Next Article in Journal
An Equivalent Model for Frequency Dynamic Analysis of Large Power Grids Based on Regulation Performance Weighting Method
Previous Article in Journal
Optimization Dispatch of Distribution Network–Prosumer Group–Prosumer Considering Flexible Reserve Resources of Prosumer
Previous Article in Special Issue
The Significance of Economic Complexity and Renewable Energy for Decarbonization in Eastern European Countries
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Do Environmental Tax and Energy Matter for Environmental Degradation in the UK? Evidence from Novel Fourier-Based Estimators

by
Kwaku Addai
1,
Souha Hanna Al Geitany
2,
Seyed Alireza Athari
2,3,*,
Panteha Farmanesh
4,
Dervis Kirikkaleli
1,5 and
Chafic Saliba
2
1
Faculty of Economics and Administrative Sciences, European University of Lefke, 99010 Lefke, Northern Cyprus, Turkey
2
Department of Business, Holy Spirit University of Kaslik, Kaslik, Jounieh P.O. Box 446, Lebanon
3
Advanced Research Centre, European University of Lefke, 99010 Lefke, Northern Cyprus, Turkey
4
Faculty of Communication, Arkin University of Creative Arts & Design, 99300 Kyrenia, Northern Cyprus, Turkey
5
Department of Economics, Adnan Kassar School of Business, Lebanese American University, Beirut 03797751, Lebanon
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Energies 2024, 17(22), 5732; https://doi.org/10.3390/en17225732
Submission received: 12 October 2024 / Revised: 29 October 2024 / Accepted: 4 November 2024 / Published: 15 November 2024
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Energy Economics, Finance and Policy Towards Sustainable Energy)

Abstract

:
Currently, the UK has ambitious plans to reach net zero by 2050, despite other countries such as Russia and India targeting 2060 and 2070, respectively. Assuming that the UK emissions unceasingly decline at a given rate annually towards achieving net zero by 2050, its economy would need to ensure a reduction of 105 MtCO2 per year of its emissions from the current 2021 levels. Given that global greenhouse gas emissions have not peaked and continue to rise, the UK seeks to implement costly and aggressive emission reduction policies towards fulfilling commitments under the 2021 Glasgow Climate Pact. This paper investigates the effect of environmental taxes on environmental degradation in the UK between 2000Q1 and 2019Q4 using novel Fourier approaches. Using the novel Fourier ARDL estimator, the long-run equilibrium estimates indicate that gross domestic product and environmental tax cause a fall in carbon emissions. However, in trade and primary energy use, a unit change caused rising carbon emissions in the UK. Especially, the results indicate that environmental taxes have a negative effect on environmental degradation in the UK, and ecological tax policy could be considered as an effective channel to attain environmental sustainability. The outcome provides the following policy insights: (i) The government of the UK should support international environmental tax coordination mechanisms, especially on carbon pricing, to avoid relocation of carbon-intensive investments. (ii) The UK government must note that imposing more taxes to encourage emissions reductions could bring complexity to the tax system and unnecessarily bring costly ways to deal with climate change. Higher domestic electricity prices could disproportionately hit low-income households and create distributional cost concerns, which require benefit payouts or compensation schemes. (iii) Switching to electric vehicles simultaneously requires investments in charging infrastructure and battery technologies. To avoid this chicken-and-egg problem, the government of the UK could play a coordinating role, including deploying targeted subsidies, regulations, direct government involvement, or setting higher carbon prices in special cases.

1. Introduction

Historically, the relationship between the growing economic activity of nations and environmental degradation has been an undisputed fact relative to production structure [1]. Theoretically, this relationship is rooted in the environmental Kuznets curve, particularly when linked to fossil fuel use [2,3]. Ecological degradation is generally explained to refer to damage to the quality and quantity of naturally endowed resources to humanity, such as air, forest, water, and land. Economists (under the Pigouvian Framework, [4]) claim this environmental damage arises once the marginal social cost of consuming environmental resources surpasses the marginal social benefits [5]. In recent times, environmental economists have recognized that environmental damage relates directly to rising global warming, a critical existential global crisis largely found to be caused by energy-related greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions [6,7]. These greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions are observed through vehicles and factories’ emissions of poisonous gasses into the air, waste generation, deforestation for agriculture, and chemical use for fishing. The consequential effects include global warming and climate change, poor agricultural output, various weather conditions, flooding, and poor human health [7].
Globally, the United Nations has, in contemporary decades, led the campaign for the reduction in carbon emissions that cause global warming. To achieve this goal, the United Nations urges the global economy to urgently take policy actions that promote low-carbon economies. Although existing global environmental initiatives, such as the Kyoto Protocol, the Paris Agreement, and the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, have made significant gains, some environmentalists and scientists have observed that global initiatives cannot sufficiently deliver global climate change mitigation and emissions reduction goals due to disagreements on important policy issues. Accordingly, the United Nations urges economies to implement sustainable policy actions through administrative orders, economic incentives, and environmental taxes. While several experts claim that administrative orders and environmental regulations tend to be rigid and ineffective, economic incentive policies are relatively useful only in some economic cycles [8].
Recently, several scholarly studies have cited and proposed environmental taxes as having the best potential to reduce environmental degradation and mitigate the effects of global warming, notwithstanding the role of renewables and financial innovation [9,10,11,12]. Theoretically, environmental pollution occurs due to corporations’ or individuals’ failure to account for environmental harm created by others through their decision making [4]. Environmental taxes are generally hinged on principles of precaution, polluters pay, risk prevention, public participation, and integration of decision making. Experts claim environmental tax gains are needed for revenue-recycling benefits and energy gains [9,10]. Figure 1 is an illustration of Pigourian environmental theory and social effects [4]. If emissions tax revenues are not used to increase economic efficiency through cutting distortionary taxes (or through funding socially desirable spending), the net benefits from emissions taxes are greatly reduced (e.g., [9,13,14]). The case for using environmental taxes on cost-effectiveness grounded on regulatory approaches (e.g., emissions standards) can be substantially undermined (e.g., [14]). Environmental taxes tend to have a bigger impact on energy prices than regulatory policies (because the former involves the pass-through of tax revenue into prices), and the revenue-recycling benefit is needed to offset the effect of these greater energy price increases on exacerbating factor tax distortions. Although several economists traditionally argue that environmental regulations increase corporate costs and affect the competitiveness of the local industry if policy variations exist across countries [9,14], however, many others claim that environmental regulations could foster innovations in environmental technologies and leadership towards increased economic growth [4,13].
The question that continues rumbling in the ears of environmental economists is whether environmental taxes can truly reduce environmental degradation. To answer this continuously echoing academic question on the role of an environmental tax on carbon emissions, the economy of the United Kingdom of Great Britain (UK) presents an inspiring case for investigation. After leaving the EU, the UK passed the Environment Act in 2021 to empower the government with powers to establish new environmentally friendly binding targets on air quality, water, biodiversity, and waste reduction. The new Environment Act also established the Office for Environmental Protection (OEP), replacing existing EU environmental oversight functions and other regulations that were expiring at the end of 2023. Additionally, the country has an ambitious climate policy of net zero by 2050. Historically, the UK’s attempt to develop environmental policies has conflicted with competing interests and perspectives of different groups in society, especially industry and local communities. Throughout history, the UK has been a signatory of several global agreements on the environment, e.g., the Convention for the Preservation and Protection of Fur Seals with the United States, Japan, and Russia (1911); the Convention for the Protection of Migratory Birds (1916) with the United States which was later extended to Mexico; and Convention on Preservation of Fauna and Flora (also referred to as London Convention of 1933).
According to [15], public advocacy on environmental taxation in the UK originated from the Minority Report of the Royal Commission on Environmental Pollution in 1972. This report set the British political and environmental agenda in 1989 when environmental taxes were presented through a meeting for a revenue-neutral carbon regulatory action. Environmental taxation in the UK was eventually influenced by the introduction of carbon taxes in Nordic countries during the 1990s but received a blow with the introduction of VAT on domestic energy in 1993. In 2001, the UK implemented the Climate Change Levy—a downstream tax on corporate energy use to promote energy efficiency and renewable energy development. In general, the UK’s environmental taxes have covered energy, transport, pollution, and commercial exploitation of natural resources. Available data from the UK’s Office of National Statistics (May 2023) indicate that, by using the internationally agreed framework, the UK’s environmental tax revenue increased by 6.9% from GBP 44.3 billion in 2021 to GBP 47.4 billion in 2022 for energy (74.7%), transport (22.3%), and pollution and resource use (3.0%). This represented 1.9% of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2022, the lowest record since 1997. To disincentivize emissions from waste disposal, the UK government imposed landfill taxes, with consistent rate increases since its introduction. Between 2004 and 2021, the landfill taxes increased from GBP 15 to GBP 96.70 per ton. Figure 2 presents the tax types in the UK.
These notwithstanding, the UK has been urged by experts to do more to reduce carbon emissions as it lags behind several European economies [17]. Given that very limited studies have been conducted on environmental taxes on carbon emissions, this paper fills the gap and brings clarity to relevant arguments on environmental taxes using novel Fourier autoregressive distributive lag econometric approaches. The study is motivated by the Pigourian tax [4] and the cap-and-trade theoretical system of environmental tax by [18].
The paper progresses as follows: The next section reviews the relevant literature for conceptual frames and to construct the assumptions for the empirical study. This is followed by separate sections for methodology and empirical outcomes. The last section deals with conclusions and policy recommendations.

2. Brief Literature Review: The Environmental Tax–CO2 Emissions Nexus

Several studies have explored the determinants of CO2. For example, [19] uncovered that economic growth intensified CO2 emissions, though green energy, remittances, and globalization decreased CO2 emissions. [20] revealed that gross domestic product (GDP), urbanization, and globalization increased CO2 emissions in China, while hydroelectricity consumption lessened CO2 emissions. Recently, some studies have also discussed environmental sustainability by probing the determinants of renewable energy (e.g., [21,22,23]) and exploring the importance of firm and sovereign environmental, social, and governance sustainability activities [24,25].
Particularly, the relationship between environmental taxation and environmental degradation has been a matter of intense debate among researchers, policymakers, and economists over the past decades. This section systematically reviews relevant studies for insights into crafting a conceptual framework and positioning the study for empirical analysis.
Environmental taxes are an efficient policy instrument to decrease carbon emissions. [26] found that environmental taxes generally seek to decrease carbon emissions by influencing a fall in fossil fuel demand. They are ultimately implemented to achieve global environmental delivery targets of the Kyoto Protocol and the Paris Climate Agreement. Historically, environmental taxes (e.g., carbon taxes) have been implemented by several economies and sub-national governments. Globally, two waves of enactments of environmental taxes have occurred, beginning from the early 1990s (Denmark, Finland, Norway, and Sweden), and in the 2000s, countries such as Switzerland, Iceland, Ireland, Japan, Mexico, and Portugal enacted such laws.
Theoretically, the basis of environmental taxes is severely documented as improving social welfare if the consumption or production of particular goods results in a negative externality [12,27]. Environmental degradation has been generally classified as problematic due to the failure of corporations or individuals to damage control in their decision making to fully price resources for production or consumption. Given the divergence between private and social costs of pollution, [4] claimed that taxing pollution equates to social marginal damage and private costs while ensuring efficient market outcomes. Critics, however, argue that no consensus globally exists on the optimal effectiveness of energy and carbon taxes, subsidies, and transfers. They claim that environmental taxes may tend to be regressive against poorer households that could be compelled to purchase cheaper and less energy-efficient appliances [28].
Similarly, environmental taxes are distortionary, given the narrow tax base, and create double taxation on both intermediate input and final output [29,30]. As an alternate theory, others have recommended a cap-and-trade system, given that the carbon tax places costs on CO2 pollution and permits markets to determine pollution. A cap-and-trade system rather caps pollution, allowing markets to have the right to pollute. In this case, politicians do not directly set prices [18]. However, [18] argues about three factors favoring carbon taxes over cap-and-trade systems. First, he argues that a cap-and-trade system allows price variations with changing market conditions, leading to price volatility and uncertainty, since corporations cannot plan for long-lived, capital-intensive projects. Second, the cap-and-trade system is administratively complex, requiring new administrative structures for tracking, holding auctions, and developing rules to avoid fraud and abuse. Finally, the cap-and-trade system has the potential for adverse policy interactions, which could be counterproductive [31].
Empirically, several studies investigating the effect of environmental taxes on pollution control have found it to be positive [32,33,34]. Ref. [35] found that environmental taxes significantly reduce carbon emissions. Furthermore, the outcomes of the investigation indicated that environmental taxes are instrumental in facilitating the development of renewable energy technologies and could help reduce energy demands. [36] investigated EU policies on carbon emissions mitigation and found environmental taxes to be a very effective approach to carbon emission reduction across member economies. A similar investigation by [37] on the effects of international competitiveness of environmental taxes in European countries indicated that environmental taxes are very effective in promoting the welfare of economies and market competitiveness. Another study by [38] examined the effects of carbon taxes on economic growth and energy intensity in China. The results indicated increases in carbon tax have negative effects on energy intensity and carbon emissions. However, some experts in their investigations found environmental taxes to have very little effect on reducing carbon emissions [39,40]. For example, [41] claimed environmental taxes could only protect environmental quality if investments in energy and environmental technologies could be prioritized. Using data from 1995 to 2005 on 25 European economies, [42] investigated the long-run effects of environmental taxes on energy use. The outcomes indicated that environmental taxes have little effect on energy consumption in the studied countries.
Based on the above review, the effects of environmental taxes on pollution vary, and the findings are inconclusive. Accordingly, the study seeks to bring clarity to the arguments on the effects of an environmental tax on pollution using the UK as a case study. To achieve the stated objectives, the paper gives the following hypothesis:
Hypothesis 1 (H1). 
Environmental taxes have negative effects on environmental degradation in the UK.

3. Methodology

3.1. Data

This paper aims to capture the effect of an environmental tax on environmental degradation in the UK between 2000Q1 and 2019Q4. To achieve the established objectives of the paper, economic growth, primary energy consumption, and trade in the UK are controlled. All variables are in the log form to avoid scaling [43]. Data were sourced on (i) carbon dioxide emissions (as a proxy variable for environmental degradation) from UNFCC. Carbon dioxide emissions are determined in kt (kiloton). Carbon dioxide (CO2) is a gas produced from the burning of carbon and the respiration of living organisms and is measured in parts-per-million (ppm) [44]. (ii) Data on environmental tax were sourced from OECD. (iii) Data were sourced from gross domestic product (GDP) as a proxy variable for economic growth. (iv) Data were sourced on primary energy consumption from OECD. Primary energy measures a country’s total energy demand. (v) Data on trade were sourced from the IMF. Trade involves voluntary exchanges of goods or services between economic actors. Trade is measured by the difference between a country’s exports and imports of goods. Figure 3 presents the analysis flowchart.

3.2. Control Variables

Towards achieving the objectives of the study, economic growth, trade, and primary energy consumption are controlled to assess the pollution effect of environmental tax in the case of the UK. First, for several decades, the UK’s energy market has been largely driven by coal, fossil energy, nuclear, and renewables. With increasing renewable use, fossil energy has halved, while coal generation in the UK is expected to be phased out by 2024. Gas supply has largely been supplied locally (54% in 2022), while the remaining was imported from Norway, Netherlands, Qatar, Algeria, Belgium, and, to some extent, Russia before the ban in 2023 due to the Ukraine invasion [45]. Electricity generation from nuclear sources stood at 15% in 2022. In general, according to ESO’s analysis, the energy mix for the UK from 2022 is made up of gas—38.5%; wind—26.8%; nuclear—15.5%; biomass—5.2%; coal—1.5%; solar—4.4%; imports—5.5%; hydro—1.8%; and energy storage—0.9%.
Hypothesis 2 (H2). 
Based on these, an assumption is made for this paper that primary energy use in the UK positively moderates CO2 emissions (H2), i.e.,ϑ2 = ϑ L C O 2 E L P E C i t ˃ 0; where ϑ represents the interest parameter; LPEC signifies the natural log of primary energy use; LCO2E is the natural log of CO2 emissions (as a proxy for environmental degradation).
For economic growth, the UK has, for several years, committed to the cause of climate change with several policies. After the 2008 climate action, which helped the economy sustain reductions in GHG emissions, the UK 2019 enacted an ambitious new law to further commit itself to reaching net zero greenhouse gas emissions by 2050. Accordingly, in 2021, the UK government adopted the sixth carbon budget to drastically cut emissions by 78% by the close of 2035. Being the pioneer of the Climate Act, the economy’s climate actions have set the pace and as a model for climate legislation in several countries, including Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, Mexico, New Zealand, and Sweden. Notwithstanding the 2007 peaking of emissions in the UK, due to a combination of environmental policies and a transition to less carbon-intensive service-based industries, the UK has witnessed imported emissions mainly from China and the neighboring EU countries. Critics have argued that the increasing proportion of the UK’s economy to the higher-value services sector raises emissions through international trade flows and exaggerates apparent declining records in territory-based emissions. According to this view, there is the need for rethinking the EKC theory [46] on growth and carbon emissions.
Hypothesis 3 (H3). 
Based on these, this study hypothesizes that rising economic growth in the UK significantly causes CO2 emissions to be reduced, i.e., (H3) =ϑ3= ϑ L C O 2   E ϑ L G D P i t   <  0; where ϑ is linked to the interest parameter; LGDP is the natural log of gross domestic product (GDP) (a proxy variable for the UK’s economic growth); LCO2E is the natural log of the UK’s carbon dioxide emissions.
Another factor considered as a determinant of carbon emissions in the UK is trade. In 2020, carbon dioxide emissions represented approximately 79% of the UK’s total GHG emissions. However, records from the [47] indicate that the United Kingdom witnessed rising consumption-based emissions, suggesting that historically falling rates in total emissions were offset by rising consumption-based emissions. UK’s exports of goods and services in 2022 amounted to GBP 834 billion. The country also imported a total of GBP 902 billion in goods and services, with the EU alone accounting for 47% of the total in 2022. Theoretically, the environmental effects of output in trade lends are explained by the pollution haven hypothesis—a framework that claims to reallocate dirty industries by corporations to economies with less strict environmental regulations [47]. Despite the negative effects of trade, several scholars argue that trade could provide knowledge and technology transfer, which helps to eventually improve environmental performance [48,49].
Hypothesis 4 (H4). 
Based on the arguments, the authors of this paper hypothesize that the trade increases environmental degradation in the UK, i.e., (H4) =ϑ4= ϑ L C O 2 E ϑ L T R A i t   >  0; where ϑ is the interest parameter; LTRA is a log of trade; and LCO2E is a log of carbon dioxide emissions in the UK.

3.3. Model

Theoretically, productive and efficient energy use can promote environmental quality [50]. With growing global concerns about energy use for growth, environmental degradation, and global warming, new policy pathways are required for successful energy transformation. One major policy pathway for dealing with increasing environmental degradation is environmental tax [11]. Despite major critiques, [4] claimed that, with the divergence between private and social costs of pollution, taxing pollution equates social marginal damage and private costs, while ensuring efficient market outcomes. To estimate the nexus between environmental degradation, environmental tax, economic growth, trade, and primary energy consumption, the study employs the Stokey framework, which can establish how environmental pollution and abatement affect the regulation [51]. Similarly, the study is motivated by a balanced growth model, the role of abatement and technological progress towards improving growth and environmental quality over time, although the growth rate of output could equally be lowered, given the strength of scale, composition, and technique effects as espoused by the EKC hypothesis [52]. The Stokey framework highlights how rapidly increasing population and economic growth could eliminate any possibility of sustainable growth. It also highlights how convergence is demonstrated across countries involved in trade and pollution abatement, justifying how environmental taxes can level variations across countries and facilitate induced innovation in energy use, growth, pollution abatement, and general technological progress. Accordingly, the empirical model for this study is as follows:
CO 2 E = f ( G D P ,   P E C ,   T R A ,   E T A X )
where CO2E is carbon dioxide emissions (as a proxy for environmental degradation in the UK); GDP is gross domestic product (as a proxy for economic output); PEC is primary energy use; TRA is trade; and ETAX is environmental tax.
Next, by logging variables, the model is specified as follows:
LCO 2 E = f ( L G D P + L P E + L T R A + L E T A X + e t )
where LCO2E is a log of carbon dioxide emissions (as a proxy for environmental degradation in the UK); GDP is GDP output; and LPEC is primary energy use; LTRA is a log of trade; LETAX is a log of environmental tax; and et is the error term.

3.4. ADF Unit Root Test with Breakpoint

Next, after descriptive statistical assessments, the paper checks the integration order of variables using Augmented Dickey–Fuller (ADF) unit root tests with breakpoints. In the field of econometrics, when variables are integrated to varying degrees, it makes models not testable for cointegration using the conventional cointegration methods. This paper adopts the novel ADF unit root tests with breakpoints, which provide better and more reliable information for cointegration assessment despite integration order. To estimate the unit roots for ADF with breaks, the model used is as follows:
x t = μ + ρ x t 1 + e t
here xt refers to variables of interest; μ is the constant term; and et is the error term. By unit differencing, the model becomes Δxt = μ + et; where Δ = (1 − B); ρ refers to parameter slopes for lagged variables and becomes 1 whenever there occurs a unit root. The study illustrates the alternative unit root for ADF with breaks in Equations (4) as follows:
x t = μ + β t δ D U t + θ D T B + e t
The re-specifications of error correction form; and after applying the augmentation factor, ADF with breaks equation is estimated as follows:
Δ x t = μ + β t + γ 1 sin 2 π k t N + γ 2 cos 2 π k t N + ( ρ 1 ) x 1 1 + i 1 p C i Δ x i 1 + ε
here c refers to the slope parameter of the augmented parts; p is the lag length with minimum information criteria values in the augmentation process; k is Fourier regularity; structural break date is TB; and break fraction refers to λ.

3.5. Fourier ARDL Cointegration Analysis

The traditional ARDL cointegration approach has historically been employed extensively by researchers for decades [53]. The limitation of this estimator is that it is unable to detect hidden long-term nonlinear relationships among variables. Accordingly, in this paper, the Fourier ARDL estimator is employed to estimate long-run equilibrium relations among interest variables. The estimators can detect the existence of unknown structural breaks, time, and structures related to the variables. In essence, the Fourier-based ARDL long-run estimator can provide more robust outcomes than the traditional ARDL approach [54,55]. The Fourier function is modeled in Equation (6).
d t = k = 1 n a k sin 2 π k t T + k = 1 n b k cos 2 π k t T
where n indicates the number of frequencies, π = 3.14, k is the number of special frequencies selected, t is the trend, and T is the sample size. A single frequency value is suggested [56,57] as in Equation (7).
d t = γ 1 s i n 2 π k t T + γ 2 c o s 2 π k t T
The FARDL model for this study is shown in Equation (8).
L C O 2 E t = β 0 + γ 1 s i n 2 π k t T + γ 2 c o s 2 π k t T + β 1 L T R A t 1 + β 2 L G D P t 1 + β 3 L P E C t 1 + β 4 L E T A X t 1 + i 1 ρ 1 φ i L C O 2 E t i + i 1 ρ 1 δ i L T R A t i + i 1 ρ 1 i L G D P t i + i 1 ρ 1 ϑ i L P E C t i + i = 1 ρ 1 ϑ i L E T A X t i + e t
Several experts apply the frequency value to the minimum sum of squared residuals [55,58,59]. In addition, the study employs the Fourier TY Causality Test to support the outcomes of the Fourier ARDL test.

4. Empirical Outcomes

In this paper, the effect of an environmental tax on environmental degradation in the case of the UK is investigated using data from 2000Q1 to 2019Q4. To achieve this objective, economic progress, trade, and primary energy consumption are controlled positions. Table 1 is a statistical description of the variables examined.
Based on the outcomes of the descriptive analysis (Table 1), it is apparent that there are no outliers in the dataset. Similarly, the results suggest all variables are distributed normally. This suggests that further estimation action could proceed.
It is noteworthy to highlight that, historically, structural breaks have been overlooked in econometric studies, causing biases in unit root estimates. Before carrying out estimations to observe the integration order of interest variables, the paper conducted the Broock, Dechert, and Scheinkman (BDS) test [60] for any existence of stochastic hidden and nonlinear patterns (i.e., dependence or independence). The BDS test can also guide against any model misspecification and judgmental errors. The model for this econometric application is as follows (9):
BDS mT ( ɛ ) = T 1 / 2 [ C m , T ( ɛ ) C 1 , T ( ɛ ) m   ] / δ mT ( ɛ )
where T is the sample size, ɛ is the randomly adopted proximity parameter, and δ_mT^ (ɛ) is the standard deviation of the numerator which varies with dimension “m” [61].
Based on the BDS estimates (Table 2), hidden nonlinear patterns exist in the time series data since variables have significant dimensional critical values higher than their respective BDS estimates. These outcomes imply nonlinear correlations between the interest variables.
The outcomes of the ADF unit root test with breakpoint (Table 3) indicate the interest variables. LGDP is integrated at level (i.e., I(0) with a breakpoint at 2009Q1 at a 10% significance level). However, while LCO2E, LPEC, LTRA, and LRTAX are integrated at order ONE (i.e., I(1) with several breakpoints in 1996Q1, 2009Q1, 1996Q1, and 1997Q1, respectively, at a 5% significance level). The outcomes of the unit root analysis demonstrate that the time series variables integrate in a mixed order.
The next step involves investigating cointegration properties among the interest variables using the Fourier ARDL Cointegration estimator. This helps to ascertain how LETAX, LGDP, LPEC, and TRAL individually and collectively impact LCO2E in the case of the UK. Table 4 shows the Fourier ARDL cointegration analysis.
The Fourier ARDL Cointegration estimates (ARDL Bounds test) indicate the F-stats are significantly higher in value than the target critical values. This outcome suggests that both the dependent and independent variables possess long-term equilibrium relationships. This means the Fourier ARDL long-run cointegration test (Table 5) could be used since the estimator could detect any hidden information.
Based on the long-run Fourier ARDL estimates, LGDP has negative coefficients with a significant statistical value. The LGDP has a coefficient of −2.198802, signifying that unit change in LGDP causes a fall in LCO2E by −2.198802% in the UK. This outcome validates hypothesis 3 (H3) established for the study and supports [62]. Theoretically, increasing economic growth creates environmental degradation as a direct result of more demand for energy and material resources for production. According to the EKC framework, the initial phase of economic growth culminates in environmental destruction until a time when environmental regulatory and technological effects set in to correct the anomaly. This outcome suggests that the UK’s economy is currently beyond the EKC threshold, where rising GDP generates falling carbon due to increased technology application. This growth and environmental theory have been extensively validated by other growth frameworks such as the Source-and-Sink framework [63], Solow model [64], and Smulders and Stokey’s AK theoretical model [51].
Similarly, LETAX has a negative coefficient with a significant statistical value. From the estimates (Table 5), the coefficient of −0.395106 signifies that a unit change in LETAX causes a fall in LCO2E by −0.395106% in the UK. This estimate validates hypothesis 1 (H1) established in the paper. The result also confirms similar outcomes of the study by [65] for the case of Sweden. For policy insight, the UK government needs to use regulatory measures such as environmental tax to facilitate the delivery of globally agreed-upon nationally determined contributions. According to [66], while the government of the UK could continue imposing environmental taxes, such action must be coherent and fittingly adjusted within the tax system.
Further, the long-run Fourier ARDL estimates (Table 5) indicate that both LTRA have positive coefficients with a significant statistical value. The LTRA has a coefficient of 0.737557, signifying that unit change in LTRA causes a rise in LCO2E by 0.737557% in the UK. It must be noted that the result validates hypothesis 4 (H4) established for the study and aligns with [67]. It is instructive to note that, in 2020, carbon dioxide emissions amounted to an estimated 79% of the UK’s total GHG emissions. According to investigations by [68], the United Kingdom has witnessed increasing demand-based carbon emissions in recent years, suggesting that rising consumption-based emissions actually offset the historically falling rates in UK’s total emissions. Available data show, in 2022, that the UK’s exports of goods and services amounted to GBP 834 billion. While its imports totaled GBP 902 billion in goods and services. In theory, the environmental impact of trade lends support to the pollution haven hypothesis.
Furthermore, the coefficient of LPEC is positive and significant (Table 5). Based on Table 5, LPEC has a coefficient of 1.645885, signifying that unit change in LPEC causes an increase in LCO2E by 1.645885% in the UK. This finding validates hypothesis 2 (H2) established in the paper. The estimate suggests that Russia’s invasion of Ukraine, together with subsequent sanctions leading to rising energy costs, have led to the increasing use of coal in electricity production in the UK. Although the UK is committed to increasing the consumption of renewable energy, total primary energy consumption in 2019 was 141,951 ktoe (1651 TWh), largely from fossil fuels: petroleum products (44%) and natural gas (31%) (BEIS, 2020). It is not surprising that a unit change in primary energy use causes a whopping 1.645885% upward adjustment relative to carbon emissions in the UK for the period under study. It must, however, be noted that 2019 was equally a milestone when the UK heralded sourcing more energy from non-carbon resources than fossil fuels. It is no wonder why the economy has committed immensely to a net-zero emissions target by 2050. Between 1990 and 2019, the UK drastically reduced carbon emissions by 40%, making it the country with the largest carbon reductions among the OECD and G20 member countries.

Model Diagnostic Tests

Historically, scientists have considered model stability and residual diagnostic tests very essential in empirical research. Towards reducing LCO2E in the UK, the coefficient values in the error-correction model must be stable to enable policy decisions on them to be reliable relative to the behavior of economic output, primary energy use, trade, and environmental taxes. Accordingly, the paper captures model stability using the cumulative stability test (CUSUM and CUSUM of squares estimators) of [69]; the estimates of both CUSUM and CUSUM of squares indicate the statistical figures are within acceptable limits. Figure 4 shows the CUSUM and CUSUM of squares estimators.
Similarly, the paper checks if the model is free from heteroskedasticity and serial correlation issues using both the Breusch–Godfrey serial correlation LM test and residual diagnostic test, respectively. The results (Table 6) indicate the model is free from both heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. This means the outcomes of the Fourier ARDL long-run equilibrium model could be used to provide policy recommendations.
To further support the outcomes of the Fourier ARDL model, the Fourier Toda Yamamoto Causality Test was carried out. The estimates indicate that LGDP, LTRA, LETAX, and LPEC individually and unidirectionally cause LCO2E in the UK. Table 7 shows the Fourier TY Causality Test results. Overall, Figure 5 shows the Summary of empirical findings with methods.

5. Conclusions

In response to the Paris Agreement, the United Kingdom is a part of developed economies committed to reducing domestic greenhouse gas emissions. They have historically achieved broad political consensus on policy initiatives on energy transition towards reaching net-zero emissions by 2050. The government seeks policy pathways toward achieving stated emissions targets. In this paper, the authors investigated the effect of an environmental tax on environmental degradation in the UK between 2000Q1 and 2019Q4. To achieve this objective, economic progress, trade, and primary energy consumption are controlled positions. Using the novel Fourier ARDL estimator, the long-run equilibrium estimates indicate that both LGDP and LETAX cause a fall in carbon emissions. However, in the case of both LTRA and LPEC, a unit change caused rising carbon emissions in the UK.

5.1. Policy Recommendations

These outcomes have profound environmental policy insight as follows: First, in periods requiring policy response to environmental degradation, the UK economy could safely deploy environmental tax to discourage pollution-intensive activities. It is conceivable to equally deploy environmental taxes on corporate managers to spur growth in green innovation, increase output, and assure environmental quality. Corporations that invest hugely in green production could derive environmental tax advantages over other pollution-intensive enterprises in terms of cost savings and subsequent competitive edge on product pricing.
Second, the UK government must simplify the environmental tax system while ensuring an equitable incentive system to bring relief to vulnerable households. This study has noted that the current UK environmental policy landscape has many overlapping and complex policy cases, especially in the energy sector, where incentives to abate vary across sectors, fuel types, and consumers. This inconsistency within environmental taxes eventually increases the costs of transitioning to net zero. Policy simplification could entail ensuring uniform, effective environmental tax rates and regulatory guidelines. Additionally, the UK government should continue seeking broad-based policy consensus to assure policy stability, as this helps corporations and households to plan. Third, for purposes of the emissions effect of trade, the government of the UK should support international environmental tax coordination efforts, such as those on carbon pricing towards avoiding relocation of carbon-intensive investments. For local coordination, the government of the UK could play a coordinating role, including deploying targeted subsidies and regulations, direct government involvement, or setting higher carbon prices in specific sectors. It is noteworthy that switching to electric vehicles simultaneously requires investments in charging infrastructure and battery technologies to avoid chicken-and-egg situations. Fourth, contrary to some other G7 economies, the United Kingdom does not track support measures with potential environmental impacts. This makes it difficult to accurately quantify the extent of support and failure in the delivery of policy objectives. Moreover, ring-fencing corporate income tax to exclude them from environmental tax is not entirely helpful since, generally, corporations fully deduct decommissioning expenses from profits.
Fifth, the UK government could offer improved private incentives for researching, developing, and deploying new green technologies. The government could recycle environmental tax revenue to support developing clean technologies and infrastructure. This will increase popular support for environmental policies and direct carbon pricing instruments. Essentially, this will require allocating portions of carbon pricing revenue to public and private investments in green infrastructure, research, development, and deployment of green technologies, including carbon capture and storage.

5.2. Limitations and Future Research

Currently, data on environmental subsidies are not fully captured within the environmental tax systems in the UK, and this affects the quality of the research outcomes. Essentially, the broad measure of environmental revenues fails to capture the effect of subsidies and compensation payments. Future studies could consider using data that capture the complete picture of the UK’s environmental tax revenues and subsidies to accurately determine their impact on environmental degradation.
Additionally, the study focuses only on the UK economy. However, due to contextual and policy differences across economies, it would be better to conduct such a study across several economies to be able to accurately capture the true effect of environmental taxes on environmental degradation. It is instructive to note that environmental policy objectives for developing economies will be quite different from developed nations. With such variations, environmental tax development and implementation may quite likely differ in their effects on pollution and environmental quality. Future scholars should take a cue from this limitation.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, K.A., D.K., and S.A.A.; methodology, K.A. and D.K.; software, D.K.; validation, K.A. and D.K.; formal analysis K.A. and D.K.; investigation, K.A. and D.K.; resources, K.A. and D.K.; data curation, K.A.; writing—original draft preparation, K.A., S.H.A.G., P.F., and C.S.; writing—review and editing, K.A. and S.A.A.; visualization, K.A. and D.K.; supervision, D.K.; project administration, D.K. and S.A.A. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research received no external funding.

Data Availability Statement

The original contributions presented in this study are included in the article. Further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflicts of interest.

References

  1. Alvarado, R.; Toledo, E. Environmental degradation and economic growth: Evidence for a developing country. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2017, 19, 1205–1218. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Stern, D.I. The rise and fall of the environmental Kuznets curve. World Dev. 2004, 32, 1419–1439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Chang, C.C.; Carballo, C.F.S. Energy conservation and sustainable economic growth: The case of Latin America and the Caribbean. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 4215–4221. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Pigou, A.C. Some problems of foreign exchange. Econ. J. 1920, 30, 460–472. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Nellor, M.D.C.; McMorran, M.R.T. Tax Policy and the Environment: Theory and Practice; International Monetary Fund: Washington, DC, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  6. Lin, B.; Jia, Z. The energy, environmental and economic impacts of carbon tax rate and taxation industry: A CGE based study in China. Energy 2018, 159, 558–568. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Sun, C.; Ouyang, X. Price and expenditure elasticities of residential energy demand during urbanization: An empirical analysis based on the household-level survey data in China. Energy Policy 2016, 88, 56–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Perino, G.; Pioch, T. Banning incandescent light bulbs in the shadow of the EU Emissions Trading Scheme. Clim. Policy 2017, 17, 678–686. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Hepburn, C.; Grubb, M.; Neuhoff, K.; Matthes, F.; Tse, M. Auctioning of EU ETS phase II allowances: How and why? Clim. Policy 2006, 6, 137–160. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Al Shammre, A.S.; Benhamed, A.; Ben-Salha, O.; Jaidi, Z. Do environmental taxes affect carbon dioxide emissions in OECD countries? Evidence from the dynamic panel threshold model. Systems 2023, 11, 307. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Kirikkaleli, D. Environmental taxes and environmental quality in Canada. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2023, 30, 117862–117870. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Liu, H.; Zafar, M.W.; Sinha, A.; Khan, I. The path to sustainable environment: Do environmental taxes and governance matter? Sustain. Dev. 2023, 31, 2278–2290. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Fullerton, D.; Metcalf, G.E. Tax Incidence; National Bureau of Economic: Medford, MA, USA, 2001. [Google Scholar]
  14. Goulder, L.H.; Parry, I.W.; Williams, R.C., III; Burtraw, D. The cost-effectiveness of alternative instruments for environmental protection in a second-best setting. J. Public Econ. 1999, 72, 329–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Dresner, S.; Jackson, T.; Gilbert, N. History and social responses to environmental tax reform in the United Kingdom. Energy Policy 2006, 34, 930–939. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. UK Environmental Taxes: 2023. Available online: https://www.ons.gov.uk/economy/environmentalaccounts/bulletins/ukenvironmentaltaxes/2023 (accessed on 29 October 2023).
  17. Liu, H.; Lei, H.; Zhou, Y. How does green trade affect the environment? Evidence from China. J. Econ. Anal. 2022, 1, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Metcalf, G.E. On the economics of a carbon tax for the United States. Brook. Pap. Econ. Act. 2019, 2019, 405–484. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Saliba, C.B.; Hassanein, F.R.; Athari, S.A.; Dördüncü, H.; Agyekum, E.B.; Adadi, P. The dynamic impact of renewable energy and economic growth on CO2 emissions in China: Do remittances and technological innovations matter? Sustainability 2022, 14, 14629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Özbay, R.D.; Athari, S.A.; Saliba, C.; Kirikkaleli, D. Towards environmental sustainability in China: Role of globalization and hydroelectricity consumption. Sustainability 2022, 14, 4182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Athari, S.A. The impact of financial development and technological innovations on renewable energy consumption: Do the roles of economic openness and financial stability matter in BRICS economies? Geol. J. 2024, 59, 288–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Athari, S.A. Global economic policy uncertainty and renewable energy demand: Does environmental policy stringency matter? Evidence from OECD economies. J. Clean. Prod. 2024, 450, 141865. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Hashemizadeh, A.; Ju, Y.; Abadi, F.Z.B. Policy design for renewable energy development based on government support: A system dynamics model. Appl. Energy 2024, 376, 124331. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Athari, S.A. Does the sovereign environmental, social, and governance sustainability activities jeopardize the banking sector’s stability: Evidence from the Arab economies. Sustain. Futures 2024, 7, 100204. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Athari, S.A.; Saliba, C.; Abboud, E.; El-Bayaa, N. Examining the Quadratic Impact of Sovereign Environmental, Social, and Governance Practices on Firms’ Profitability: New Insights from the Financial Industry in Gulf Cooperation Council Countries. Sustainability 2024, 16, 2783. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Bashir, M.F.; Ma, B.; Bashir, M.A.; Radulescu, M.; Shahzad, U. Investigating the role of environmental taxes and regulations for renewable energy consumption: Evidence from developed economies. Econ. Res. Ekon. Istraživanja 2022, 35, 1262–1284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Baumol, W.J. On taxation and the control of externalities. Am. Econ. Rev. 1972, 62, 307–322. [Google Scholar]
  28. Yamaguchi, M.; Takamoto, T.; Khan, A.; Imaizumi, M.; Matsuda, S.; Ekins-Daukes, N.J. Super-high-efficiency multi-junction solar cells. Prog. Photovolt. Res. Appl. 2005, 13, 125–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Goulder, L.H. Environmental taxation and the double dividend: A reader’s guide. Int. Tax Public Financ. 1995, 2, 157–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Llop, M. Environmental taxation and international trade in a tax-distorted economy. Economics 2023, 17, 20220038. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Ivanov, I.T.; Kruttli, M.S.; Watugala, S.W. Banking on carbon: Corporate lending and cap-and-trade policy. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2024, 37, 1640–1684. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Meng, S.; Siriwardana, M.; McNeill, J. The environmental and economic impact of the carbon tax in Australia. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2013, 54, 313–332. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Jiang, Z.; Xu, C.; Zhou, J. Government environmental protection subsidies, environmental tax collection, and green innovation: Evidence from listed enterprises in China. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2023, 30, 4627–4641. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Chen, Z.; Zhang, R.; Wang, F.; Xia, F.; Liu, B.; Zhang, B. The distributional effects of China’s environmental taxation: A multi-regional analysis. J. Environ. Manag. 2022, 324, 116276. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  35. Niu, T.; Yao, X.; Shao, S.; Li, D.; Wang, W. Environmental tax shocks and carbon emissions: An estimated DSGE model. Struct. Change Econ. Dyn. 2018, 47, 9–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Barker, T.; Junankar, S.; Pollitt, H.; Summerton, P. Carbon leakage from unilateral environmental tax reforms in Europe, 1995–2005. Energy Policy 2007, 35, 6281–6292. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Ekins, P.; Speck, S. (Eds.) Environmental Tax Reform (ETR): A Policy for Green Growth; Oxford University Press: Oxford, UK, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  38. Fang, G.; Tian, L.; Fu, M.; Sun, M. The impacts of carbon tax on energy intensity and economic growth—A dynamic evolution analysis on the case of China. Appl. Energy 2013, 110, 17–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Lin, B.; Li, X. The effect of carbon tax on per capita CO2 emissions. Energy Policy 2011, 39, 5137–5146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Vera, S.; Sauma, E. Does a carbon tax make sense in countries with still a high potential for energy efficiency? Comparison between the reducing-emissions effects of carbon tax and energy efficiency measures in the Chilean case. Energy 2015, 88, 478–488. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Miceikiene, A.; Čiulevičienė, V.; Rauluskeviciene, J.; Štreimikienė, D. Assessment of the effect of environmental taxes on environmental protection. Ekon. Časopis 2018, 66, 286–308. [Google Scholar]
  42. Morley, B. Empirical evidence on the effectiveness of environmental taxes. Appl. Econ. Lett. 2012, 19, 1817–1820. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Yang, J.; Yue, Y.; Rashmi, K.V. A large-scale analysis of hundreds of in-memory key-value cache clusters at twitter. ACM Trans. Storage TOS 2021, 17, 1–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. U.S nergy Information Administration. International Energy Outlook 2019. Available online: https://www.eia.gov/outlooks/ieo/pdf/ieo2019.pdf (accessed on 30 October 2023).
  45. House of Commons. Introduction to the Domestic Energy Market. Available online: https://researchbriefings.files.parliament.uk/documents/CBP-9768/CBP-9768.pdf (accessed on 30 October 2023).
  46. Grossman, G.M.; Krueger, A.B. Economic growth and the environment. Q. J. Econ. 1995, 110, 353–377. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Niu, T.; Wang, P. The karmic debt of pollution haven hypothesis: Subnational environmental regulatory pressure and foreign divestment from an emerging market. J. Int. Mark. 2023, 32, 33–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Nathaniel, S.P.; Murshed, M.; Bassim, M. The nexus between economic growth, energy use, international trade and ecological footprints: The role of environmental regulations in N11 countries. Energy Ecol. Environ. 2021, 6, 496–512. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Ulucak, R.; Danish; Kassouri, Y. An assessment of the environmental sustainability corridor: Investigating the non-linear effects of environmental taxation on CO2 emissions. Sustain. Dev. 2020, 28, 1010–1018. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Krarti, M.; Dubey, K.; Howarth, N. Energy productivity analysis framework for buildings: A case study of GCC region. Energy 2019, 167, 1251–1265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Stokey, N.L. Are there limits to growth? Int. Econ. Rev. 1998, 39, 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Brock, W.A.; Taylor, M.S. The green Solow model. J. Econ. Growth 2010, 15, 127–153. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Pesaran, M.H.; Shin, Y.; Smith, R.J. Bounds testing approaches to the analysis of level relationships. J. Appl. Econom. 2001, 16, 289–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. McNown, R.; Sam, C.Y.; Goh, S.K. Bootstrapping the autoregressive distributed lag test for cointegration. Appl. Econ. 2018, 50, 1509–1521. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  55. Yilanci, V.; Ozkan, Y.; Altinsoy, A. Testing the unemployment hysteresis in G7 countries: A fresh evidence from fourier threshold unit root test. Rom. J. Econ. Forecast. 2020, 23, 49–59. [Google Scholar]
  56. Becker-Olsen, K.L.; Cudmore, B.A.; Hill, R.P. The impact of perceived corporate social responsibility on consumer behavior. J. Bus. Res. 2006, 59, 46–53. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Ludlow, J.; Enders, W. Estimating non-linear ARMA models using Fourier coefficients. Int. J. Forecast. 2000, 16, 333–347. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Christopoulos, D.K.; León-Ledesma, M.A. Smooth breaks and non-linear mean reversion: Post-Bretton Woods real exchange rates. J. Int. Money Financ. 2010, 29, 1076–1093. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Omay, T. Fractional frequency flexible Fourier form to approximate smooth breaks in unit root testing. Econ. Lett. 2015, 134, 123–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Broock, W.A.; Scheinkman, J.A.; Dechert, W.D.; LeBaron, B. A test for independence based on the correlation dimension. Econom. Rev. 1996, 15, 197–235. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  61. Kočenda, E. Macroeconomic convergence in transition countries. J. Comp. Econ. 2001, 29, 1–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Addai, K.; Serener, B.; Kirikkaleli, D. Empirical analysis of the relationship among urbanization, economic growth and ecological footprint: Evidence from Eastern Europe. Environ. Sci. Pollut. Res. 2022, 29, 27749–27760. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Copeland, B.R.; Taylor, M.S. Trade and the Environment: Theory and Evidence; Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ, USA, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  64. Solow, R.M. An almost practical step toward sustainability. Resour. Policy 1993, 19, 162–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Jagers, S.C.; Hammar, H. Environmental taxation for good and for bad: The efficiency and legitimacy of Sweden’s carbon tax. Environ. Politics 2009, 18, 218–237. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. McEldowney, J.; Salter, D. Environmental taxation in the UK: The climate change levy and policy making. Denning LJ 2016, 28, 37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Serener, B.; Kirikkaleli, D.; Addai, K. Patents on environmental technologies, financial development, and environmental degradation in Sweden: Evidence from novel Fourier-based approaches. Sustainability 2022, 15, 302. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  68. Tyndall Centre. Tyndall Centre Publications. Available online: https://tyndall.ac.uk/publications/ (accessed on 30 October 2023).
  69. Brown, R.L.; Durbin, J.; Evans, J.M. Techniques for testing the constancy of regression relationships over time. J. R. Stat. Soc. Ser. B Stat. Methodol. 1975, 37, 149–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Social effects of environmental taxes under the Pigouvian framework (source: [4]).
Figure 1. Social effects of environmental taxes under the Pigouvian framework (source: [4]).
Energies 17 05732 g001
Figure 2. Tax types in the UK (source: [16]).
Figure 2. Tax types in the UK (source: [16]).
Energies 17 05732 g002
Figure 3. Analysis flowchart.
Figure 3. Analysis flowchart.
Energies 17 05732 g003
Figure 4. Model stability using the cumulative stability test (CUSUM and CUSUM of squares estimators).
Figure 4. Model stability using the cumulative stability test (CUSUM and CUSUM of squares estimators).
Energies 17 05732 g004
Figure 5. Summary of empirical findings with methods.
Figure 5. Summary of empirical findings with methods.
Energies 17 05732 g005
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
Table 1. Descriptive statistics.
LCO2ELGDPLETAXLPECLTRA
Production-Based CO2 EmissionsGDP (Constant 2015 USD)Environmental TaxesPrimary Energy ConsumptionTrade
Mean5.68081412.406560.8838053.39479712.10137
Median5.71879612.421530.8833953.40725512.14079
Maximum5.73792712.506710.9416623.43299312.28227
Minimum5.53577912.275470.8214663.32460011.81647
Std. Dev.0.0632090.0633800.0329830.0333210.125218
Skewness−0.971417−0.4405790.118102−0.557668−0.648029
Kurtosis2.5086732.2634052.1499411.7853342.420849
Jarque–Bera17.402685.7157213.37303411.784038.732460
Probability0.0001660.0573910.1851630.0027610.012699
Observation8080808080
Table 2. BDS test.
Table 2. BDS test.
LCO2E
DimensionBDS StatisticStd. ErrorZ-StatisticProb.
20.1898140.00804823.586580.0000
30.3152990.01287724.485200.0000
40.3987360.01543925.826200.0000
50.4559430.01620328.140130.0000
60.4964960.01573331.557270.0000
LETAX
DimensionBDS StatisticStd. ErrorZ-StatisticProb.
20.1809570.00515735.090750.0000
30.3010610.00820436.695700.0000
40.3773480.00977638.600400.0000
50.4228360.01019441.480580.0000
60.4473320.00983445.489290.0000
LPEC
DimensionBDS StatisticStd. ErrorZ-StatisticProb.
20.1843770.00569332.388480.0000
30.3054640.00906933.683160.0000
40.3850170.01082135.580630.0000
50.4376000.01130038.726570.0000
60.4730690.01091743.334010.0000
LGDP
DimensionBDS StatisticStd. ErrorZ-StatisticProb.
20.2078990.00543838.233260.0000
30.3527090.00865140.769680.0000
40.4544830.01030944.085790.0000
50.5268800.01075149.009110.0000
60.5787960.01037255.802520.0000
LTRA
DimensionBDS StatisticStd. ErrorZ-StatisticProb.
20.2055970.00600334.250650.0000
30.3493110.00958536.441760.0000
40.4503810.01146539.281940.0000
50.5219160.01200243.485890.0000
60.5730000.01162449.295330.0000
Table 3. ADF unit root test with breakpoint.
Table 3. ADF unit root test with breakpoint.
VariablesADF with Breakpoint
LCO2E−2.276 (2013Q1)
LETAX−3.510 (2002Q1)
LGDP−5.062 *** (2009Q1)
LPEC−2.145 (2006Q4)
LTRA−3.881 (1994Q4)
DLCO2E−6.406 (1996Q1) **
DLETAX−6.011 (2009Q1) **
DLGDPNA
DLPEC−6.790 (1996Q1) **
DLTRA−5.391 (1997Q1) **
Note: ** and *** denote 5% and 1% significance levels, respectively.
Table 4. Fourier ARDL Cointegration Analysis.
Table 4. Fourier ARDL Cointegration Analysis.
Model FrequencyMin AIC
LCO2E = f(LETAX, LGDP, LTRA, LPEC)−7.8539770.6−3.572768
Table 5. Fourier ARDL long-run form.
Table 5. Fourier ARDL long-run form.
VariablesCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
LGDP−2.1988020.521931−4.2128190.0001
LTRA0.7375570.3034972.4301940.0183
LETAX−0.3951060.153661−2.5712790.0128
LPEC1.6458850.4298623.8288640.0003
C1.7574060.2796096.2852160.0000
@TREND8.31 × 10−51.49 × 10−55.5614380.0000
SIN 0.0007100.0002492.8492810.0061
COS0.0001040.0002700.3838570.7025
CointEq(-1) ***−0.0937550.014914−6.2862910.0000
Note: *** denote statistical significance at the 1% level.
Table 6. Heteroskedasticity test and serial correlation LM tests.
Table 6. Heteroskedasticity test and serial correlation LM tests.
Breusch–Pagan–Godfrey
F-statistic0.790948Prob. F(39,57)0.7790
Breusch–Godfrey Test
F-statistic0.371832Prob. F(6,51)0.8935
Table 7. Fourier TY Causality Test.
Table 7. Fourier TY Causality Test.
T-Statp-Value
Ho1LGDP does not cause LCO2E16.88529 **0.031326
Ho2LTRA does not cause LCO2E25.33331 ***0.000662
Ho3LETAX does not cause LCO2E16.94006 **0.017787
Ho4LPEC does not cause LCO2E10.85399 *0.07612
Note: *, **, and *** denote statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Addai, K.; Al Geitany, S.H.; Athari, S.A.; Farmanesh, P.; Kirikkaleli, D.; Saliba, C. Do Environmental Tax and Energy Matter for Environmental Degradation in the UK? Evidence from Novel Fourier-Based Estimators. Energies 2024, 17, 5732. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17225732

AMA Style

Addai K, Al Geitany SH, Athari SA, Farmanesh P, Kirikkaleli D, Saliba C. Do Environmental Tax and Energy Matter for Environmental Degradation in the UK? Evidence from Novel Fourier-Based Estimators. Energies. 2024; 17(22):5732. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17225732

Chicago/Turabian Style

Addai, Kwaku, Souha Hanna Al Geitany, Seyed Alireza Athari, Panteha Farmanesh, Dervis Kirikkaleli, and Chafic Saliba. 2024. "Do Environmental Tax and Energy Matter for Environmental Degradation in the UK? Evidence from Novel Fourier-Based Estimators" Energies 17, no. 22: 5732. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17225732

APA Style

Addai, K., Al Geitany, S. H., Athari, S. A., Farmanesh, P., Kirikkaleli, D., & Saliba, C. (2024). Do Environmental Tax and Energy Matter for Environmental Degradation in the UK? Evidence from Novel Fourier-Based Estimators. Energies, 17(22), 5732. https://doi.org/10.3390/en17225732

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop