How Consideration of Future Consequences, Prior Gain or Loss, Personal Risk Profile, and Justification Affect Risk–Payoff Preferences
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Theoretical Background
2.1. Consideration of Future Consequences
2.2. Prior Gain/Loss and Risk
2.3. Justification
3. Hypotheses Development
4. Research Design
5. Analyses
6. Limitations and Future Research
7. Conclusions and Implications
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Appendix B
1------------------ | 2------------------ | 3---------- | 4---------- | 5-------------- | 6------------- | 7------------- |
Extremely | Moderately | Slightly | Neutral | Slightly | Moderately | Extremely |
Uncharacteristic | Uncharacteristic | Uncharacteristic | Characteristic | Characteristic | Characteristic |
____ 1. | I consider how things might be in the future, and try to influence those things with my day-to-day behavior. |
____ 2. | Often, I engage in behaviors to achieve outcomes that may not produce results for many years. |
____ 3. R | I only act to satisfy immediate concerns, figuring the future will take care of itself. |
____ 4. R | My behavior is only influenced by the immediate and short-term outcomes of my actions. |
____ 5. R | My convenience is a big factor in the decisions I make or the actions I take. |
____ 6. | I am willing to sacrifice my immediate happiness or well-being in order to achieve future outcomes. |
____ 7. | I think it is important to take warnings about negative outcomes seriously even if the negative outcome will not occur for many years. |
____ 8. | I think it is more important to perform a behavior with important distant consequences than a behavior with less important immediate consequences. |
____ 9. R | I generally ignore warnings about possible future problems because I think the problems will be resolved before they reach crisis level. |
____ 10. R | I think that sacrificing now is usually unnecessary since future outcomes can be dealt with at a later time. |
____ 11. R | I only act to satisfy immediate concerns, figuring that I will take care of future problems that may occur at a later date. |
____ 12. R | It is more important to me to take care of my day-to-day work that has immediate outcomes than my work that has distant outcomes. |
____ 13. | When I make a decision, I think about how it might affect me in the future. |
____ 14. | My behavior is generally influenced by future consequences. |
R: Reverse-scored items. |
1 | This is affirmed through a time clock monitored by a third-party researcher during the experimental study. In addition, there is no significant difference in the amount of time spent on both tasks by the participants from both conditions (p > 0.100). Justification responses received for both tasks were also quite uniform in length. |
2 | In analyzing the participants’ responses, Scenario 2 was reverse-coded. Lower (higher) combined scores for the responses from both scenarios thus indicate a greater affinity for lower (higher) risk and payoff. |
3 | Vilar et al. (2022) and Joireman et al. (2012) have alternatively suggested a two-factor solution (CFC-Future and CFC-Immediate) to the CFC scale. Dichotomizing into two factors, factor analyses similarly affirmed adequate internal reliabilities for both factors and a sufficiently robust model fit. |
4 | A greater number of participants responded in the upper half of the CFC scale (i.e., n = 339 for those with averages above ‘4′ on the CFC scale), as compared to those who responded in the lower half of the CFC scale (i.e., n = 27 for those with averages below ‘4′ on the CFC scale). Since ‘4′ on the 7-point CFC scale denotes a neutral position, and with the upper half denoting characteristic and the lower half denoting uncharacteristic, this study dichotomizes the high versus low CFC group at the midway point of the CFC scale. |
5 | Mann–Whitney U-testing was performed as a nonparametric alternative, with the results remaining qualitatively unchanged (p > 0.100). |
6 | Respondents were asked to self-assess their personal risk profile on a 0 (unwilling to take risks) to 10 (fully prepared to take risks) scale with the following question: “How do you see yourself in financial matters: Are you a person who is fully prepared to take risks or do you try to avoid taking risks?” (adapted from Dohmen et al. (2005)). The ‘risk avoider’ versus the ‘risk seeker’ group was differentiated using the midway point of 5 on the scale. Additional testing for the small number of respondents scoring ‘5′ shows that their subsequent responses were much closer to those of risk avoiders (p < 0.050), hence were also counted as risk avoiders. The results of the study remain qualitatively unchanged when this middle group is removed from the test sample (p > 0.100). |
7 | Results for risk and payoff are both directionally consistent; Untabulated analyses based on responses from those with low CFC showed that this group exhibits a uniformly greater inclination to prefer decision choices with a lower risk (i.e., higher probability) of a payoff, irrespective of differences in risk profiles as well as prior gain or loss position (all p > 0.100). |
8 | Untabulated analyses for those with low CFC show that the earlier observed preference for a lower risk variance spread remains unchanged regardless of whether a justification requirement is imposed or not (p > 0.100). |
9 | The sample and the general population data may differ in various dimensions. For instance, according to the U.S. Census Bureau projections’ data for 2022, the percentage of the population in the 18–24 age group is 9.4%, the percentage of the male population is 49.6%, and the percentage of persons 18–24 years of age with a Bachelors’ degree is 11.4% among that age group (see https://www.census.gov (accessed on 27 December 2023)). |
References
- Cahlikova, Jana, and Lubomir Cingl. 2017. Risk preferences under acute stress. Experimental Economics 20: 209–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dohmen, Thomas J., Armin Falk, David Huffman, Uwe Sunde, Jürgen Schupp, and Gert G. Wagner. 2005. Individual Risk Attitudes: New Evidence from a Large, Representative, Experimentally-Validated Survey. Discussion Paper No. 1730. Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Edwards, Ward. 1954. The theory of decision making. Psychological Bulletin 51: 380–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grable, John E., and Abed Rabbani. 2014. Risk tolerance across life domains: Evidence from a sample of older adults. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning 25: 174–83. [Google Scholar]
- Heider, Fritz. 1958. The Psychology of Interpersonal Relations. New York: John Wiley & Sons. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heo, Wookjae, Abed Rabbani, and John E. Grable. 2021. An evaluation of the effect of the COVID-19 pandemic on the risk tolerance of financial decision makers. Finance Research Letters 41: 101842. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hoorens, Vera, Jozef M. Nuttin Jr., Ildikó Erdélyi Herman, and Ubolwanna Pavakanun. 1990. Mastery pleasure versus mere ownership; A quasi-experimental cross-cultural and cross-alphabetical test of the name letter effect. European Journal of Social Psychology 20: 181–205. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Howlett, Elizabeth, Jeremy Kees, and Elyria Kemp. 2008. The role of self-regulation, future orientation, and financial knowledge in long-term financial decisions. The Journal of Consumer Affairs 42: 223–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Huber, Oswald, Arlette S. Bär, and Odilo W. Huber. 2009. Justification pressure in risky decision making: Search for risk defusing operators. Acta Psychologica 130: 17–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Irandoust, Manuchehr. 2017. Factors associated with financial risk tolerance based on proportional odds model: Evidence from Sweden. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning 28: 155–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Johnson, Van E., and Steven E. Kaplan. 1991. Experimental evidence on the effects of accountability on auditor judgments. Auditing: A Journal of Practice & Theory 10: 96–107. [Google Scholar]
- Joireman, Jeff, Alan Strathman, and Daniel Balliet. 2006. Considering future consequences: An integrative model. In Judgments over Time: The Interplay of Thoughts, Feelings, and Behaviors. Edited by Lawrence Sanna and Edward Chang. Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 88–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Joireman, Jeff, and Daniel Balliet. 2004. Preference for certain but smaller vs less certain but larger outcomes as a function of individual differences in the consideration of future consequences. Unpublished Data. [Google Scholar]
- Joireman, Jeff, David E. Sprott, and Eric R. Spangenberg. 2005. Fiscal responsibility and the consideration of future consequences. Personality and Individual Differences 39: 1159–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Joireman, Jeff, Monte Shaffer, Daniel Balliet, and Alan Strathman. 2012. Promotion orientation explains why future-oriented people exercise and eat healthy: Evidence from the two-factor consideration of future consequences-14 scale. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 38: 1272–87. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos Tversky. 1979. Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica 47: 263–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard H. Thaler. 1990. Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy 98: 1325–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kirchler, Michael, David Andersson, Caroline Bonn, Magnus Johannesson, Erik Sorenson, Matthias Stefan, Gustav Tinghog, and Daniel Vastfjall. 2017. The effects of fast and slow decisions on risk taking. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 54: 37–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Kocher, Martin, Julius Pahlke, and Stefan Trautmann. 2013. Tempus fugit: Time pressure in risky decisions. Management Science 59: 2380–91. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Koonce, Lisa, Marlys Lipe, and Mary McAnally. 2005a. Judging the risk of financial instruments: Problems and potential remedies. The Accounting Review 80: 871–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Koonce, Lisa, Mary McAnally, and Molly Mercer. 2005b. How do investors judge the risk of financial items? The Accounting Review 80: 221–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lerner, Jennifer. S., and Philip. E. Tetlock. 1999. Accounting for the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin 125: 255–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Libby, Robert, and Peter. C. Fishburn. 1977. Behavioral models of risk taking in business decisions: A survey and evaluation. Journal of Accounting Research 15: 272–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liberman, Nira, and Yaacov Trope. 1998. The role of feasibility and desirability considerations in near and distant future decisions: A test of temporal construal theory. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 75: 5–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mao, James C. T. 1970. Survey of capital budgeting: Theory and practice. Journal of Finance 25: 349–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Murphy, Lisa, Elmer Cadogan, and Samantha Dockray. 2020. The consideration of future consequences: Evidence for domain specificity across five life domains. Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 46: 663–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Noman, Abdullah, Lanlan Chu, and Mohammad Rahman. 2023. Subjective and objective financial knowledge and their associations with financial risk tolerance. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning 34: 219–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, Jisook, and W. Trey Hill. 2018. Exploring the role of justification and cognitive effort exertion on post-purchase regret in online shopping. Computers in Human Behavior 83: 235–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Payne, John W. 2005. It is whether you win or lose: The importance of the overall probabilities of winning or losing in risky choice. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 30: 5–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Payne, John W., and Myron L. Braunstein. 1971. Preferences among gambles with equal underlying distributions. Journal of Experimental Psychology 87: 13–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Payne, John W., Dan J. Laughhunn, and Roy Crum. 1980. Translation of gambles and aspiration level effects in risky choice behavior. Management Science 26: 1039–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Payne, John W., Dan J. Laughhunn, and Roy Crum. 1981. Further tests of aspiration level effects in risky choice behavior. Management Science 27: 953–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rabbani, Abed, John Grable, Barbara O’Neill, Frances Lawrence, and Zheying Yao. 2021. Financial risk tolerance before and after a stock market shock: Testing the recency bias hypothesis. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning 32: 294–310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schippers, Michaela, and Diana Rus. 2021. Optimizing decision-making processes in times of COVID-19: Using reflexivity to counteract information-processing failures. Frontiers in Psychology 12: 650525. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Sagristano, Michael, Yaacov Trope, and Nira Liberman. 2002. Time-dependent gambling: Odds now, money later. Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 131: 364–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schooley, Diane, and Debra Worden. 2016. Perceived and realized risk tolerance: Changes during the 2008 financial crisis. Journal of Financial Counseling and Planning 27: 265–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sharpe, William. 1970. Portfolio Theory and Capital Markets. New York: McGraw-Hill. [Google Scholar]
- Siegel, Sidney. 1957. Level of aspiration and decision making. Psychological Review 64: 253–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Simonson, Itamar, and Peter Nye. 1992. The effect of accountability on susceptibility to decision errors. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 51: 416–46. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Slovic, Paul. 1972. Psychological study of human judgment: Implications for investment decision making. Journal of Finance 27: 779–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Strathman, Alan, Faith Gleicher, David Boninger, and Scott Edwards. 1994. The consideration of future consequences: Weighing immediate and distant outcomes of behavior. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 66: 742–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tetlock, Philip E. 1983. Accountability and complexity of thought. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 45: 74–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tetlock, Philip E. 1985. Accountability: A social check on the fundamental attribution error. Social Psychology Quarterly 48: 227–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Trope, Yaacov, and Nira Liberman. 2000. Temporal construal and time-dependent changes in preference. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 79: 876–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman. 1973. Availability: A heuristic for judging frequency and probability. Cognitive Psychology 5: 207–32. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Vilar, Roosevelt, Taciano Milfont, Rafaella Araújo, Gabriel Coelho, Ana Soares, and Valdiney Gouveia. 2022. Consideration of future consequences (CFC): Validation and proposition of an ultra-short scale. Current Psychology 41: 3428–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zimbardo, Philip, and John Boyd. 1999. Putting time in perspective: A valid, reliable individual- differences metric. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 77: 1271–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Kaiser–Meyer–Olkin measure of sampling adequacy. | 0.877 | |
Bartlett’s test of sphericity: | Approx. chi-square | 1.666 × 103 |
Df | 91 | |
Sig. | 0.000 |
C1 | C2 | C3 | C4 | C5 | C6 | C7 | C8 | C9 | C10 | C11 | C12 | C13 | C14 | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
C1 | 1.0 | 0.317 | 0.372 | 0.344 | 0.110 | 0.332 | 0.245 | 0.186 | 0.302 | 0.326 | 0.403 | 0.296 | 0.527 | 0.552 | |
C2 | 0.317 | 1.0 | 0.233 | 0.237 | 0.217 | 0.298 | 0.093 | 0.190 | 0.132 | 0.219 | 0.364 | 0.297 | 0.267 | 0.335 | |
C3 | 0.372 | 0.233 | 1.000 | 0.684 | 0.243 | 0.280 | 0.183 | 0.155 | 0.293 | 0.361 | 0.604 | 0.365 | 0.335 | 0.396 | |
C4 | 0.344 | 0.237 | 0.684 | 1.000 | 0.287 | 0.244 | 0.191 | 0.148 | 0.312 | 0.313 | 0.555 | 0.352 | 0.341 | 0.386 | |
C5 | 0.110 | 0.217 | 0.243 | 0.287 | 1.000 | 0.042 | −0.009 | −0.011 | 0.190 | 0.241 | 0.292 | 0.253 | 0.039 | 0.073 | |
C6 | 0.332 | 0.298 | 0.280 | 0.244 | 0.042 | 1.00 | 0.356 | 0.200 | 0.131 | 0.296 | 0.389 | 0.247 | 0.329 | 0.388 | |
C7 | 0.245 | 0.093 | 0.183 | 0.191 | −0.009 | 0.356 | 1.00 | 0.239 | 0.398 | 0.364 | 0.272 | 0.149 | 0.370 | 0.313 | |
C8 | 0.186 | 0.190 | 0.155 | 0.148 | −0.011 | 0.200 | 0.239 | 1.00 | 0.176 | 0.199 | 0.219 | 0.061 | 0.230 | 0.238 | |
C9 | 0.302 | 0.132 | 0.293 | 0.312 | 0.190 | 0.131 | 0.398 | 0.176 | 1.000 | 0.469 | 0.407 | 0.296 | 0.366 | 0.355 | |
C10 | 0.326 | 0.219 | 0.361 | 0.313 | 0.241 | 0.296 | 0.364 | 0.199 | 0.469 | 1.000 | 0.505 | 0.310 | 0.366 | 0.330 | |
C11 | 0.403 | 0.364 | 0.604 | 0.555 | 0.292 | 0.389 | 0.272 | 0.219 | 0.407 | 0.505 | 1.000 | 0.469 | 0.394 | 0.425 | |
C12 | 0.296 | 0.297 | 0.365 | 0.352 | 0.253 | 0.247 | 0.149 | 0.061 | 0.296 | 0.310 | 0.469 | 1.000 | 0.294 | 0.294 | |
C13 | 0.527 | 0.267 | 0.335 | 0.341 | 0.039 | 0.329 | 0.370 | 0.230 | 0.366 | 0.366 | 0.394 | 0.294 | 1.00 | 0.646 | |
C14 | 0.552 | 0.335 | 0.396 | 0.386 | 0.073 | 0.388 | 0.313 | 0.238 | 0.355 | 0.330 | 0.425 | 0.294 | 0.646 | 1.000 | |
Sig. (1-tailed) | C1 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.018 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | |
C2 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.038 | 0.000 | 0.006 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C3 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.002 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C4 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.002 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C5 | 0.018 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.211 | 0.432 | 0.415 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.230 | 0.083 | ||
C6 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.211 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.006 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C7 | 0.000 | 0.038 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.432 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.002 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C8 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.002 | 0.002 | 0.415 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.122 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C9 | 0.000 | 0.006 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.006 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C10 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C11 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C12 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.002 | 0.122 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C13 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.230 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | ||
C14 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.083 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 |
Group Statistics | |||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
CFC | n | Mean | Std. Deviation | Std. Error Mean | |
DV | Low | 27 | 2.26 | 0.526 | 0.101 |
High | 339 | 2.83 | 0.854 | 0.046 |
Levene’s Test for Equality of Variances | t-Test for Equality of Means | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
F | Sig. | t | df | Sig. (2-Tailed) | Mean Difference | Std. Error Difference | 95% Confidence Interval of the Difference | |||
Lower | Upper | |||||||||
DV | Equal variances assumed | 22.309 | 0.000 | −3.393 | 364 | 0.001 | −0.567 | 0.167 | −0.895 | −0.238 |
Equal variances not assumed | −5.091 | 37.961 | 0.000 | −0.567 | 0.111 | −0.792 | −0.341 |
Description | Type | n |
---|---|---|
Risk | Seeker | 185 |
Avoider | 181 | |
Prior | Gain | 151 |
Neutral | 68 | |
Loss | 147 | |
Justification | No | 177 |
Yes | 189 | |
CFC | Low | 27 |
High | 339 |
Prior Gain/Loss | Justification | Risk Profile | Mean | Std. Deviation | n |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Gain | No | Seeker | 3.81 | 0.397 | 30 |
Avoider | 2.06 | 0.246 | 30 | ||
Total | 2.94 | 0.941 | 60 | ||
Yes | Seeker | 2.25 | 0.615 | 41 | |
Avoider | 2.02 | 0.152 | 41 | ||
Total | 2.14 | 0.462 | 82 | ||
Total | Seeker | 2.91 | 0.941 | 71 | |
Avoider | 2.04 | 0.197 | 71 | ||
Total | 2.48 | 0.807 | 142 | ||
Neutral | No | Seeker | 3.76 | 0.437 | 15 |
Avoider | 2.50 | 0.516 | 14 | ||
Total | 3.15 | 0.795 | 29 | ||
Yes | Seeker | 3.05 | 0.405 | 16 | |
Avoider | 2.12 | 0.342 | 14 | ||
Total | 2.63 | 0.598 | 30 | ||
Total | Seeker | 3.39 | 0.549 | 31 | |
Avoider | 2.31 | 0.471 | 28 | ||
Total | 2.88 | 0.744 | 59 | ||
Loss | No | Seeker | 3.82 | 0.385 | 38 |
Avoider | 3.77 | 0.423 | 37 | ||
Total | 3.80 | 0.403 | 75 | ||
Yes | Seeker | 3.00 | 0.250 | 31 | |
Avoider | 2.03 | 0.171 | 32 | ||
Total | 2.51 | 0.533 | 63 | ||
Total | Seeker | 3.45 | 0.528 | 69 | |
Avoider | 2.97 | 0.936 | 69 | ||
Total | 3.21 | 0.796 | 138 | ||
Total | No | Seeker | 3.81 | 0.395 | 82 |
Avoider | 2.92 | 0.887 | 82 | ||
Total | 3.37 | 0.816 | 164 | ||
Yes | Seeker | 2.67 | 0.610 | 89 | |
Avoider | 2.04 | 0.204 | 86 | ||
Total | 2.36 | 0.553 | 175 | ||
Total | Seeker | 3.22 | 0.771 | 171 | |
Avoider | 2.47 | 0.771 | 168 | ||
Total | 2.85 | 0.856 | 339 |
Source | Type III Sum of Squares | df | Mean Square | F | Sig. |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Corrected model | 186.385 a | 8 | 23.298 | 102.624 | 0.000 |
Intercept | 2573.013 | 1 | 2573.013 | 1.133 × 104 | 0.000 |
PriorGL (prior gain/loss position) | 28.226 | 2 | 14.113 | 62.165 | 0.000 |
Justification | 61.741 | 1 | 61.741 | 271.961 | 0.000 |
RiskProfile | 52.518 | 1 | 52.518 | 231.333 | 0.000 |
PriorGL ×RiskProfile | 5.433 | 2 | 2.717 | 11.966 | 0.000 |
PriorGL × justification | 7.642 | 2 | 3.821 | 16.831 | 0.000 |
Error | 74.91 | 330 | 0.227 | ||
Total | 3234 | 339 | |||
Corrected total | 267.432 | 338 |
CFC | Prior Gain/Loss | Risk Avoider/Seeker | Justification | Risk–Payoff Preference | Tests |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Low | Low | H1 √ | |||
High | High | ||||
High | Gain | No | Lower | H2a √ | |
High | Loss | No | Higher | ||
High | Gain | Avoider | No | Lower | H2b √ |
High | Gain | Seeker | No | Higher | |
High | Loss | Avoider | No | Higher | |
High | Loss | Seeker | No | Higher | |
High | Both Gain and loss | Avoider | Yes | Lower | H3 √ |
High | Gain | Seeker | Yes | Lower | Overall lower |
High | Loss | Seeker | Yes | Higher |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2024 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Lee, W.E. How Consideration of Future Consequences, Prior Gain or Loss, Personal Risk Profile, and Justification Affect Risk–Payoff Preferences. J. Risk Financial Manag. 2024, 17, 83. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17020083
Lee WE. How Consideration of Future Consequences, Prior Gain or Loss, Personal Risk Profile, and Justification Affect Risk–Payoff Preferences. Journal of Risk and Financial Management. 2024; 17(2):83. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17020083
Chicago/Turabian StyleLee, W. Eric. 2024. "How Consideration of Future Consequences, Prior Gain or Loss, Personal Risk Profile, and Justification Affect Risk–Payoff Preferences" Journal of Risk and Financial Management 17, no. 2: 83. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17020083
APA StyleLee, W. E. (2024). How Consideration of Future Consequences, Prior Gain or Loss, Personal Risk Profile, and Justification Affect Risk–Payoff Preferences. Journal of Risk and Financial Management, 17(2), 83. https://doi.org/10.3390/jrfm17020083