they are doing well. |
Cummings and Durrani (2016) | Effect of the Basel Accord capital requirements on the loan-loss provisioning practices of Australian banks | IL, IFRS 9 | Sep. 2003–Dec. 2012, Australia | None | Bank provisioning behavior has both procyclical and countercyclical characteristics. Provisions and allowances are sensitive to cyclical fluctuations in default risk, however, banks adjust them by including future economic conditions and cushion the impact of cyclical fluctuations through capital and earnings management. The positive relationships between allowances and excess regulatory capital and between allowances and earnings are found. Banks allocate higher allowances when their risk-based capital ratios and earnings are higher than average and adjust them downwards in periods when capital and earnings indicators are weaker. |
DeRitis and Zandi (2018) | Gauging CECL cyclicality | IL, ECL(CECL) | 1999–2018, US | None, but considers aggregate time-series data. | Considered correlation between LLA and macro variables. Co-movement with aggregate macroeconomic activity; correlation between macro variables and loss reserves; build-up of allowances in good economic times before a recession. |
Handorf and Zhu (2006) | US bank loan-loss provisions, economic conditions, and regulatory guidance | IL | 1990–2000, US | None | Empirical tests do not support the claim that bank loan loss provisioning is procyclical. After the nondiscretionary component of provisioning practices in controlled for, US banks generally overstate loan-loss provisions during economic expansions. |
Laeven and Majnoni (2003) | Loan loss provisioning and economic slowdowns: too much, too late? | IL | 1988–1999, 45 countries | None | Find empirical evidence that many banks around the world delay provisioning for bad loans until too late, when cyclical downturns have already set in, thereby magnifying the impact of the economic cycle on banks’ income and capital. |
Loudis and Ranish (2019) | CECL and the credit cycle | IL, ECL(CECL) | 1998–2014, US | Use a merger-adjusted version of the Y-9C that adjusts holding company data only in the quarter that the merger occurs. | Considered fluctuations (standard deviation) in lending growth. Co-movement with aggregate economic activity implies a reduction in lending during downturns and an increase in lending during upturns. |
Wheeler (2019) | Loan loss accounting and procyclical bank lending: the role of direct regulatory actions | IL | 1990–2014, quarterly | None | Procyclical lending refers to supply-driven changes in lending that amplify the business cycle in a general discussion in the introduction, but the setup of the empirical analysis only captures co-movement with the business cycle. |
Name | Ticker | Total Loans a |
---|---|---|
Bank of America Corporation | BAC | 1.03 |
JPMorgan Chase & Co. | JPM | 0.99 |
Wells Fargo & Company | WFC | 0.98 |
Citigroup Inc. | C | 0.72 |
Truist Financial Corporation | TFC | 0.31 |
U.S. Bancorp | USB | 0.30 |
PNC Financial Services Group, Inc., The | PNC | 0.24 |
Citizens Financial Group, Inc. | CFG | 0.12 |
Fifth Third Bancorp | FITB | 0.11 |
Keycorp | KEY | 0.10 |
M&T Bank Corporation | MTB | 0.09 |
Regions Financial Corporation | RF | 0.08 |
Huntington Bancshares Incorporated | HBAN | 0.08 |
Bank of New York Mellon Corporation, The | BK | 0.05 |
Comerica Incorporated | CMA | 0.05 |
New York Community Bancorp, Inc. | NYCB | 0.04 |
Synovus Financial Corp. | SNV | 0.04 |
East West Bancorp, Inc. | EWBC | 0.03 |
TCF Financial Corporation | TCF | 0.03 |
SVB Financial Group | SIVB | 0.03 |
First Horizon National Corporation | FHN | 0.03 |
Northern Trust Corporation | NTRS | 0.03 |
Valley National Bancorp | VLY | 0.03 |
First Citizens Bancshares, Inc. | FCNCA | 0.03 |
Texas Capital Bancshares, Inc. | TCBI | 0.03 |
$5.57 |
Entity Type | Period | Start Quarter | End Quarter | Number of Mergers | Relative Size of Acquiring and Target Holding Companies | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Mean | Minimum | Maximum | |||||
BHC | Pre-crisis | 2002: Q1 | 2007: Q3 | 54 | 0.146 | 0.000 | 0.644 |
BHC | Crisis | 2007: Q4 | 2009: Q2 | 10 | 0.427 | 0.020 | 1.334 |
BHC | Post-crisis | 2009: Q3 | 2019: Q4 | 53 | 0.278 | 0.010 | 1.121 |
Thrift | Pre-crisis | 2002: Q1 | 2007: Q3 | 9 | 0.036 | 0.003 | 0.081 |
Thrift | Crisis | 2007: Q4 | 2009: Q2 | 5 | 0.085 | 0.017 | 0.209 |
Thrift | Post-crisis | 2009: Q3 | 2019: Q4 | 9 | 0.158 | 0.006 | 0.666 |
Variable | Period | Mean | SD | Min | Median | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Panel A: Call Report Variables | ||||||
PROVit | Pre-crisis | 0.001 | 0.001 | −0.008 | 0.001 | 0.012 |
Crisis | 0.005 | 0.005 | 0.000 | 0.004 | 0.028 | |
Post-crisis | 0.002 | 0.002 | −0.002 | 0.001 | 0.024 | |
ALLLit | Pre-crisis | 0.013 | 0.005 | 0.004 | 0.013 | 0.035 |
Crisis | 0.017 | 0.009 | 0.004 | 0.016 | 0.053 | |
Post-crisis | 0.016 | 0.010 | 0.002 | 0.013 | 0.065 | |
NPLit | Pre-crisis | 0.008 | 0.005 | 0.000 | 0.007 | 0.030 |
Crisis | 0.021 | 0.015 | 0.001 | 0.017 | 0.065 | |
Post-crisis | 0.020 | 0.017 | 0.001 | 0.014 | 0.080 | |
RWACit | Pre-crisis | 1.317 | 0.295 | 0.775 | 1.210 | 2.458 |
Crisis | 1.326 | 0.344 | 0.916 | 1.213 | 3.019 | |
Post-crisis | 1.324 | 0.390 | 0.782 | 1.207 | 3.201 | |
WFUNDit | Pre-crisis | 0.165 | 0.175 | 0.004 | 0.102 | 0.898 |
Crisis | 0.182 | 0.147 | 0.015 | 0.129 | 0.642 | |
Post-crisis | 0.119 | 0.134 | 0.000 | 0.068 | 0.662 | |
RCAPit | Pre-crisis | 0.049 | 0.023 | 0.019 | 0.040 | 0.136 |
Crisis | 0.056 | 0.025 | 0.015 | 0.049 | 0.137 | |
Post-crisis | 0.063 | 0.024 | 0.011 | 0.061 | 0.153 | |
EBPTit | Pre-crisis | 0.006 | 0.002 | −0.010 | 0.006 | 0.024 |
Crisis | 0.003 | 0.006 | −0.044 | 0.004 | 0.021 | |
Post-crisis | 0.004 | 0.002 | −0.018 | 0.004 | 0.031 | |
Panel B: Call Report Variables (Adjusted for Mergers) | ||||||
PROVit | Pre-crisis | 0.001 | 0.001 | −0.008 | 0.001 | 0.010 |
Crisis | 0.006 | 0.004 | 0.000 | 0.004 | 0.025 | |
Post-crisis | 0.002 | 0.002 | −0.001 | 0.001 | 0.019 | |
ALLLit | Pre-crisis | 0.013 | 0.004 | 0.006 | 0.012 | 0.035 |
Crisis | 0.017 | 0.008 | 0.006 | 0.015 | 0.052 | |
Post-crisis | 0.016 | 0.009 | 0.002 | 0.013 | 0.064 | |
NPLit | Pre-crisis | 0.008 | 0.004 | 0.001 | 0.007 | 0.029 |
Crisis | 0.022 | 0.014 | 0.001 | 0.020 | 0.059 | |
Post-crisis | 0.021 | 0.017 | 0.001 | 0.014 | 0.080 | |
RWACit | Pre-crisis | 1.281 | 0.294 | 0.760 | 1.186 | 2.482 |
Crisis | 1.295 | 0.341 | 0.876 | 1.195 | 3.019 | |
Post-crisis | 1.312 | 0.397 | 0.800 | 1.184 | 3.201 | |
WFUNDit | Pre-crisis | 0.151 | 0.134 | 0.004 | 0.112 | 0.780 |
Crisis | 0.172 | 0.137 | 0.015 | 0.130 | 0.642 | |
Post-crisis | 0.120 | 0.133 | 0.000 | 0.071 | 0.662 | |
RCAPit | Pre-crisis | 0.048 | 0.016 | 0.020 | 0.043 | 0.136 |
Crisis | 0.055 | 0.020 | 0.017 | 0.053 | 0.118 | |
Post-crisis | 0.064 | 0.024 | 0.011 | 0.063 | 0.146 | |
EBPTit | Pre-crisis | 0.006 | 0.002 | −0.010 | 0.006 | 0.015 |
Crisis | 0.003 | 0.005 | −0.038 | 0.003 | 0.019 | |
Post-crisis | 0.004 | 0.002 | −0.018 | 0.004 | 0.029 | |
Panel C: Macroeconomic Variables | ||||||
GDPGt−1 | Pre-crisis | 2.878 | 1.630 | 0.60 | 2.600 | 7.000 |
Crisis | −1.486 | 4.076 | −8.40 | −2.100 | 2.500 | |
Post-crisis | 2.257 | 1.545 | −1.10 | 2.300 | 5.500 | |
LEADt | Pre-crisis | 1.155 | 0.403 | 0.43 | 1.213 | 1.683 |
Crisis | −0.757 | 1.088 | −2.42 | −0.600 | 0.430 | |
Post-crisis | 1.456 | 0.376 | 0.01 | 1.517 | 1.933 | |
VIXMAXt | Pre-crisis | 23.016 | 8.690 | 12.67 | 19.960 | 45.080 |
Crisis | 44.851 | 19.253 | 24.12 | 42.280 | 80.860 | |
Post-crisis | 25.046 | 8.634 | 13.12 | 22.850 | 48.000 |
Explanatory Variable | Dependent Variable: PROVit | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Pre-Crisis | Pre-Crisis (Adjusted) | Crisis | Crisis (Adjusted) | Post-Crisis | Post-Crisis (Adjusted) | |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
NPLit | 0.121 *** | 0.127 *** | 0.195 *** | 0.152 ** | 0.085 *** | 0.079 *** |
(0.024) | (0.018) | (0.054) | (0.065) | (0.018) | (0.016) | |
RWACit | −0.001 | −0.001 | −0.001 | −0.003 | −0.0003 | −0.0003 |
(0.001) | (0.001) | (0.002) | (0.003) | (0.001) | (0.001) | |
WFUNDit | 0.001 | 0.001 | 0.007** | 0.004 | 0.001 | 0.001 |
(0.001) | (0.001) | (0.003) | (0.005) | (0.003) | (0.003) | |
RCAPit | −0.013 *** | −0.012 ** | 0.021 | 0.050 ** | −0.005 | −0.001 |
(0.005) | (0.006) | (0.020) | (0.025) | (0.004) | (0.004) | |
EBPTit | 0.126 | 0.177 * | −0.067 | −0.115 * | −0.020 | −0.020 |
(0.089) | (0.106) | (0.082) | (0.062) | (0.037) | (0.025) | |
GDPGt−1 | −0.005 *** | −0.004 *** | −0.019 *** | −0.010 | 0.005 | 0.005 |
(0.002) | (0.001) | (0.007) | (0.013) | (0.005) | (0.005) | |
LEADt | 0.002 | −0.012 | 0.172 ** | 0.140 | −0.268 *** | −0.277 *** |
(0.013) | (0.011) | (0.086) | (0.094) | (0.043) | (0.042) | |
VIXMAXt | 0.00003 *** | 0.00002 ** | 0.0001 ** | 0.0001 * | 0.00001 | 0.00001 |
(0.00001) | (0.00001) | (0.00004) | (0.00003) | (0.00001) | (0.00001) | |
Force Merged Adjusted? | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Bank Fixed Effects? | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
No. Banks | 25 | 25 | 25 | 25 | 25 | 25 |
Observations | 575 | 575 | 175 | 175 | 1050 | 1050 |
R2 | 0.346 | 0.421 | 0.481 | 0.429 | 0.652 | 0.688 |
Adjusted R2 | 0.307 | 0.387 | 0.364 | 0.300 | 0.641 | 0.678 |
Explanatory Variable | Dependent Variable: ALLLit | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Pre-Crisis | Pre-Crisis (Adjusted) | Crisis | Crisis (Adjusted) | Post-Crisis | Post-Crisis (Adjusted) | |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
NPLit | 0.477 *** | 0.636 *** | 0.315 *** | 0.325 *** | 0.377 *** | 0.390 *** |
(0.107) | (0.091) | (0.060) | (0.051) | (0.039) | (0.035) | |
RWACit | 0.008 ** | 0.007 * | −0.003 | −0.002 | 0.004 | 0.001 |
(0.004) | (0.004) | (0.002) | (0.002) | (0.004) | (0.004) | |
WFUNDit | −0.003 | −0.001 | 0.006 | 0.012 * | 0.016 | 0.019 * |
(0.002) | (0.002) | (0.005) | (0.007) | (0.010) | (0.010) | |
RCAPit | 0.107 *** | 0.110 *** | 0.149 *** | 0.149 *** | 0.059 ** | 0.021 |
(0.039) | (0.038) | (0.037) | (0.032) | (0.030) | (0.025) | |
EBPTit | −0.130 | −0.174 | 0.050 | 0.024 | −0.388 ** | −0.258 * |
(0.140) | (0.166) | (0.053) | (0.061) | (0.184) | (0.152) | |
GDPGt−1 | 0.008 | 0.007 | 0.019 ** | 0.026 * | 0.008 | 0.008 * |
(0.015) | (0.011) | (0.008) | (0.015) | (0.005) | (0.005) | |
LEADt | 0.100 | 0.103 | −0.063 | −0.086 | −0.191 *** | −0.181 *** |
(0.105) | (0.091) | (0.054) | (0.085) | (0.072) | (0.065) | |
VIXMAXt | 0.0001 *** | 0.0001 ** | −0.00003 * | −0.00004 ** | 0.0001 *** | 0.00005 *** |
(0.00003) | (0.00002) | (0.00002) | (0.00002) | (0.00002) | (0.00002) | |
Force Merged Adjusted? | N | Y | N | Y | N | Y |
Bank Fixed Effects? | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y | Y |
No. Banks | 25 | 25 | 25 | 25 | 25 | 25 |
Observations | 575 | 575 | 175 | 175 | 1050 | 1050 |
R2 | 0.605 | 0.675 | 0.859 | 0.846 | 0.787 | 0.805 |
Adjusted R2 | 0.582 | 0.656 | 0.828 | 0.812 | 0.780 | 0.798 |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Du, F.; Hancock, D.; von Hafften, A.H. Are Incurred Loss Standards Countercyclical? A Case Study Using U.S. Bank Holding Company Data. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2022, 15, 111. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030111
Du F, Hancock D, von Hafften AH. Are Incurred Loss Standards Countercyclical? A Case Study Using U.S. Bank Holding Company Data. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2022; 15(3):111. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030111
Chicago/Turabian StyleDu, Fang, Diana Hancock, and Alexander H. von Hafften. 2022. "Are Incurred Loss Standards Countercyclical? A Case Study Using U.S. Bank Holding Company Data" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 15, no. 3: 111. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030111
APA StyleDu, F., Hancock, D., & von Hafften, A. H. (2022). Are Incurred Loss Standards Countercyclical? A Case Study Using U.S. Bank Holding Company Data. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 15(3), 111. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm15030111