Speed Optimization vs Speed Reduction: the Choice between Speed Limits and a Bunker Levy
Abstract
:1. Introduction
“Consider and analyze the use of speed optimization and speed reduction as a measure, taking into account safety issues, distance travelled, distortion of the market or trade and that such measure does not impact on shipping’s capability to serve remote geographic areas”
2. Background
2.1. Definition of “Speed Optimization”
“Speed optimization can produce significant savings. However, optimum speed means the speed at which the fuel used per tonne mile is at a minimum level for that voyage. It does not mean minimum speed; in fact, sailing at less than optimum speed will consume more fuel rather than less. Reference should be made to the engine manufacturer’s power/consumption curve and the ship’s propeller curve. Possible adverse consequences of slow speed operation may include increased vibration and problems with soot deposits in combustion chambers and exhaust systems. These possible consequences should be taken into account.”
Speed optimization can be defined as the selection of an appropriate speed profile for the ship so as to optimize a specific objective while meeting various requirements (or constraints) on the ship’s operation. The speeds that correspond to the chosen speed profile are called “optimal speeds”.
2.2. Slow Steaming: A Voluntary Practice
2.3. Factors that May Influence Ship Speed
2.4. Other Contexts and Side-Effects
3. The Speed Limiters’ Pitch
4. Comparison between a Bunker Levy and a Speed Limit
4.1. Preamble
4.2. A Rudimentary Example
- Round trip time T = 2L/v (days)
- Round trip TEU throughput H = 2uQ (TEU)
- Round trip cost C = T (pkv3 + X) = 2(pkLv2 + LX/v) (USD)
- Round trip income I = 2uRQ (USD)
- Round trip profit P = I − C = 2(uRQ − pkLv2 − LX/v) (USD)
- Average per day profit P’ = P/T = uRQv/L − pkv3 − X (USD/day)
- Average per day TEU throughput H’ = 2uQ/T= uQv/L (TEU/day)
- vopt = vmin if vmin > v0
- vopt = v0 if vmin ≤ v0 ≤ vmax
- vopt = vmax if vmax < v0
4.3. Speed Directional Imbalances
- Two different load factors, u1 from A to B, and u2 from B to A, both in the range 0 to 1.
- Two different freight rates, R1 from A to B, and R2 from B to A (both in USD per laden TEU).
- Two different cargo in transit inventory costs, β1 from A to B, and β2 from B to A, each expressed in USD per laden TEU per day. Each of the betas is a function of the value of the cargo, according to the formula βi = CIFi D/365 (i = 1,2), where CIFi is the CIF value of the cargo (in USD/TEU) in direction i (i = 1,2) and D is the cargo owner’s cost of capital.
- Two (generally) different speeds, v1 from A to B and v2 from B to A.
- v1 = v2 = vmin if vmin > v0
- v1 = v2 = v0 if vmin ≤ v0 ≤ vmax
- v1 = v2 = vmax if vmax < v0
- with v0 = (R0Q/3pkL)1/2
- vmin ≤ v1 ≤ vmax
- vmin ≤ v2 ≤ vmax
4.4. Additional Considerations in the Comparison
- For ships of different size, a common and uniform levy will result in different optimal speeds. The levy will have to be uniform as it reflects the external cost of GHG emissions, which should be independent of the source of these emissions (not to mention that administering a non-uniform levy would be impossible). However, a larger ship would in general imply a higher optimal speed, everything else being equal. Therefore, achieving equivalence such as the one examined in Section 4.2 by a common and uniform speed limit V would be impossible. To do so, one would have to set size-specific (or maybe also ship type-specific or even route-specific) speed limits. A ship type- and size-specific speed limit has been proposed by CSC in their latest IMO speed-limit paper [29], but it would make the whole exercise an administrative nightmare.
- Conversely, if a common and uniform speed limit V is imposed, the limit may be superfluous for some ship types and sizes and binding for some others, depending on the state of the market, the price of fuel, and a host of other parameters. Having the same speed limit in boom market periods and in depressed market periods could create all sorts of distortions. In depressed market periods the limit may be superfluous, and in boom market periods the limit would force some ships (likely at the high end of the scale) to slow down whereas others do not. A speed limit may also be superfluous in one route direction (e.g., from Europe to the Far East, where ships go slower anyway) and binding in the other direction (ships go faster from the Far East to Europe).
- In addition to not paying the levy, another short-term effect of a speed limit that would be beneficial for ship owners is that freight rates would go up, as the speed limit would effectively shrink the ship transport capacity supply curve. What the freight rate increase will be and who, among ship owners, will be the main beneficiaries of this rate increase would depend (among other things) on the nature and structure of the speed limit in regards to the world fleet. Note that the contraction of the supply curve due to slow steaming because of a bunker levy would also result in a freight rate increase. A comparison of the two outcomes (freight rate increase induced by a speed limit versus freight rate increase induced by a bunker levy) is not straightforward.
- Even though higher freight rates and no payment of a levy may render the speed limit measure preferable to some ship owners versus a levy (let alone versus a “do nothing” option), shippers would be hit twice: They would pay more for their cargo and also suffer increased transit times and increased in-transit inventory costs. Trade may also be affected.
- Another effect of a speed limit, which is more in the long run, is that additional ships will have to be built to sustain ton-mile throughput at lower speeds, particularly if maritime trade is projected to grow. Building these additional ships would produce additional GHG emissions due to shipbuilding and recycling (lifecycle GHG emissions). See Gratsos et al. [36] and Chatzinikolaou and Ventikos [37,38] for more details.
- Building more ships would also take place in the long run if speeds are reduced due to a bunker levy. However, due to the much lower flexibility of a speed limit, it is speculated that lifecycle GHG emissions of the speed limit scenario would be higher, as some ships would have to be built only to sustain a ton-mile throughput that could be met by higher speeds in boom periods (something that would be impossible if a speed limit is instituted). Then in depressed market periods this extra ship capacity would make the fleet overcapacity problem even more acute.
- A speed limit regime would not be compatible with virtual arrival, as the latter scheme requires maximum flexibility on the part of the ship to meet a prescribed port time slot. Flexibility is also a must in cases when schedule disruptions (for instance due to bad weather, port congestion, search and rescue operations, etc.) should be handled. Such flexibility would be reduced by a speed limit.
- The impact of a bunker levy or a speed limit on the economies of LDCs (lesser developed countries) and SIDS (small island developing states) is largely unknown. This may include a decrease of export products competitiveness, an increase of import prices, shifts to other modes of transport, and other side-effects.
- Last but not least, a speed limit would hardly serve as an incentive to economize and improve the energy efficiency of ships. Two ships of the same type and size, one modern and energy efficient and one old and energy inefficient, would have to go at the same speed, and this would offer an unfair advantage to the latter ship and would thus distort competition. In the long run, a speed limit would not incentivize the development of energy efficient technologies that are currently non-viable.
5. Conclusions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- IMO. Resolution MEPC.304(72) (Adopted on 13 April 2018), Initial IMO Strategy on Reduction of GHG Emissions from Ships, IMO doc MEPC 72/17/Add.1, Annex 11; IMO: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Psaraftis, H.N. Market Based Measures for Green House Gas Emissions from Ships: A Review. Wmu J. Marit. Aff. 2012, 11, 211–232. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Psaraftis, H.N. Green maritime transportation: Market based measures. In Green Transportation Logistics: In Search for Win-Win Solutions; Psaraftis, H.N., Ed.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- IMO. Proposal to Include Work on Market-based Measures in the Programme of Follow-up Actions of the Initial IMO GHG Strategy, Submitted by France to the 4th Intersessional Working Group on GHGs, IMO doc. ISWG-GHG 4/2/11; IMO: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- IMO. Action Plan for Implementing the IMO GHG Strategy and Candidate Measures, Submitted by Antigua and Barbuda, Kenya, Marshall Islands, Palau, Solomon Islands, Tonga, and Tuvalu to the 4th Intersessional Working Group on GHGs, IMO doc. ISWG-GHG 4/2/3; IMO: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Psaraftis, H.N.; Kontovas, C.A. Speed models for energy-efficient maritime transportation: A taxonomy and survey. Transp. Res. C Emerg. Technol. 2013, 26, 331–351. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mills, J.; Donnison, A.; Brightwell, G. Factors affecting microbial spoilage and shelf-life of chilled vacuum-packed lamb transported to distant markets: A review. Meat Sci. 2014, 98, 71–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- IMO. Resolution MEPC.213(63) Adopted on 2 March 2012 2012 Guidelines for the Development of a Ship Energy Efficiency Management Plan (SEEMP), IMO doc MEPC 63/23 Annex 9; IMO: London, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Alphaliner. Extra and Super Slow Steaming Help Absorb 7.4 % of Fleet. Alphaliner Weekly Newsletter. 2013. Available online: www.alphaliner.com (accessed on 12 April 2019).
- UNCTAD. Review of Maritime Transport 2016; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; United Nations: New York, NY, USA; Geneva, Switzerland, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Lloyds List. MSC Boxships Slow Down as Chief Executive Diego Aponte Overhauls Network; Informa PLC: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- International Maritime Organization (IMO). Third IMO GHG Study 2014, Co-Authored by Smith, T.W.P., Jalkanen, J.P., Anderson, B.A., Corbett, J.J., Faber, J., Hanayama, S., O’Keeffe, E., Parker, S., Johansson, L., Aldous, L., Raucci, C., Traut, M., Ettinger, S., Nelissen, D., Lee, D.S., Ng, S., Agrawal, A., Winebrake, J., Hoen, M., Chesworth, S., Pandey, A.; International Maritime Organization (IMO): London, UK, 2014. [Google Scholar]
- Gkonis, K.G.; Psaraftis, H.N. Modelling Tankers’ Optimal Speed and Emissions; Archival Paper, 2012 SNAME Transactions. In Proceedings of the Annual Meeting of the Society of Naval Architects and Marine Engineers, Providence, RI, USA, 24–26 October 2012; Volume 120, pp. 90–115. [Google Scholar]
- Psaraftis, H.N. Speed Optimization for sustainable shipping. In Sustainable Shipping: A Cross-Disciplinary View; Psaraftis, H.N., Ed.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Psaraftis, H.N.; Kontovas, C.A. Ship Emissions: Logistics and Other Tradeoffs. In Proceedings of the 10th International Marine Design Conference, Trondheim, Norway, 26–29 May 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Fagerholt, K.; Gausel, N.T.; Rakke, J.G.; Psaraftis, H.N. Maritime routing and speed optimization with emission control areas. Transp. Res. C: Emerg. Technol. 2015, 52, 57–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Fagerholt, K.; Psaraftis, H.N. On two speed optimization problems for ships that sail in and out of emission control areas. Transp. Res. D: Transp. Environ. 2015, 39, 56–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Magirou, E.F.; Psaraftis, H.N.; Bouritas, T. The economic speed of an oceangoing vessel in a dynamic setting. Transp. Res. B Methodol. 2015, 76, 48–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Giovannini, M.; Psaraftis, H.N. The profit maximizing liner shipping problem with flexible frequencies: Logistical and environmental considerations. Flex. Serv. Manuf. J. 2018, 1–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Psaraftis, H.N.; Kontovas, C.A. Balancing the economic and environmental performance of maritime transportation. Transp. Res. D Transp. Environ. 2010, 15, 458–462. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- IMO. Analysis of the Impact on States and the Implications of Speed Reduction, Submitted by Chile and Peru to the 3rd Intersessional WG on GHGs, IMO doc. ISWG-GHG 3/2/10; IMO: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Zis, T.; Psaraftis, H.N. The implications of the new sulphur limits on the European Ro-Ro sector. Transp. Res. D Transp. Environ. 2017, 52, 185–201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zis, T.; Psaraftis, H.N. Operational measures to mitigate and reverse the potential modal shifts due to environmental legislation. Marit. Manag. 2018, 46, 117–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Psaraftis, H.N.; Kontovas, C.A. Slow steaming in maritime transportation: Fundamentals, trade-offs, and decision models. In Handbook of Ocean Container Transportation Logistics: Making Global Supply Chains Effective; Lee, C.-Y., Meng, Q., Eds.; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Zis, T.; North, R.J.; Angeloudis, P.; Ochieng, W.Y.; Bell, M.G.H. Evaluation of cold ironing and speed reduction policies to reduce ship emissions near and at ports. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2014, 16, 371–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Golias, M.; Boile, M.; Theofanis, S.; Efstathiou, C. The berth-scheduling problem: Maximizing berth productivity and minimizing fuel consumption and emissions production. Transp. Res. Rec. 2010, 2166, 20–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Du, Y.; Chen, Q.; Quan, X.; Long, L.; Fung, R.Y.K. Berth allocation considering fuel consumption and vessel emissions. Transp. Res. E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2011, 47, 1021–1037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- CE Delft. Regulating Speed: A Short Term Measure to Reduce Maritime GHG Emissions, Study by CE Delft for the Clean Shipping Coalition; CE Delft: Delft, The Netherlands, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- IMO. The Regulation of Ship Operational Speed: An Immediate GHG Reduction Measure to Deliver the IMO 2030 Target, Submitted by the Clean Shipping Coalition (CSC) to the 4th Intersessional Working Group on GHGs, IMO doc. ISWG-GHG 4/2/8; IMO: London, UK, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Cariou, P. Is slow steaming a sustainable means of reducing CO2 emissions from container shipping? Transp. Res. D Transp. Environ. 2011, 16, 260–264. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cheaitou, A.; Cariou, P. Liner shipping service optimisation with reefer containers capacity: An application to northern Europe–South America trade. Marit. Manag. 2012, 39, 589–602. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Federal Maritime Commission (FMC). Study of the 2008 Repeal of the Liner Conference Exemption from European Union Competition Law, Bureau of Trade Analysis; Federal Maritime Commission: Washington, DC, USA, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Vilas, R.F. Container Shipping Performance: A Case Study on a Transpacific Service. Master’s Thesis, Technical University of Denmark, Lyngby, Denmark, 2018. [Google Scholar]
- Devanney, J.W. Speed Limits versus Slow Steaming, Center for Tankship Excellence. 2011. Available online: www.c4tx.org (accessed on 12 April 2019).
- Cariou, P.; Cheaitou, A. The effectiveness of a European speed limit versus an international bunker-levy to reduce CO2 emissions from container shipping. Transp. Res. D: Transp. Environ. 2012, 17, 116–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gratsos, G.A.; Psaraftis, H.N.; Zachariadis, P. Life-cycle CO2 emissions of bulk carriers: A Comparative Study. Int. J. Marit. Eng. 2010, 152, 119–134. [Google Scholar]
- Chatzinikolaou, S.D.; Ventikos, N.P. Holistic framework for studying ship air emissions in a life cycle perspective. Ocean Eng. 2015, 110, 113–122. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chatzinikolaou, S.D.; Ventikos, N.P. Critical Analysis of Air Emissions from Ships: Lifecycle Thinking and Results. In Project Scheduling; Springer: Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany, 2016; Volume 226, pp. 387–412. [Google Scholar]
- Psaraftis, H.N. Speed optimization vs speed reduction: The speed limit debate. In Proceedings of the Conference of the International Association of Maritime Economists (IAME 2019), Athens, Greece, 25–28 June 2019. [Google Scholar]
Input | Value |
---|---|
Q | 10,000 TEU |
L | 20,000 nm |
R (base case) | 1500 USD/TEU |
u | 0.6 |
p | 500 USD/tonne |
vmin | 16 knots |
vmax | 26 knots |
X | 15,000 USD/day |
R (USD/TEU) | 500 | 1000 | 1500 (Base Case) | 1800 | 2000 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
vopt (knots) | 16.00 | 18.84 | 23.07 | 25.28 | 26.00 |
T (days) | 104.17 | 88.47 | 73.23 | 65.94 | 64.10 |
H (TEU) | 12,000 | 12,000 | 12,000 | 12,000 | 12,000 |
C (USD) | 4,447,589 | 5,326,987 | 7,083,480 | 8,189,078 | 8,579,871 |
I (USD) | 6,000,000 | 12,000,000 | 18,000,000 | 21,600,000 | 24,000,000 |
P (USD) | 1,552,451 | 6,673,013 | 10,916,520 | 13,410,922 | 15,420,129 |
P’ (USD/day) | 14,904 | 75,430 | 151,131 | 203,385 | 240,554 |
H’ (TEU/day) | 115.20 | 135.65 | 166.13 | 181.99 | 187.20 |
CO2 (tonnes/day) | 172.27 | 281.24 | 516.67 | 679.18 | 739.22 |
SPEED LIMIT CASE | LEVY CASE | |
---|---|---|
v0 | (uRQ/3pkL)1/2 | (uRQ/3 (p + q) kL)1/2 |
vopt | vopt = vmin if vmin > v0 | vopt = vmin if vmin > v0 |
vopt = v0 if vmin ≤ v0 ≤ V | vopt = v0 if vmin ≤ v0 ≤ vmax | |
vopt = V if V < v0 | vopt = vmax if vmax < v0 | |
P’ | uRQvopt/L − pkvopt3 − X | uRQvopt/L − (p + q) kvopt3 − X |
CO2 | fkvopt3 | fkvopt3 |
V (Knots) | 18.00 | 20.00 | 22.00 |
---|---|---|---|
vopt (knots) | 18.00 | 20.00 | 22.00 |
T (days) | 92.59 | 83.33 | 75.76 |
C (USD) | 5,040,279 | 5,757,889 | 6,590,909 |
I (USD) | 18,000,000 | 18,000,000 | 18,000,000 |
P (USD) | 12,959,721 | 12,242,111 | 11,409,091 |
r | 1.28 | 1.15 | 1.05 |
P’ (USD/day) | 179,418 | 169,483 | 157,951 |
CO2 (tonnes/day) | 314.43 | 388.18 | 469.70 |
ΔCO2 (tonnes/day) | 202.24 | 128.49 | 46.97 |
% ΔCO2 | 39% | 25% | 9% |
q (USD/Tonne) | 100 | 300 | 500 |
---|---|---|---|
vopt (knots) | 21.06 | 18.24 | 16.32 |
T (days) | 79.13 | 91.37 | 102.15 |
C (USD/rtrip) | 7,186,893 | 7,370,506 | 7,532,272 |
I (USD/rtrip) | 18,000,000 | 18,000,000 | 18,000,000 |
P (USD/rtrip) | 10,813,107 | 10,629,494 | 10,467,728 |
r | 1.10 | 1.27 | 1.41 |
P’ (USD/day) | 149,723 | 147,169 | 144,880 |
CO2 (tonnes/day) | 430.62 | 322.94 | 258.27 |
ΔCO2 (tonnes/day) | 86.05 | 193.73 | 258.40 |
% ΔCO2 | 17% | 37% | 50% |
© 2019 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Psaraftis, H.N. Speed Optimization vs Speed Reduction: the Choice between Speed Limits and a Bunker Levy. Sustainability 2019, 11, 2249. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11082249
Psaraftis HN. Speed Optimization vs Speed Reduction: the Choice between Speed Limits and a Bunker Levy. Sustainability. 2019; 11(8):2249. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11082249
Chicago/Turabian StylePsaraftis, Harilaos N. 2019. "Speed Optimization vs Speed Reduction: the Choice between Speed Limits and a Bunker Levy" Sustainability 11, no. 8: 2249. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11082249
APA StylePsaraftis, H. N. (2019). Speed Optimization vs Speed Reduction: the Choice between Speed Limits and a Bunker Levy. Sustainability, 11(8), 2249. https://doi.org/10.3390/su11082249