Simulating the Evolution of Business Models for Electricity Recharging Infrastructure Development by 2030: A Case Study for Greece
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Background
2.1. Literature Review and Motivation for Research
2.2. Defining Business Models for EV Recharging Infrastructure
- the electro-mobility service provider (EMSP), who offers electro-mobility services to the end users. The offered services may include, apart from vehicle charging, navigating services;
- the charging station operator (CSO), who is involved in the management, monitoring, and maintenance of a charging station and offers charging to the EMSP based on a business-to-business (B2B) relationship (directly or through a third party);
- the Distribution System Operator (DSO), the owner and operator of the distribution network. The DSO is the entity that maintains and operates the distribution network and provides a platform that allows the connection between the charging station and the electrical utilities.
3. Methodology
3.1. Modelling the Agents of Electro-Mobility
- The private investors generally allocate their capital in investing options that maximize the overall returns while minimizing the investment risks and considering the opportunity costs. To model their behaviour (i.e., investing in charging infrastructure), we utilize the internal rate of return (IRR) criterion to model whether the private investor will engage in the investment or not. We assume a decision threshold R which represents an estimation of the opportunity cost incurred to the investor by the former choice, i.e., it represents a rate of return that the investor could achieve by investing in other choices. If the IRR of charging infrastructure investments is below that threshold, the investor has no incentive to invest. The modelling considers only the case of fast charging points and assumes exogenously that a specific part of the electricity needs is provided by other types of charging points. The price of charging services comprises of the electricity price and the tariff for recovering the capital cost of the investment. The former is exogenous to the modelling and is provided by the PRIMES energy systems model [44]. The latter is endogenously calculated based on the utilisation of the charging points assuming that the tariff is calculated using the levelized cost approach. The overall price of the charging service is capped to an upper limit and, thus, considered being regulated. We carry out sensitivity analysis around this hypothesis;
- The policy maker promotes the decarbonisation of the energy system aiming to mitigate GHG emissions in the most efficient way. Decarbonisation entails setting a target on EV penetration. The EV penetration targets are exogenous to our modelling. If the electro-mobility system fails to achieve the target without the policy maker’s intervention, the latter chooses to either subsidize private investors, respecting an assumed subsidy budget per charging station, or to allow the DSO to deploy the EV infrastructure for some part of the modelled period (see Section 3.2). Further, we assume that the policy maker prioritizes the deployment of infrastructure by private agents (free market model) against employing a DSO model. This assumption effectively implements the EC proposal (COM (2016) 864);
- The DSO is modelled as an agent with a trivial behaviour that is activated by the policy maker and is influenced by the participation of private investors. Hence, the DSO model may not be activated in cases of high participation of private investors. Alternatively, the DSO model takes place in case of low interest from private investors that would hamper EV deployment and risk not meeting the penetration target. In this case, the DSO develops charging infrastructure that allows reaching the EV penetration targets, respecting an annual budget for charging infrastructure expenditures. It is assumed that the DSO follows a central planning approach in building charging stations and may not exceed an assumed budget for public infrastructure expenditures. The pricing of the charging service provided by the DSO is assumed to be regulated; the infrastructure costs are socially recovered via increases in electricity price;
- Consumers decide whether to purchase a conventional vehicle or an EV. They make their choice considering total cost of vehicle ownership (depending on capital, maintenance, fuel costs, and mileage), as well as perceived cost and, in particular, the lack of charging infrastructure (range anxiety). In our modelling the evolution of the capital and maintenance costs is exogenous. The rest of the cost components are endogenous. Fuel costs are calculated by adding the charging price (which are endogenous) and the electricity provided by the charging station. Range anxiety is an endogenous feature of the model as it relates to the availability of infrastructure which is the result of the choices of private investors and DSO model activation. The modelling of range anxiety draws from the PRIMES-TREMOVE model [45] and for the purposes of the present paper follows a reduced form approach.
3.2. A Game Theoretic View on the Interaction among the Agents
3.3. Mathematical Formulation of the Problem
4. Scenarios and Results: The Evolution of Electro-Mobility in Greece for the 2021–2030 Period
4.1. Background
4.2. Assumptions and Description of Scenarios
- The price of electricity, which is the variable cost of a charging station and affects the fuel cost of EVs draws from the PRIMES model [44] and ranges from 0.163 euros/kWh in 2021 to 0.175 euros/kWh in 2030. The remuneration of the capital cost of the charging points is calculated endogenously in the model based on the levelized cost of infrastructure. The charging price is assumed to be capped at 0.32 euros/kWh to prevent overcharging of EV users;
- The share of demand that is self-supplied by means of home charging is assumed to range from around 75% in the start of the 2021–2030 decade to around 70% in 2030, drawing from [47];
- The maximum annual subsidy per charging station is assumed to be 4000 euros. Recall that, in our modelling, the actual annual subsidy is endogenously derived each year to ensure a certain level of profitability for private investors;
- The annual budget for public infrastructure investment is assumed to be 15 million euros. Public infrastructure investments are made whenever DSO model deploys. In this case, the amount of investments depends on the infrastructure coverage required to achieve the desired level of EV penetration, following a central planning approach;
- The IRR decision threshold for private investors to engage in the charging infrastructure development is assumed to be 5%. We carry out sensitivity analysis on this assumption;
- All the techno-economic assumptions on the competing vehicle technologies, apart from the purchase cost of EVs, are common among the scenarios. These assumptions include vehicle mileage, fuel consumption, maintenance and insurance costs, and vehicle economic lifetime. For the competing fuel technologies, we assume two representative vehicles: a medium-sized gasoline car and a medium sized EV;
- Lastly, for public infrastructure we consider L3 DC fast recharging stations assuming a typical charging power of 50 KW.
4.3. Model Results
4.3.1. Penetration of EVs
4.3.2. Deployment of Private Investments in Charging Infrastructure Development
4.4. Sensitivity Analysis
- charging prices of the private investors, by assuming that the capital cost recovery is based on pre-defined regulated prices;
- values of IRR decision threshold for private investors to engage in the recharging infrastructure development business;
- levels of the maximum available budget (per charging point) for subsidising private investors.
4.4.1. The Effects of Different Levels of Regulated Charging Tariffs on the Infrastructure Deployment
4.4.2. Sensitivity Analysis on Private Investors’ IRR
4.4.3. Sensitivity Analysis on the Available Budget
5. Conclusions
5.1. Policy Implications
5.2. Limitations and Scope for Further Research
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- EC. A Clean Planet for all A European Strategic Long-Term Vision for a Prosperous, Modern, Competitive and Climate Neutral Economy: In-Depth Analysis in Support of the Commission Communication COM(2018) 773. 2018. Available online: https://knowledge4policy.ec.europa.eu/publication/depth-analysis-support-com2018-773-clean-planet-all-european-strategic-long-term-vision_en (accessed on 21 February 2021).
- Connolly, D.; Mathiesen, B.V.; Ridjan, I. A comparison between renewable transport fuels that can supplement or replace biofuels in a 100% renewable energy system. Energy 2014, 73, 110–125. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- McCollum, D.; Krey, V.; Kolp, P.; Nagai, Y.; Riahi, K. Transport electrification: A key element for energy system transformation and climate stabilization. Clim. Chang. 2014, 123, 651–664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pietzcker, R.C.; Longden, T.; Chen, W.; Fu, S.; Kriegler, E.; Kyle, P.; Luderer, G. Long-term transport energy demand and climate policy: Alternative visions on transport decarbonization in energy-economy models. Energy 2014, 64, 95–108. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Bosetti, V.; Longden, T. Light duty vehicle transportation and global climate policy: The importance of electric drive vehicles. Energy Policy 2013, 58, 209–219. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhang, Q.; Li, H.; Zhu, L.; Campana, P.E.; Lu, H.; Wallin, F.; Sun, Q. Factors influencing the economics of public charging infrastructures for EV—A review. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2018, 94, 500–509. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sierzchula, W.; Bakker, S.; Maat, K.; Wee, B. The influence of financial incentives and other socio-economic factors on electric vehicle adoption. Energy Policy 2014, 68, 183–194. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Statharas, S.; Moysoglou, Y.; Siskos, P.; Zazias, G.; Capros, P. Factors Influencing Electric Vehicle Penetration in the EU by 2030: A Model-Based Policy Assessment. Energies 2019, 12, 2739. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dong, J.; Lin, Z. Within-day recharge of plug-in hybrid electric vehicles: Energy impact of public charging infrastructure. Trans. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2012, 17, 405–412. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sioshansi, F.; Webb, J. Transitioning from conventional to electric vehicles: The effect of cost and environmental drivers on peak oil demand. Econ. Anal. Policy 2019, 61, 7–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, S.; Wang, J.; Li, J.; Wang, J.; Liang, L. Policy implications for promoting the adoption of electric vehicles: Do consumer’s knowledge, perceived risk and financial incentive policy matter? Trans. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2018, 117, 58–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Myklebust, B. EVs in bus lanes—Controversial incentive. In Proceedings of the World Electric Vehicle Symposium and Exhibition, Barcelona, Spain, 17–20 November 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Nie, Y.M.; Ghamami, M.; Zockaie, A.; Xiao, F. Optimization of incentive polices for plug-in electric vehicles. Trans. Res. Part B Methodol. 2016, 84, 103–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sykes, M.; Axsen, J. No free ride to zero-emissions: Simulating a region’s need to implement its own zero-emissions vehicle (ZEV) mandate to achieve 2050 GHG targets. Energy Policy 2017, 110, 447–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Siskos, P.; Moysoglou, Y. Assessing the impacts of setting CO₂ emission targets on truck manufacturers: A model implementation and application for the EU. Trans. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2019, 125, 123–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Speidel, S.; Bräunl, T. Driving and charging patterns of electric vehicles for energy usage. Renew. Sustain. Energy Rev. 2014, 40, 97–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Morrissey, P.; Weldon, P.; Mahony, M.O. Future standard and fast charging infrastructure planning: An analysis of electric vehicle charging behaviour. Energy Policy 2016, 89, 257–270. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kihm, A.; Trommer, S. The new car market for electric vehicles and the potential for fuel substitution. Energy Policy 2014, 73, 147–157. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Neaimeh, M.; Salisbury, S.D.; Hill, G.A.; Blythe, P.T.; Scoffield, D.R.; Francfort, J.E. Analysing the usage and evidencing the importance of fast chargers for the adoption of battery electric vehicles. Energy Policy 2017, 108, 474–486. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lin, Z.; Greene, D.L. Promoting the market for plug-in hybrid and battery electric vehicles: Role of recharge availability. Trans. Res. Rec. 2011, 2252, 49–56. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Greene, D.L.; Kontou, E.; Borlaug, B.; Brooker, A.; Muratori, M. Public charging infrastructure for plug-in electric vehicles: What is it worth? Trans. Res. Part D Trans. Environ. 2020, 78, 102182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kontou, E.; Liu, C.; Xie, F.; Wu, X.; Lin, Z. Understanding the linkage between electric vehicle charging network coverage and charging opportunity using GPS travel data. Trans. Res. Part C Emerg. Technol. 2019, 98, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kley, F.; Lerch, C.; Dallinger, D. New business models for electric cars—A holistic approach. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 3392–3403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Patt, A.; Aplyn, D.; Weyrich, P.; Vliet, O. Availability of private charging infrastructure influences readiness to buy electric cars. Trans. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2019, 125, 1–7. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Siskos, P.; Zazias, G.; Petropoulos, A.; Evangelopoulou, S.; Capros, P. Implications of delaying transport decarbonisation in the EU: A systems analysis using the PRIMES model. Energy Policy 2018, 121, 48–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schroeder, A.; Traber, T. The economics of fast charging infrastructure for electric vehicles. Energy Policy 2012, 43, 136–144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gnann, T.; Plötz, P.; Wietschel, M. How to address the chicken-egg-problem of electric vehicles? Introducing an interaction market diffusion model for EVs and charging infrastructure. In Proceedings of the ECEEE Summer Study, Toulon, France, 1–6 June 2015; pp. 873–884. [Google Scholar]
- Baresch, M.; Moser, S. Allocation of e-car charging: Assessing the utilization of charging infrastructures by location. Trans. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2019, 124, 388–395. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Madina, C.; Zamora, I.; Zabala, E. Methodology for assessing electric vehicle charging infrastructure business models. Energy Policy 2016, 89, 284–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhang, L.; Zhao, Z.; Xin, H.; Chai, J.; Wang, G. Charge pricing model for electric vehicle charging infrastructure public-private partnership projects in China: A system dynamics analysis. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 199, 321–333. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, L.; Yang, M.; Zhao, Z. Game analysis of charging service fee based on benefit of multi-party participants: A case study analysis in China. Sustain. Cities Soc. 2019, 48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Osterwalder, A.; Pigneur, Y. Business Model Generation: A Handbook for Visionaries, Game Changers, and Challengers; John Wiley & Sons: Hoboken, NJ, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Adler, M.; Bagemihl, J.; Bernard, G.; Biser, T.; Caleno, F.; Sanchez, J.M.C.; Densley, D.; Exposito, E.D.; Flader, L.; Martin, J.G.; et al. Eurelectric. Deploying publicly accessible charging infrastructure for electric vehicles: How to organise the market? Eurelectric Concept Pap. 2013. Dépôt légal: D/2013/12.105/35. Available online: https://www.eurelectric.org/media/1816/0702_emobility_market_model_final_ac-2013-030-0501-01-e.pdf (accessed on 21 February 2021).
- Papathanasiou, S.; Schina, O. Suggestions for the function of electro-mobility market in Greece. Rep. Regul. Auth. Energy 2019. (In Greek) [Google Scholar]
- Energy Saving Trust. Procuring electric vehicle charging infrastructure as a local authority. Rep. Energy Sav. Trust. 2019.
- International Energy Agency. Germany Charging Infrastructure. 2019. Available online: http://www.ieahev.org/by-country/germany-charging-infrastructure/ (accessed on 20 April 2021).
- Chen, D.; Jing, Z.; Tan, H. Optimal Bidding/Offering Strategy for EV Aggregators under a Novel Business Model. Energies 2019, 12, 1384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Guo, Y.; Liu, W.; Wen, F.; Salam, A.; Mao, J.; Li, L. Bidding Strategy for Aggregators of Electric Vehicles in Day-Ahead Electricity Markets. Energies 2017, 10, 144. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Schiavo, L.; Bonafede, D.; Celaschi, S.; Colzi, F. Regulatory Issues in the Development of Electro-Mobility Services: Lessons Learned from the Italian Experience. In Proceedings of the 1st e-Mobility Power System Integration Symposium, Berlin, Germany, 23 October 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Caleno, F.; Coppola, G. DSO business model for speeding up EVs mass market. In Proceedings of the 22nd International Conference on Electricity Distribution, Stockholm, Sweden, 10–13 June 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Eurelectric. Charging Infrastructure for electric vehicles. Eurelectric Position Pap. 2016.
- Lorentzen, E.; Haugneland, P.; Bu, C.; Hauge, E. Charging infrastructure experiences in Norway—The worlds most advanced EV market. In Proceedings of the EVS30 International Battery, Hybrid and Fuel Cell Electric Vehicle Symposium, Stuttgart, Germany, 9–11 October 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Burger, S.P.; Luke, M. Business models for distributed energy resources: A review and empirical analysis. Energy Policy 2017, 109, 230–248. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Capros, P.; Zazias, G.; Evangelopoulou, S.; Kannavou, M.; Fotiou, T.; Siskos, P.; Sakellaris, K. Energy-system modelling of the EU strategy towards climate-neutrality. Energy Policy 2019, 134, 110960. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Siskos, P.; Capros, P.; de Vita, A. CO2 and energy efficiency car standards in the EU in the context of a decarbonisation strategy: A model-based policy assessment. Energy Policy 2015, 84, 22–34. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hellenic Republic Ministry of the Environment and Energy. National Energy and Climate Plan. December 2019. Available online: https://ec.europa.eu/energy/sites/ener/files/el_final_necp_main_en.pdf (accessed on 20 April 2021).
- Nicholas, M.; Hall, D.; Lutsey, N. Quantifying the electric vehicle charging infrastructure gap across U.S. markets. ICCT White Pap. 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Vagropoulos, S.; Kleidaras, A.; Bakirtzis, A. Financial Viability of Investments on Electric Vehicle Charging Stations in Workplaces with Parking Lots under Flat Rate Retail Tariff Schemes. In Proceedings of the Universities Power Engineering Conference, Cluj-Napoca, Romania, 2–5 September 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Kang, N.; Feinberg, F.M.; Papalambros, P.Y. Integrated decision making in electric vehicle and charging station location network design. J. Mech. Des. 2015, 137, 061402. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Business Model Category | Infrastructure Deployment | Advantages | Disadvantages | Application Examples |
---|---|---|---|---|
Private free market model | Private | Competition ensures optimal cost and utilization of infrastructure | Uneven spatial deployment, chicken-egg dilemma | Germany, UK, Italy |
Public DSO-type model | Public | Deployment of infrastructure even in remote areas, resolution of chicken egg dilemma | Problematic adaptation to changing charging needs | Austria, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg |
Public tenders hybrid model | Private (central planning) | Even infrastructure deployment, merits of competition | Delays due to tendering procedures, binding infrastructure deployment | Norway |
Decision Makers | Objectives and Behaviour | Notes |
---|---|---|
Private investor | Seeks to allocate capital in profitable investing options. If charging businesses display a certain level of profitability, the private investor expresses interest to invest in charging infrastructure. |
|
Consumers | Modelled to select purchasing either an EV or a conventional vehicle depending on the total cost of ownership of the options and the density of charging infrastructure. |
|
Policy maker | Sets concrete targets regarding the envisaged penetration of EVs. Needs to ensure the availability of recharging points to promote uptake of EVs. |
|
DSO | DSO’s role in infrastructure deployment is activated via a public DSO-type model only if the private sector does not express interest in infrastructure investments. |
|
Name | Type | Description |
---|---|---|
endogenous | The number of EVs incited by deployed infrastructure when the DSO is not involved | |
endogenous | The number of EVs incited by infrastructure, deployed either by private investors or DSO | |
endogenous | Existing stock of EVs inherited from previous periods. | |
exogenous | EV penetration target | |
exogenous | Upper bound of annual subsidy given per charging station (‘000 euros) | |
exogenous | Annual DSO’s budget for infrastructure investments (‘000 euros) | |
exogenous | Spatial factor denoting the geographical coverage a single charging station satisfies | |
exogenous | Self-Supply factor: fraction of a single EV’s demand that can be satisfied by means of charging at home/work | |
endogenous | Amount of charging demand that is supplied by chargers at home/work | |
exogenous | Capital cost of a charging station | |
exogenous | total cost of ownership for EVs | |
exogenous | total cost of ownership for the typical ICE conventional vehicle | |
EVdemand | exogenous | the annual charging demand of a representative EV in kWh/year |
endogenous | The annual subsidy per charging station in ‘000 euros/year | |
endogenous | Total annual charging demand considering only the private investors involvement in GWh | |
endogenous | Total charging demand incurred by the deployment of infrastructure by private investors and DSO | |
endogenous | New privately deployed infrastructure for the current period (number of charging stations) | |
endogenous | Total new infrastructure deployed in the current period | |
exogenous | Existing infrastructure inherited from previous periods. | |
exogenous | Maximum possible number of charging stations | |
endogenous | Private agent’s infrastructure investments in ‘000 euros | |
endogenous | DSO infrastructure investments in ‘000 euros | |
endogenous | Charging station’s annual cash flow | |
endogenous | The internal rate of return for charging infrastructure investments | |
exogenous | Decision threshold on the value of IRR | |
endogenous | Annual demand satisfied by a single charging station | |
endogenous | Charging price in Euros/kWh |
Scenario Name | EV Purchase Cost | Charging Station Capital Cost |
---|---|---|
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | Low Cost (optimistic) | Low Cost (optimistic) |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | Low Cost (optimistic) | Central Cost |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | Low Cost (optimistic) | High Cost (pessimistic) |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | Central Cost | Low Cost (optimistic) |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | Central Cost | Central Cost |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | Central Cost | High Cost (pessimistic) |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | High Cost (pessimistic) | Low Cost (optimistic) |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | High Cost (pessimistic) | Central Cost |
High EV-High Ch.Point | High Cost (pessimistic) | High Cost (pessimistic) |
Euros | 2020 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Low Cost | 27,000 | 23,000 | |
Moderate Cost | 31,000 | 28,000 | 24,000 |
High Cost | 29,000 | 27,000 |
Euros | 2020 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Low Cost | 36,500 | 28,000 | |
Moderate Cost | 44,000 | 40,000 | 35,000 |
High Cost | 42,500 | 40,000 |
Scenario | 2021 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | 2.7 | 143 | 549 |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | 2.6 | 143 | 535 |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | 2.5 | 143 | 527 |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | 2.6 | 143 | 530 |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 2.5 | 143 | 518 |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | 2.5 | 142 | 511 |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | 2.5 | 143 | 504 |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | 2.4 | 142 | 493 |
High EV-High Ch.Point | 1.8 | 138 | 479 |
Scenario | 2021 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | 79 | 1719 | 5245 |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | 78 | 1708 | 4924 |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | 78 | 1695 | 4746 |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | 79 | 1765 | 5066 |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 78 | 1757 | 4772 |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | 78 | 1751 | 4599 |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | 79 | 1841 | 4822 |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | 78 | 1832 | 4541 |
High EV-High Ch.Point | 73 | 1822 | 4312 |
Scenario | 2021 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | 34% | 85% | |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | 34% | 84% | |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | 33% | 83% | |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | 35% | 84% | |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 0% | 35% | 83% |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | 31% | 81% | |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | 36% | 82% | |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | 32% | 80% | |
High EV-High Ch.Point | 25% | 76% |
Scenario | 2024 | 2025 | 2026 | 2027 | 2028 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | 3700 | 2600 | 1200 | 0 | 0 |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | 3900 | 2800 | 1500 | 100 | 0 |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | 4000 | 3000 | 1600 | 200 | 0 |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | 3800 | 2700 | 1400 | 200 | 0 |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 4000 | 3000 | 1700 | 400 | 0 |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | 4000 | 3200 | 1900 | 600 | 0 |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | 3900 | 3000 | 1800 | 600 | 0 |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | 4000 | 3200 | 2000 | 900 | 0 |
High EV-High Ch.Point | 4000 | 4000 | 2700 | 500 | 300 |
Scenario | 2021 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | 3.5 | 52.7 | 53.7 |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | 3.4 | 54.2 | 55.6 |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | 3.4 | 55.9 | 57.6 |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | 3.5 | 53.7 | 55.3 |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 3.4 | 55.3 | 57.4 |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | 3.4 | 58.6 | 60.9 |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | 3.5 | 55.5 | 58.1 |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | 3.4 | 59.6 | 62.7 |
High EV-High Ch.Point | 3.2 | 71.6 | 75.8 |
Scenario | Tariff for Recovery of the Capital Cost of Charging Point | Total Charging Tariff (Incl. Electricity Price) | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
2025 | 2030 | 2025 | 2030 | |
Low EV-Low Ch.Point | 0.131 | 0.114 | 0.281 | 0.289 |
Low EV-Mid Ch.Point | 0.137 | 0.126 | 0.287 | 0.301 |
Low EV-High Ch.Point | 0.142 | 0.137 | 0.292 | 0.312 |
Mid EV-Low Ch.Point | 0.133 | 0.116 | 0.283 | 0.291 |
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 0.141 | 0.131 | 0.291 | 0.306 |
Mid EV-High Ch.Point | 0.147 | 0.142 | 0.297 | 0.317 |
High EV-Low Ch.Point | 0.136 | 0.119 | 0.286 | 0.294 |
High EV-Mid Ch.Point | 0.146 | 0.136 | 0.296 | 0.311 |
High EV-High Ch.Point | 0.152 | 0.137 | 0.302 | 0.312 |
Scenario | Cumulative Number of Stations | Share of Stations Developed by Private Agents |
---|---|---|
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 4772 | 83% |
High Ch.Price | 4985 | 89% |
Low Ch.Price | 4547 | 77% |
Scenario | Cumulative Number of Stations | Share of Stations Developed by Private Agents | EV Fleet |
---|---|---|---|
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 4772 | 83% | 518.2 |
IRR_8 | 4186 | 75% | 491.9 |
IRR_12 | 3408 | 61% | 465.7 |
Scenario | 2021 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 1757 | 4772 | |
High Sub | 78 | 1803 | 4799 |
Low Sub | 1690 | 4727 |
Scenario | 2021 | 2025 | 2030 |
---|---|---|---|
Mid EV-Mid Ch.Point | 0% | 35% | 83% |
High Sub | 52% | 88% | |
Low Sub | 0% | 71% |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Statharas, S.; Moysoglou, Y.; Siskos, P.; Capros, P. Simulating the Evolution of Business Models for Electricity Recharging Infrastructure Development by 2030: A Case Study for Greece. Energies 2021, 14, 2345. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14092345
Statharas S, Moysoglou Y, Siskos P, Capros P. Simulating the Evolution of Business Models for Electricity Recharging Infrastructure Development by 2030: A Case Study for Greece. Energies. 2021; 14(9):2345. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14092345
Chicago/Turabian StyleStatharas, Stergios, Yannis Moysoglou, Pelopidas Siskos, and Pantelis Capros. 2021. "Simulating the Evolution of Business Models for Electricity Recharging Infrastructure Development by 2030: A Case Study for Greece" Energies 14, no. 9: 2345. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14092345
APA StyleStatharas, S., Moysoglou, Y., Siskos, P., & Capros, P. (2021). Simulating the Evolution of Business Models for Electricity Recharging Infrastructure Development by 2030: A Case Study for Greece. Energies, 14(9), 2345. https://doi.org/10.3390/en14092345