Asymmetric Impact of Financial Intermediary Development in Low- and High-Income Countries
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Methodology
2.1. Three-Sector Endogenous Growth Model
2.1.1. Representative Family
2.1.2. Production Sector
2.1.3. Financial Intermediation Sector
2.1.4. Equilibrium
2.2. Empirical Analysis
2.2.1. Introduction of Quantile Regression
2.2.2. Empirical Model Setting
2.3. Data Description and Variables Selection
- For the household sector, this study selects consumer price index (CPI), labor supply, employment, and population growth as variables (Baldwin and Forslid, [2]). Specifically, education is used to determine whether economic development results from labor capital quality (According to the United Nations Economic Commission, gross enrolment ratio in tertiary education is defined as “a nation’s total enrollment in a tertiary level of education, regardless of age, expressed as a percentage of the population to tertiary level of education”) or from population growth.
- For the production sector, capital industrial production, producer price index (PPI), and wage rate are selected as the independent variables (Baldwin and Forslid, [17]).
- For the financial intermediary sector, in addition to interest spread, numerous indices including scale, efficiency, capital market momentum, and international banking are chosen (Beck et al., [18]):
- To examine the scale of a financial system, this study first calculates the ratio of financial sector liquid liabilities to GDP, which can be used to evaluate the growth of financial institutions according to their liquid liability holdings; ratios of financial system deposits to GDP and bank deposits to GDP are also employed. The ratio of private credit by deposit money at banks and other financial institutions to GDP (pcrdbofgdp) is the proportion of private deposits in commercial banks to GDP, indicating that the more the deposits that people place in banks, the faster national wealth grows (Beck et al., [19,20]).
- To examine the scale, efficiency, and stability of a financial system, the following independent variables are evaluated: central bank assets to GDP, deposit money banks’ assets to GDP, other financial institutions’ assets to GDP, and deposit money versus central bank assets. Furthermore, an efficiency index is calculated using net interest margin and overhead cost; a higher net interest margin indicates that a bank uses its assets adequately, whereas a higher overhead cost indicates that a bank does not use its assets efficiently. Finally, the profit earning ability of a bank is examined using the return on assets and return on equity. The stability variable of a bank is represented by a z-score, which is calculated from the following equation:
- To determine whether the ability of a company to self-finance can affect economic growth, the scale of the stock and bond markets and the stock market turnover ratio are considered.
- Finally, the ratio of international debt issues to GDP is included to evaluate the overseas debt of a nation in relation to its GDP. The ratio of offshore deposits to domestic deposits and the ratio of remittance inflows to GDP are also valuable indices.
3. Empirical Results
3.1. Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) Model
3.2. Quantile Regression (QR) Model
4. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Romer, P.M. Endogenous technological change. J. Political Econ. 1990, 98, 71–102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Koenker, R.; Gilbert, B. Regression quantiles. Econometrica 1978, 46, 211–244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fu, Z.; Xi, D.; Xu, J. Bank competition, financial development, and income inequality. Contemp. Econ. Policy 2020. forthcoming. [Google Scholar]
- Levine, R.; Beck, T.; Loayza, N. Financial intermediation and growth: Causality and causes. J. Monet. Econ. 2000, 46, 31–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Odedokun, M.O. Alternative econometric approaches for analysing the role of the financial sector in economic growth: Time-series evidence from LDCs. J. Dev. Econ. 1996, 50, 119–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cheng, S.Y.; Hou, H. Do non-intermediation services tell us more in the finance-growth nexus? Causality evidence from eight OECD countries. Appl. Econ. 2020, 52, 756–768. [Google Scholar]
- Levine, R. Stock markets, growth, and tax policy. J. Financ. 1991, 46, 1445–1465. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mhadhbi, K.; Terzi, C.; Bouchrika, A. Banking sector development and economic growth in developing countries: A bootstrap panel Granger causality analysis. Empir. Econ. 2020, 58, 2817–2836. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beck, T.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; Laeven, L.; Levine, R. Finance, firm size, and growth. J. Money Credit Bank. 2008, 40, 1379–1405. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; Levine, R. Stock market development and financial Intermediaries: Stylized facts. World Bank Econ. Rev. 1996, 10, 291–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bencivenga, V.R.; Smith, B.D. Economic development and financial depth in a model with costly financial intermediation. Res. Econ. 1998, 52, 363–386. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Greenwood, J.; Smith, B.D. Financial markets in development, and the development of financial markets. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 1997, 21, 145–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jones, C.I.; Kim, J. A Schumpeterian model of top income inequality. J. Political Econ. 2018, 126, 1785–1826. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Aghion, P.; Akcigit, U.; Bergeaud, A.; Blundell, R.; Hemous, D. Innovation and top income inequality. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2019, 86, 1–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Goodfriend, M.; McCallum, B.T. Banking and interest rates in monetary policy analysis: A quantitative exploration. J. Monet. Econ. 2007, 54, 1480–1507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Mello, M.; Perrelli, R. Growth equations: A quantile regression exploration. Q. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2003, 43, 643–667. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baldwin, R.E.; Forslid, R. The core-periphery model and endogenous growth: Stabilizing and destabilizing intergration. Economica 2000, 67, 307–324. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beck, T.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; Levine, R. Financial Institutions and Markets across Countries and over Time—Data and Analysis; Policy Research Working Paper No. 4943; World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2009. [Google Scholar]
- Beck, T.; Levine, R.; Loayza, N. Finance and the sources of growth. J. Financ. Econ. 2000, 58, 261–300. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Beck, T.; Demirgüç-Kunt, A.; Levine, R. Finance, inequality and the poor. J. Econ. Growth 2007, 12, 27–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Variable Name | Symbol | Definition |
---|---|---|
Dependent variable | ||
The growth rate of GDP per capita | gdpr | , where gdppc is the country’s GDP divided by the total number of people in the country in a given year t. |
Independent variables (about household) | ||
Consumer price index | cpi | A measure that examines the weighted average of prices of a basket of consumer goods and services. |
Higher educated rate | edu | total number educated above senior high school divided by all citizens |
Independent variables (about firm) | ||
Capital | cpl | |
industrial production | ip | |
Producer price index | ppi | |
Wage hourly earnings | whe | |
Independent variables (about the scale of financial institution) | ||
Liquid liabilities to GDP | llgdp | |
Financial system’s deposits to GDP | fdgdp | |
Bank deposits to GDP | bdgdp | |
Private credit to GDP | pcrdbofgdp | the private sector’s deposits in the commercial banks and other intermediaries per GDP |
Independent variables (about the efficiency and stability of financial institution) | ||
Interest spread | is | Lending rate-Deposit rates |
Central bank assets to GDP | cbagdp | |
Deposit money banks’ assets to GDP | dbagdp | |
Other financial assets to GDP | ofagdp | |
Deposit money vs. central bank assets | dbacba | |
Net interest margin | netintmargin | |
Overhead cost | overhead | |
Return on assets | roa | |
Return on equity | roe | |
Bank z-score | zscore | The ratio of return on assets plus capital-asset-The ratio to the standard deviation of return on assets. |
Dependent variable (About financial market) | ||
Stock market capitalization to GDP | stmktcap | |
Bond Market capitalization to GDP | pubond | |
Stock market turnover ratio | stturnover | The turnover of stock market |
Dependent variable (the index of financial integration) | ||
International debt issues to GDP | intldebt | |
Offshore deposits to domestic deposits | offdep | |
Remittance inflows to GDP | remit |
Number | Country Name | Abbreviation | Income Classification |
---|---|---|---|
1 | Taiwan | TWN | high |
2 | Japan | JPN | high |
3 | Korea | KOR | high |
4 | United Kingdom | GBR | high |
5 | United States | USA | high |
6 | Brazil | BLZ | medium high |
7 | Malaysia | MYS | medium high |
8 | Russia | RUS | medium high |
9 | China | CHN | medium low |
10 | India | IND | medium low |
11 | Philippines | PHL | medium low |
12 | Thailand | THA | medium low |
13 | Vietnam | VNM | low |
14 | Cambodia | KHM | low |
15 | Myanmar | MMR | low |
Mean | S.D. | Q1 | Median | Q3 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
gdpr | 0.1046 | 0.1029 | 0.0479 | 0.0929 | 0.1565 |
edu | 39.5417 | 27.3560 | 13.0000 | 32.0000 | 62.5000 |
llgdp | 0.7588 | 0.4888 | 0.4564 | 0.6390 | 1.0244 |
fdgdp | 0.6964 | 0.4879 | 0.4068 | 0.5751 | 0.9550 |
bdgdp | 0.6859 | 0.4881 | 0.4068 | 0.5751 | 0.9550 |
cbagdp | 0.0490 | 0.0499 | 0.0172 | 0.0259 | 0.0582 |
dbacba | 0.8995 | 0.1554 | 0.8904 | 0.9530 | 0.9836 |
netintmargin | 0.0357 | 0.0199 | 0.0218 | 0.0291 | 0.0418 |
overhead | 0.0281 | 0.0186 | 0.0148 | 0.0222 | 0.0400 |
roa | 0.0112 | 0.0122 | 0.0040 | 0.0093 | 0.0145 |
roe | 0.0949 | 0.1247 | 0.0516 | 0.1027 | 0.1444 |
zscore | 7.7531 | 5.9334 | 3.8571 | 5.6263 | 9.3997 |
cpi | 125.3000 | 52.2310 | 101.7000 | 108.8000 | 121.2000 |
Variable | Coefficient | s.e. | t-Value | Pr > |t| |
---|---|---|---|---|
Intercept | −0.3289 *** | 0.1198 | −2.75 | 0.0071 |
edu | −0.0008 ** | 0.0004 | −2.08 | 0.0395 |
llgdp | −0.1477 | 0.1031 | −1.43 | 0.1549 |
fdgdp | 0.0433 | 0.2389 | 0.18 | 0.8566 |
bdgdp | 0.0839 | 0.2610 | 0.32 | 0.7486 |
cbagdp | −0.2275 | 0.3202 | −0.71 | 0.4791 |
dbacba | 0.3227 ** | 0.1295 | 2.49 | 0.0143 |
netintmargin | 0.3070 | 1.1742 | 0.26 | 0.7943 |
overhead | 0.6971 | 0.9699 | 0.72 | 0.4739 |
roa | 3.2909 *** | 0.8604 | 3.82 | 0.0002 |
roe | −0.1141 | 0.0774 | −1.47 | 0.1434 |
zscore | −0.0003 | 0.0017 | −0.18 | 0.8553 |
cpi | 0.0015 *** | 0.0002 | 6.85 | <0.0001 |
Year effects | Yes | |||
Obs. | 215 | |||
Adjusted R-square | 0.325 |
Variable | Coefficient | s.e. | 95% Confidence | Limits | t-Value | Pr > |t| |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Intercept | −0.2347 | 0.1439 | −0.5199 | 0.0506 | −1.63 | 0.1059 |
edu | −0.0007 * | 0.0004 | −0.0014 | 0.0000 | −1.85 | 0.0665 |
llgdp | −0.1707 * | 0.1016 | −0.3721 | 0.0307 | −1.68 | 0.0958 |
fdgdp | 0.1135 | 0.2557 | −0.3936 | 0.6206 | 0.44 | 0.6582 |
bdgdp | 0.0622 | 0.2863 | −0.5054 | 0.6298 | 0.22 | 0.8284 |
cbagdp | −0.4415 | 0.3190 | −1.0740 | 0.1909 | −1.38 | 0.1692 |
dbacba | 0.2689 ** | 0.1313 | 0.0085 | 0.5293 | 2.05 | 0.0431 |
netintmargin | 0.4569 | 1.2255 | −1.9731 | 2.8868 | 0.37 | 0.7101 |
overhead | 0.1324 | 1.0325 | −1.9149 | 2.1797 | 0.13 | 0.8982 |
roa | 1.6101 | 1.4307 | −1.2267 | 4.4469 | 1.13 | 0.2630 |
roe | 0.0482 | 0.1095 | −0.1689 | 0.2653 | 0.44 | 0.6607 |
zscore | 0.0001 | 0.0015 | −0.0028 | 0.0030 | 0.07 | 0.9454 |
cpi | 0.0013 *** | 0.0003 | 0.0007 | 0.0019 | 4.21 | 0.0001 |
Year effects | Yes | |||||
Obs. | 215 | |||||
Adjusted R-square | 0.242 |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Yang, C.-C.; Chang, Y.-K. Asymmetric Impact of Financial Intermediary Development in Low- and High-Income Countries. Sustainability 2020, 12, 5960. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12155960
Yang C-C, Chang Y-K. Asymmetric Impact of Financial Intermediary Development in Low- and High-Income Countries. Sustainability. 2020; 12(15):5960. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12155960
Chicago/Turabian StyleYang, Chi-Chun, and Ya-Kai Chang. 2020. "Asymmetric Impact of Financial Intermediary Development in Low- and High-Income Countries" Sustainability 12, no. 15: 5960. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12155960
APA StyleYang, C. -C., & Chang, Y. -K. (2020). Asymmetric Impact of Financial Intermediary Development in Low- and High-Income Countries. Sustainability, 12(15), 5960. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12155960