Assessing the Effects of Tradable Green Certificates and Renewable Portfolio Standards through Demand-Side Decision-Making Simulation: A Case of a System Containing Photovoltaic Power
Abstract
:1. Introduction
1.1. Background
1.2. Literature Review
- (1)
- The impact on the supply side. Marchenko et al. [9] and Qu et al. [10] pointed out that TGC transactions can increase the profits of renewable-energy manufacturers, thereby promoting generation of renewable energy. As an important way to make up for the gap in subsidies, TGC transactions provide additional funds for renewable energy, which can promote the green transformation of the power-supply side [11,12]. In addition, Song et al. [13] and Zhang et al. [14] applied system dynamics (SDs) and pointed out that TGC transactions can promote investment in the renewable-energy industry, thereby improving the structural proportion of renewable energy on the supply side. Similarly, Zhao et al. [15] constructed an evolutionary-game model and proposed that TGC transactions could promote renewable-energy development in the long term.
- (2)
- The impact on power dispatching and transactions. Considering the environmental value of TGCs, Liang et al. [16], Yuan et al. [17] and Li et al. [18] pointed out that the TGC + RPS policy can reduce the amount of discarded photovoltaic power. In addition, the coupled interaction between TGCs and the power market has a significant impact on the behavior of power producers [19,20]. For example, Wang et al. [21] constructed a decision-optimization model considering subjects’ preferences and utility, and the results showed that TGC price is an important factor affecting the profitability of energy manufacturers.
- (3)
- Exploration of TGC price mechanisms. A reasonable price mechanism can support the development of the TGC market, RPSs and the renewable-energy industry [22,23]. For example, Tu et al. [24] proposed that setting the unit price of TGCs between 84.57 CNY and 330.28 CNY could reduce investment risk and promote development of photovoltaic power. Zhao et al. [25] pointed out that under the voluntary subscription mechanism, the impact of factors such as assessment period, the discount rate and subsidies should be considered when setting TGC prices.
- (1)
- The existing research focuses on the effect of the “TGC + RPS” policy on supply-side subjects from a long-term perspective. According to China’s RPS, demand-side subjects are the subjects of responsibility, subjects’ decision-making behaviors and market performance are affected by changes in supply and demand in a short period (the one-year assessment period) and relevant research is limited.
- (2)
- Current research on the relationship between the TGC market, power dispatching and power trading usually regards the TGC market as an external static boundary, and few studies have considered the impact of power transactions on TGC market performance.
- (3)
- Most existing studies design the TGC price mechanism from a static perspective, ignoring the causal feedback relationship among responsible subjects’ decision-making behaviors, TGCs and the electricity market.
- (1)
- In terms of research perspective, this paper focuses on the demand side and reveals the causal feedback relationship between the demand side and TGC market performance, namely, reflexivity. This expands the perspective from research objects and theory.
- (2)
- In terms of research content, on the basis of analyzing factors affecting China’s TGC market performance, this paper casts demand-side responsible subjects’ decision-making behaviors as a sequential decision-making process and analyzes the influences of RPS weight, the TGC price cap, penalties and discount factors on responsible subjects’ behaviors. These make up for the shortcomings of previous studies in demand-side behavior analysis and dynamic TGC-price evolution.
- (3)
- In terms of research methods, an MDP model was constructed to simulate the sequential decision-making of responsible subjects, and the Gaussian mixture model was used to deal with renewable-energy uncertainty. Through applying dynamic programming (DP) and evolutionary algorithms (EAs) to solve the MDP model, this paper discusses the decision-making trends of responsible subjects, thus providing a reference for relevant policy improvement.
2. The TGC Market under RPSs and Research Assumptions
2.1. China’s TGC Market
- (1)
- Renewable-power and TGC transactions. TGCs can be issued after renewable power is traded, which means that renewable-power transactions will affect not only RPS target completion but also TGC supply capacity; meanwhile, TGC transaction results can directly change the stock of TGCs, thus changing the supply–demand relationship in the TGC market.
- (2)
- RPS weight. When power-consumption demand and renewable-energy unit capacity are constant, the RPS weight can determine the RPS targets to be accomplished, thereby affecting the demand for TGCs.
- (3)
- Penalties. The difference between penalty cost and transaction cost can affect responsible subjects’ TGC purchase strategies directly. In reference to the experiences with the “TGC transaction + RPS assessment” mechanism in various countries, setting a penalty mechanism is an important means to improve the TGC market mechanism and ensure consumption of renewable power. That is, when responsible subjects fail to complete the RPS target, they will be required to pay the penalty per megawatt–hour.
- (4)
- TGC utility. TGC utility represents the ability of purchased TGCs to satisfy the needs of responsible subjects. Based on cardinal utility theory, at the beginning of the assessment period, the RPS target would be far from being completed, so the utility generated by purchasing TGCs is obvious, and the acceptable TGC price for responsible subjects is high; as the unfulfilled RPS target decreases, the utility will gradually weaken and the acceptable price will decrease.
- (5)
- Assessment period. As the remaining time in the assessment period decreases, in order to reduce the penalty cost and recover the operating cost, enthusiasm of market subjects to participate in TGC transactions will be enhanced. Therefore, the acceptable price for buyers may rise, while the acceptable price for sellers may decrease [25]. Meanwhile, as the assessment period comes to an end, the supply of renewable power and TGCs will weaken, and the acceptable TGC price for sellers may rise.
2.2. Reflexivity of the TGC Market
- (1)
- Market states determine responsible subjects’ purchasing decisions. The available renewable-energy output, renewable power and TGC trading results will affect the supply capacity, utility and price of TGCs and further affect responsible subjects’ transaction decisions.
- (2)
- Responsible subjects’ behaviors will shape the future market state. The timing and quantity of responsible subjects’ purchases of renewable power and TGCs will indirectly or directly change the supply of TGCs, thus affecting the supply–demand relationship, utility and price of TGCs in the future market.
2.3. Research Assumption
- (a)
- Suppliers in the electricity market are renewable-energy manufacturers, and thermal-power manufacturers and suppliers in the TGC market are also renewable-energy manufacturers.
- (b)
- As buyers in the electricity and TGC markets, responsible subjects are rational subjects that pursue cost minimization.
- (c)
- TGCs and renewable power are not bundled for trade.
- (d)
- The electricity market and the TGC market are monthly markets. The trading deviations in the electricity market due to renewable-power uncertainty can be balanced by trading in the balanced market.
3. Methodology
3.1. Problem and Model Description
- (a)
- A sequence of time steps, , where T = 12.
- (b)
- A set of uncontrolled inputs, , where each i is represented by a state variable: .
- (c)
- A set of controlled inputs, , where each j is represented by a decision variable: .
- (d)
- Constraints for state and decision variables, including thermal power and renewable-energy-unit output constraints, power supply–demand balance constraints, etc.
- (e)
- A transition function, , where consists of the constraints of the variables at time step t.
- (f)
- An objective function, , where represents the reward incurred at time step t. In this work, the reward is the sum of the costs of purchasing renewable power, thermal power, TGCs and penalties.
3.2. Modeling
3.2.1. TGC Price
3.2.2. Renewable-Energy Uncertainty
3.2.3. Objective Function
3.2.4. Constraints
3.3. Solution
Algorithm 1: Solution based on DP and EAs | |
1 | Initialize , , , maximum of iterations K, |
2 | for k = 1 to K |
3 | for t = 1 to T |
4 | Calculate , |
5 | end for |
6 | for t = T to 1 |
7 | Use EA to extract optimal policy by solving Equation (27), update , , |
8 | end for |
9 | Calculate objective function at kth iteration |
10 | Calculate the variation between objective function of kth and (k−1)th, |
11 | if < |
12 | break |
13 | end if |
14 | k = k + 1 |
15 | end for |
16 | Return the optimal policy and objective function value |
4. Simulations and Discussion
4.1. Basic Scenario and Data
4.2. RPS Weight
4.3. TGC Price Cap
4.4. Penalty
4.5. Discount Factor
4.5.1. RPS Weight
4.5.2. TGC Price Cap
4.5.3. Penalty
5. Conclusions and Policy Implications
5.1. Conclusions
- (1)
- In general, policy parameters such as RPS weight, TGC price cap and penalty have significant impacts on responsible subjects’ renewable power and TGC transaction behavior under the “TGC transaction + RPS assessment” policy mix, and it is by no means true that the higher or lower a parameter is, the more it can promote the demand side to complete the RPS target. Additionally, the policy’s effect is also influenced by other factors, including demand-side subjects’ preference for short-term benefits, renewable-energy uncertainty, price difference, etc.
- (2)
- Under the annual assessment and penalty mechanism, increasing RPS weight within an appropriate range can improve responsible subjects’ enthusiasm for purchasing renewable power and TGCs and willingness to bear the risks caused by renewable-energy uncertainty without significantly increasing costs. Additionally, an increase in RPS weight can effectively alleviate price fluctuation of TGCs. However, when the RPS weight is set at a low range, increasing the RPS weight will have a stronger stimulating effect on the demand for renewable power than on the demand for TGCs, which may lead to excessive accumulation of unsold TGCs; as a result, renewable-energy manufacturers cannot relieve operating pressure via selling TGCs. This is contrary to the original intention of promoting renewable-energy development and alleviating subsidy pressure via establishing the RPS and TGC markets. In addition, when responsible subjects prefer short-term benefits, they tend to increase TGC purchases and reduce renewable-power purchases to complete RPS targets, which will become more and more obvious with increases in RPS weight. In addition, when the penalty is equal to the TGC price cap, excessively increasing RPS weight can lead to a sharp drop in the transaction volumes of renewable power and TGCs.
- (3)
- When the RPS target is higher than the annual available renewable-unit output, appropriately increasing the TGC price cap will not significantly increase the cost of completing the RPS target for responsible subjects and will increase the purchase of renewable energy, but the responsible subjects will reduce the total purchases of TGCs. That is to say, if the TGC price cap is too high, it may lead to accumulation of massive unsold TGCs, which will further increase the difficulty for renewable-energy manufacturers to recover operating costs through TGC transactions. It is worth noting that when the RPS weight is too low and responsible subjects prefer short-term benefits, increasing the TGC price cap has no significant impact on responsible subjects’ purchasing strategies for renewable power and TGCs or RPS completion progress.
- (4)
- Setting a penalty of no less than the TGC price cap can ensure effective operation of the TGC market. Appropriately increasing the penalty can increase the willingness of responsible subjects to undertake the uncertainty risk and to purchase more renewable power while not causing a significant impact on transaction costs. However, an increase in the penalty will cause declines in price and trading volume in the TGC market and an increase of unsold TGCs. It should also be noted that when the RPS weight is high, setting a penalty greater than the TGC price cap is necessary to promote the completion of the RPS target, and an increase in the penalty can promote monthly and annual TGC purchases. In addition, when responsible subjects prefer short-term benefits, the increase in renewable-power transactions and unsold TGCs and the decline in TGC transactions and TGC prices due to increased penalties still exist. However, an increase in the penalty can alleviate the decline in renewable-power transactions caused by the preference for short-term benefits, as mentioned in (1), to a certain extent.
5.2. Implications
- (1)
- Promote the transition of the TGC transaction mode from voluntary subscription to market-oriented transactions. Under the RPS policy, reasonable policy parameter design and market-oriented transactions can fully urge responsible subjects to complete the RPS target. In view of this, while improving RPS policy, the government should continuously improve the TGC market framework from the dimensions of access and exit mechanisms, clearing methods, settlement mechanisms and regulatory mechanisms. These measures can fully restore the commodity attributes of TGCs through cooperation of the “visible hand” and the “invisible hand” and provide support for the implementation of RPSs and the orderly development of the renewable-energy industry.
- (2)
- Build a multilevel coordinated TGC market mechanism. As pointed out in the simulations and conclusions, responsible subjects’ trading decisions can be influenced by various factors, such as preference for short-term interests, renewable-energy uncertainty and renewable-energy installation capacity. Considering the differences in renewable-resource endowment, energy structure and other factors between different regions in China, the government should build a TGC market with coordinated operation within and between the provinces. Among them, the intraprovincial market would mainly provide support for the optimal allocation of resources and operating-cost recovery for renewable-energy manufacturers in the province; the interprovincial market would aim to meet the needs of large-scale optimal allocation of resources and promote sustainable development of renewable energy.
Author Contributions
Funding
Data Availability Statement
Conflicts of Interest
Nomenclature
Symbol | Description |
, | Discount rate of buyer and seller |
RPS target that has been completed by time step t | |
TGC price at time step t | |
Renewable-power price at time step t | |
Price of electricity in the balanced market at time step t | |
, | Utility coefficient at time step t |
, | Actual available renewable-energy output at time step t |
, | Error in predicting output of renewable energy at time step t |
Power demand at time step t | |
TGCs available for transactions at time step t, that is, accumulation of unsold TGCs | |
TGCs purchased at time step t | |
Weight of the nth normal distribution | |
Variance of the nth normal distribution | |
Cost of purchasing renewable power at time step t | |
Cost of purchasing TGCs at time step t | |
Total RPS target | |
Highest price of TGCs at time step t | |
, | Acceptable TGC price for buyers and sellers at time step t |
Thermal-power price at time step t | |
Penalty value | |
Uncompleted RPS target at time step t | |
, | Predicted renewable-energy output at time step t |
, | Upper bound and lower bound of confidence interval for renewable energy at time step t |
, | Minimum and maximum output of thermal power at time step t |
Renewable power purchased at time step t | |
Thermal power purchased at time step t | |
Mean of the nth normal distribution | |
Value of RPS weight | |
Cost of purchasing thermal power at time step t | |
Penalty cost |
References
- National Energy Administration. Reply to Proposals No. 0429 and No. B097 of the Fourth Session of the Thirteenth National Committee of the Chinese People’s Political Consultative Conference. Available online: http://zfxxgk.nea.gov.cn/2022-02/24/c_1310486036.htm/ (accessed on 25 March 2022).
- National Energy Administration. Interim Measures for the Administration of Collection and Use of Renewable Energy Development Funds. Available online: http://www.nea.gov.cn/2011-12/20/c_131316289.htm/ (accessed on 21 May 2021).
- National Energy Administration. Notice on the Full Guaranteed Acquisition of Wind Power and Photovoltaic Power Generation. Available online: http://www.nea.gov.cn/2016-06/01/c_135404529.htm/ (accessed on 20 May 2021).
- National Energy Administration. Notice on Trial Implementation of Renewable Energy Green Power Certificate Issuance and Voluntary Subscription Trading System. Available online: https://www.ndrc.gov.cn/xxgk/zcfb/tz/201702/t20170203_962895.html/ (accessed on 15 October 2021).
- National Energy Administration. Renewable Energy Power Quota and Assessment Methods (Draft for Comments). Available online: http://zfxxgk.nea.gov.cn/auto87/201803/t20180323_3131.htm/ (accessed on 15 October 2021).
- National Development and Reform Commission. Notice on Establishing and Improving the Renewable Energy Power Consumption Guarantee Mechanism. Available online: https://www.ndrc.gov.cn/xxgk/zcfb/tz/201905/t20190515_962446.html/ (accessed on 15 May 2021).
- State Grid Energy Research Institute Co., Ltd. China New Energy Power Generation Analysis Report; China Electric Power Press: Beijing, China, 2021; pp. 19–26. [Google Scholar]
- State Grid Energy Research Institute Co., Ltd. China Power Development Analysis Report; China Electric Power Press: Beijing, China, 2021; pp. 24–34. [Google Scholar]
- Marchenko, O.V. Modeling of a Green Certificate Market. Renew. Energy 2008, 33, 1953–1958. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Qu, M.; Ding, T.; Bai, J.; He, Y.; Liu, R.; Chen, T. Green Certificate Transaction Analysis in China Under Responsibility for Non-hydro Renewable Energy Integration Ratio. Power Syst. Technol. 2019, 44, 3885–3894. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fan, J.; Wang, J.; Hu, J.; Wang, Y.; Zhang, X. Optimization of China’s provincial renewable energy installation plan for the 13th five-year plan based on renewable portfolio standards. Appl. Energy 2019, 254, 606–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhou, Y.; Zhao, X.; Wang, Z. Demand side incentive under renewable portfolio standards: A system dynamics analysis. Energy Policy 2020, 144, 111652. [Google Scholar]
- Song, X.; Han, J.; Zhang, L.; Zhao, C.; Wang, P.; Liu, X.; Li, Q. Impacts of renewable portfolio standards on multi-market coupling trading of renewable energy in China: A scenario-based system dynamics model. Energy Policy 2021, 159, 112647. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, J.; Zhou, X. Impact Analysis of Market-Driented Carbon Emission Reduction Policies in Power Generation Industry Based on System Dynamics. Electr. Power 2020, 53, 114–123. [Google Scholar]
- Zhao, X.; Ren, L.; Wan, G. Renewable Portfolio Standards, the Strategic of Power Producers and Evolution. China J. Manag. Sci. 2019, 27, 168–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liang, J.; Zuo, Y.; Zhang, Y.; Zhao, X. Energy-saving and Economic Dispatch of Power System Containing Wind Power Integration Under Renewable Portfolio Standard. Power Syst. Technol. 2019, 43, 2528–2534. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yuan, G.; Liu, P.; Jia, X.; Dong, J.; Fang, F. Economic Optimal Scheduling Considering Tradable Green Certificate System. Acta Energ. Sol. Sin. 2021, 42, 139–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, Y.; Han, C.; Xiao, Y.; Li, J.; Wang, B.; Li, Y. Tradable Green Certificate Market Transaction Based on Economic Scheduling Timing Simulation of Renewable Energy. Smart Power 2021, 49, 58–65. [Google Scholar]
- Zhu, C.; Fan, R.; Lin, J. The impact of renewable portfolio standard on retail electricity market: A system dynamics model of tripartite evolutionary game. Energy Policy 2020, 136, 111072. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lv, Y.; Yang, P.; Chen, J.; Chen, Y.; Zeng, K. Optimized Configuration of DC Microgrid Under Diversified Green Trading System. Power Syst. Technol. 2021, 45, 997–1005. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, H.; Chen, B.; Zhao, H.; Liao, K.; Bao, X. Optimal Decision-making of Trans-provincial Power Transaction Subjects Under Renewable Portfolio Standard. Power Syst. Technol. 2019, 43, 1987–1995. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, L.; Zhang, T.; Li, X.; Wu, M.; Wang, B. System Dynamics Simulation of Renewable Energy Power Trading Based on Renewable Portfolio Standard. J. Glob. Energy Interconnect. 2020, 3, 497–507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Benth, F.E.; Eriksson, M.K.V.; Westgaard, S. Optimal management of green certificates in the Swedish-Norwegian market. Soc. Sci. Electron. Publ. 2017, 10, 1–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tu, Q.; Mo, J.; Betz, R.; Cui, L.; Fan, Y.; Liu, Y. Achieving grid parity of solar PV power in China- The role of Tradable Green Certificate. Energy Policy 2020, 144, 111681. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, H.; Zhang, Q.; Shi, J.; Ye, X.; Zhang, X. Research on the Trading Pricing Strategy of Chinese Tradable Green Certificate. Price Theory Pract. 2019, 9, 42–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, Y.; Sun, Y.; Chen, W. Construction of space of information flows and assessment of network resilience from reflexive perspective: A case study of Baidu index in Yangtze River Delta. J. Univ. Chin. Acad. Sci. 2021, 38, 62–72. [Google Scholar]
- Chen, J.; Chen, W. The Reflexivity of Informatics—In Comparison with Natural Sciences. Inf. Sci. 2007, 1613–1616. [Google Scholar]
- Li, H. Is the Natural Character Simple? Stud. Dialectics Nat. 2003, 28–33. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Keerthisinghe, C.; Chapman, A.C.; Verbic, G. PV and Demand Models for a Markov Decision Process Formulation of the Home Energy Management Problem. IEEE Trans. Ind. Electron. 2019, 66, 1424–1433. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Keerthisinghe, C.; Verbic, G.; Chapman, A.C. A Fast Technique for Smart Home Management: ADP With Temporal Difference Learning. IEEE Trans. Smart Grid 2018, 9, 3291–3303. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Coulon, M.; Khazaei, J.; Warren, B.P. SMART-SREC: A stochastic model of the New Jersey solar renewable energy certificate market. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2015, 73, 13–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yi, Y.; Tong, X. Dynamic Economic Dispatch Considering Uncertainties of Wind Power and Load Forecast Error. Power Syst. Technol. 2019, 43, 4050–4057. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, S.; Wang, Y.; Xu, Y. Dependent Chance Programming Dispatching of Integrated Thermal Power Generation and Energy Storage System Based on Wind Power Forecasting Error. Proc. CSEE 2014, 34, 9–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, L.; Zhang, Y.; Xu, Q. An Interval Optimal Scheduling Method Considering the Influence of Power Uncertainty and the Flexibility of Distribution Network. Power Syst. Technol. 2020, 44, 4654–4664. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, J.; Yan, Z.; Li, M.; Yun, J.; Wang, H.; Xu, X.; Wang, H. Optimization Method of Interprovincial Trading Plan for Surplus Renewable Energy Power Based on CVaR and Output Prediction. High Volt. Eng. 2022, 48, 467–479. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- National Development and Reform Commission. Notice on the 2021 Renewable Energy Power Consumption Responsibility Weight and Related Matters. Available online: http://www.gov.cn/zhengce/zhengceku/2021-05/26/content_5612441.htm (accessed on 26 May 2021).
- National Development and Reform Commission. Opinions on Improving the Institutional Mechanism and Policy Measures for Energy Green and Low-Carbon Transformation. Available online: https://www.ndrc.gov.cn/xxgk/zcfb/tz/202202/t20220210_1314511.html/ (accessed on 18 May 2021).
- Tu, Q.; Betz, R.; Mo, J.; Fan, Y. The profitability of onshore wind and solar PV power projects in China-A comparative study. Energy Policy 2019, 132, 404–417. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Time | Policy Name | Relevant Content |
---|---|---|
November 2011 | Interim Measures for the Administration of Collection and Use of Renewable Energy Development Funds | Promotes renewable-energy development and reduces the price difference between renewable power and thermal power through national financial subsidies. |
May 2016 | Notice on Full Guaranteed Acquisition of Wind Power and Photovoltaic Power Generation | States that grid companies shall purchase wind and photovoltaic power in full, and subsidies should be paid to renewable-energy manufacturers. |
February 2017 | Notice on Trial Implementation of Green Certificates and Voluntary Subscription System | States that TGCs can be issued for each megawatt–hour of renewable on-grid power. TGCs can be sold for profit. |
March 2018 | Renewable Power Quota and Assessment Method | States that RPSs will be implemented in China and TGCs can be used to complete the RPS target. |
May 2019 | Notice on Establishing and Improving the Renewable Power Consumption Guarantee Mechanism | States that the demand side is the responsible subjects of the RPSs, and the RPS target is calculated by multiplying the annual power consumption and a government-specified weight. |
Scenario | RPS Weight | TGC Price Cap | Penalty |
---|---|---|---|
S0 | 13% | 350 | 350 |
S1 | 5% | 350 | 350 |
S2 | 7% | 350 | 350 |
S3 | 9% | 350 | 350 |
S4 | 19% | 350 | 350 |
Scenario | RPS Weight | TGC Price Cap | Penalty |
---|---|---|---|
S5 | 7% | 300 | 350 |
S2 | 7% | 350 | 350 |
S6 | 7% | 400 | 350 |
S7 | 7% | 800 | 350 |
S8 | 13% | 300 | 350 |
S0 | 13% | 350 | 350 |
S9 | 13% | 400 | 350 |
S10 | 13% | 800 | 350 |
Scenario | RPS Weight | TGC Price Cap | Penalty |
---|---|---|---|
S11 | 13% | 350 | 250 |
S0 | 13% | 350 | 350 |
S12 | 13% | 350 | 450 |
S13 | 19% | 350 | 250 |
S4 | 19% | 350 | 350 |
S14 | 19% | 350 | 450 |
Scenario | RPS Weight | TGC Price Cap | Penalty | Discount Factor |
---|---|---|---|---|
S2 | 7% | 350 | 350 | 1 |
S15 | 7% | 350 | 350 | 0.7 |
S0 | 13% | 350 | 350 | 1 |
S16 | 13% | 350 | 350 | 0.7 |
S4 | 19% | 350 | 350 | 1 |
S17 | 19% | 350 | 350 | 0.7 |
Scenario | RPS Weight | TGC Price Cap | Penalty | Discount Factor |
---|---|---|---|---|
S8 | 13% | 300 | 350 | 1 |
S18 | 13% | 300 | 350 | 0.7 |
S0 | 13% | 350 | 350 | 1 |
S16 | 13% | 350 | 350 | 0.7 |
S9 | 13% | 400 | 350 | 1 |
S19 | 13% | 400 | 350 | 0.7 |
Scenario | RPS Weight | TGC Price Cap | Penalty | Discount Factor |
---|---|---|---|---|
S0 | 13% | 350 | 350 | 1 |
S16 | 13% | 350 | 350 | 0.7 |
S20 | 13% | 350 | 400 | 1 |
S21 | 13% | 350 | 400 | 0.7 |
S12 | 13% | 350 | 450 | 1 |
S22 | 13% | 350 | 450 | 0.7 |
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content. |
© 2023 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Xu, Y.; Ma, J.; Wang, Y.; Zeng, M. Assessing the Effects of Tradable Green Certificates and Renewable Portfolio Standards through Demand-Side Decision-Making Simulation: A Case of a System Containing Photovoltaic Power. Energies 2023, 16, 3517. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16083517
Xu Y, Ma J, Wang Y, Zeng M. Assessing the Effects of Tradable Green Certificates and Renewable Portfolio Standards through Demand-Side Decision-Making Simulation: A Case of a System Containing Photovoltaic Power. Energies. 2023; 16(8):3517. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16083517
Chicago/Turabian StyleXu, Yanbin, Jiaxin Ma, Yuqing Wang, and Ming Zeng. 2023. "Assessing the Effects of Tradable Green Certificates and Renewable Portfolio Standards through Demand-Side Decision-Making Simulation: A Case of a System Containing Photovoltaic Power" Energies 16, no. 8: 3517. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16083517
APA StyleXu, Y., Ma, J., Wang, Y., & Zeng, M. (2023). Assessing the Effects of Tradable Green Certificates and Renewable Portfolio Standards through Demand-Side Decision-Making Simulation: A Case of a System Containing Photovoltaic Power. Energies, 16(8), 3517. https://doi.org/10.3390/en16083517