1. Introduction
In recent years, with the continuous development of globalization and economy, the iterative speed of product updates is gradually accelerating, and the production of a large number of discarded products makes the problems of environmental pollution and resource shortage increasingly serious. How to properly dispose of discarded products has aroused widespread concern in society [
1]. The recycling and remanufacturing of waste products offers an excellent opportunity for social and economic sustainability because it can save 50% of the cost, 60% of the energy, and 70% of the raw materials, and reduce air pollution by 80% [
1,
2,
3]. This also makes enterprises focus not only on the use of forward supply chain for the procurement, production, and sales of new products, but also gradually start to focus on the use of reverse supply chain for the recycling and utilization of waste products, that is, to implement closed-loop supply chain (CLSC) management [
4]. In reality, Fuji Xerox, Ford, IBM, and other enterprises, through the implementation of CLSC management, actively carry out the recycling and remanufacturing of waste products, while achieving good economic benefits, and achieving a wide social reputation [
1,
5,
6]. Therefore, CLSC management can effectively help companies achieve the balance of the triple bottom line of economic, social, and environmental responsibility, and play an important role for companies in achieving global sustainable development [
7].
As is well-known, governments and consumers are focusing more on manufacturers’ recycle and disposal of EOL (end of life) products [
4], and many regulations and directives, such as WEEE Directive of the European Union (waste electrical and electronic equipment Directive), require manufacturers to assume responsibility for proper recycling and disposal of EOL products, which aim to recover the residual value of products as much as possible, reduce environmental implication of EOL products, and minimize the number of final waste products [
8]. However, in many countries, especially emerging developing countries, due to the lack of advanced remanufacturing technology and other reasons, manufacturers generally lack the motivation to participate in the recycling and remanufacturing activities of waste products [
9]. In this context, many national and regional governments are concerned about the recycling and remanufacturing of waste products, and have promulgated a series of laws and regulations to support enterprises in participating in the recycling and remanufacturing of waste products [
10]. Among them government subsidies, as a form of financial incentive, have been implemented in many countries, including China, Sweden, and Germany [
11,
12,
13]. For example, the United States, Japan, and Canada have begun allocating subsidies for the recycling of discarded electronics [
9,
10]. The Chinese government has long offered subsidies to manufacturers to support develop of recycling and remanufacturing activities [
14,
15]. It is clear that the government subsidy mechanism is an important driving force to support recycling and remanufacturing, however, almost all existing studies considering government subsidies or reward and punishment mechanisms ignore the influence of corporate social responsibility (CSR) behaviors of enterprises on decision-making and coordination of CLSC.
In fact, with continuous development of the global economy, how to effectively achieve coordinated development of the economy, society, and the environment has become an important topic of common concern for governments, enterprises, the media, and consumers. Under this background, to achieve long-term development, companies must change the traditional concept of profit as the sole goal in production and operation, and actively take responsibility for consumers, society, and the environment in the process of product production, sales, and distribution, which means fulfilling the corresponding CSR [
16,
17]. With the widespread attention of CSR from all walks of life, CSR has become one of the main influential factors in the strategic decision-making process of enterprises [
18]. More and more well-known international companies such as Apple, Huawei, and Alibaba have started to release CSR reports regularly [
19,
20,
21]. Furthermore, recent studies have shown that CSR behavior of enterprises can not only reduce the operational risk of enterprises and increase the value of enterprises, but also effectively promote the purchase behavior of consumers [
22,
23].
At the same time, from the perspective of supply chain enterprise practice, fulfilling CSR can not only establish a good image for the enterprise, but also effectively improve the company’s marketing power and efficiency in the long run [
24,
25]. For example, Dettol Co. perceived a growth in the sales of Dettol products after the company implemented a CSR-related marketing strategy whereby upon purchase of any of their products a shilling is donated to charity [
26]. Therefore, the company’s CSR strategy helped its products stand out from other products in the market. Moreover, companies donate part of their profits to social welfare organizations as their own CSR investment, which not only helps improve their own performance, but also contributes to the sustainable development of society [
25,
26]. In reality, more and more companies have begun to perform CSR through donation activities, which not only enhances the public image and reputation of the company, but also achieves good economic and social benefits [
26,
27]. For example, Apple implemented a number of large-scale social welfare activities and fulfilled CSR by actively donating to the society. Procter and Gamble stated that the CSR program has helped 280,000 children gain education in India through cumulative donations over the past eight years. Walmart donated
$311.6 million to social and economic development, environmental protection, and hunger issues, fulfilling its CSR and facilitating the good operation of its supply chain [
28]. Similarly, companies such as Google, Intel, and Microsoft also implement CSR through similar donation activities [
29]. These examples illustrate how companies use donations as a core tool for CSR investment.
Integrating CSR into the classic framework of CLSC and considering its impacts on operations of CLSC are meaningful theoretically, empirically, and practically. Therefore, some scholars have begun to discuss the impact of CSR on the operation of CLSC. By combing the existing relevant literature, it can be found that the existing research can be roughly divided into two categories. The first one is from the perspective of CSR macro behavior, and it believes that enterprises can achieve the goal of improving the interests of stakeholders by setting the goal of maximizing social welfare considering consumer surplus, as discussed by Panda et al. [
30], Shu et al. [
31], and so on. Another kind of research is from the perspective of micro-investment, and believes that CSR behavior refers to an investment behavior in which an enterprise spends a certain amount of investment to improve the interests of stakeholders and stimulate consumption at the same time (Ni et al. [
32], Huseh [
17], Modak et al. [
26] and so on).
However, the existing research describes CSR from the perspective of micro-investment generally and regards the CSR investment behavior of enterprises as a pure cost investment behavior similar to advertising or sales efforts, ignoring that many companies began to fulfill CSR through profit donation because profit donation can improve their reputation and create a better public image [
26]. Secondly, the few existing studies on the impact of corporate donation on the operation of CLSC almost all assume that the channel leader is the manufacturer, and usually only consider that the manufacturer makes the CSR investment. In fact, with the rise of Walmart, Suning, and other retail giants, and the development of chain retail, in some industries, retail enterprises have gradually formed as the core of the supply chain partnership [
6,
33]. At the same time, in reality, many retail giants such as Walmart and Carrefour attach great importance to the construction of CSR and have achieved significant results. However, few studies have compared and analyzed the impact of CSR investment behavior of different member enterprises on the operation of CLSC. Thirdly, few existing studies have analyzed the impact of government recycling and remanufacturing subsidy mechanisms on enterprises’ CSR investment behavior of different enterprises and CLSC performance from the perspective of the environmental, economic, and social. Finally, with the promotion and implementation of the extended producer responsibility system in various countries around the world (for example, the state council of China again published the notice of the general office of the state council on printing and distributing the implementation plan of the extended producer responsibility system in 2017), manufacturers are further required to assume more responsibility for the recovery and remanufacturing of waste products. Therefore, it is of great practical significance to study the influence of government subsidies and different CSR investment modes on the decision-making of CLSC with a dominant retailer under the channel structure when the manufacturer is responsible for recycling.
At the same time, decentralized decision-making will lead to the CLSC to produce double marginal effect, so that the overall performance of CLSC cannot reach the level of centralized decision-making. Recently, a variety of coordination contracts are used to improve the overall performance of CLSC, but there are few coordination contracts designed for the CLSC considering CSR investment and government subsidy.
Based on the above research situation, in this paper, we aim to discuss the following issues by distinguishing existing research:
In the CLSC considering government subsidies and CSR investment, when the different CLSC members make donations, what is the impact of the government’s policy of recycling and remanufacturing subsidy on the wholesale and retail prices of new products, recovery rate, the CSR investment level, and channel performance?
Under the government’s subsidy, how does the change of CSR investment (different member enterprises make donations) affect the CLSC pricing decision, CSR investment level, and channel performance? Which is a better decision choice for the subject to donate? Moreover, when consumers’ sensitivity to CSR investment level changes, what impact will it have on CLSC decision making and channel performance?
How to formulate and implement appropriate contracts to effectively improve the performance of CLSC considering government subsidies and CSR investment?
To shed light on these research questions, this paper discusses a single-cycle CLSC consisting of a manufacturer and a dominant retailer considering government subsidy and CSR investment. Meanwhile, we investigate the impact of profit donation as CSR investment and government subsidy from the profit maximization motive. Based on observations from current practices and the extant literature, we consider three different CLSC decision models: (1) The central planner gets the government subsidy, undertakes the product recovery and profit donation under the centralized system (Model C); (2) the manufacturer gets the government subsidy, undertakes the product recovery and profit donation under the decentralized system (Model M); (3) the manufacturer gets the government subsidy and undertakes the product recovery, the retailer undertakes the profit donation under the decentralized system (Model R). We first characterize the optimal equilibrium solutions for the three models and discuss the effects of government subsidies and corporate profit donations on the optimal equilibrium solutions for the different decision models. Then, we systematically compare and analyze the equilibrium solutions under the three decision models. Finally, we design a CSR cost-sharing contract to effectively resolve channel conflicts between the manufacturer and retailer, thereby improving the efficiency of the CLSC.
The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. The next section presents the literature review. In
Section 3, we describe the problem in detail, including assumptions and annotations. The modelling of different structures and solution are provided in
Section 4. The analytical optimal results for the different CLSC structures are presented in
Section 5. In
Section 6, the channel coordination considering CSR cost sharing contract is discussed.
Section 7 illustrates the numerical simulation. We conclude the paper in
Section 8 and point out some possible directions for future research.
5. Equilibrium Result Analysis
In this section, we first analyze the impact of government recycling and remanufacturing subsidies on equivalent variables and profits of CLSCs. Secondly, we analyze the influence of consumer sensitivity to CSR investment on CLSC decision-making and performance. Finally, we compare and analyze the equilibrium variables under different decision models.
Property 1. , .
Property 1 shows that in the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, whether the manufacturer or the retailer makes CSR investment, with the increase of governments’ recycling and remanufacturing subsidy, the manufacturer will not only increase the recycling rate of waste products, but also reduce the wholesale price of new products. In fact, with the increase of government subsidies, regardless of whether the manufacturer has invested in CSR or not, it will try to improve the recycling rate of waste products in order to obtain higher marginal benefits brought by recycling and remanufacturing of waste products. The increase of waste product rate can further reduce the average cost of new products for the manufacturer, so the manufacturer will also reduce the wholesale price of new products to encourage retailers to lower retail prices, aiming to stimulate consumption and further improve the market demand and the recovery rate of waste products, finally achieving the purpose of gaining more income.
Furthermore, with the increase of government subsidies for recycling and remanufacturing, when the retailer makes CSR investment, the wholesale price of new products decreases greatly, and when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, the recycling rate of waste products increases greatly. This is because the government subsidy can also improve the CSR investment level of CLSC (Property 2 indicates that the increase of government subsidy can prompt manufacturer or retailer to increase the CSR investment level), so with the increase of government subsidy for recycling and remanufacturing, the manufacturer’s CSR investment cost will increase with its own CSR investment level. Therefore, in order to make up the cost of increasing CSR investment, the manufacturer will reduce the extent of wholesale price reduction to improve the unit marginal profit. Meanwhile, the manufacturer will make more efforts to improve the recycling rate of waste products to win more subsidies from the government and further reduce the production cost of new products, so as to ensure the increase of its own profits. Therefore, with the increase of the government’s subsidy, compared with the retailer’s CSR investment, the wholesale price reduction of new products is relatively smaller while the recovery rate of waste products is relatively larger under the manufacturer’s CSR investment.
Property 2. , , .
Property 2 shows that in the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, whether manufacturer or retailer makes the CSR investment, with the increase of government subsidy, the retail price of new products will reduce, and the market demand and the level of CSR investment will increase. In fact, with the increase of government subsidy, the manufacturer takes the initiative to lower the wholesale price of new products, and the dominant retailer will lower the retail price of new products to respond to manufacturer and further stimulate consumption. Meanwhile, the profits of manufacturer and retailer are mainly determined by the market demand of new products, and the CSR investment level is the key factor influencing market demand (Wang et al. [
1] also pointed out that CSR behavior of enterprises is an important factor influencing consumers’ purchasing behavior). Therefore, with the increase of government subsidies, both the manufacturer and retailer will increase CSR investment level in order to bring greater market demand.
Furthermore, compared with the dominant retailer’s CSR investment, the retail price of new products decreases more, and the market demand and CSR investment level increase more when the manufacturer makes CSR investment. Actually, as a follower, the manufacturer has relatively weaker bargaining power in the CLSC and is more dependent on market demand. Therefore, with the increase of government subsidies, the manufacturer will be more motivated to increase CSR investment to stimulate consumption and increase market demand so as to ensure the increase of its own profits. At the same time, when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, the retailer as the dominant of CLSC, enjoys more benefits that brought by the CSR investment of manufacturer. Therefore, the retailer will strategically increase the retail price reduction extent at this time to stimulate consumption and increase market demand, so as to encourage the manufacturer to further increase CSR investment level and achieve the purpose of consolidating its own market leadership. Finally, since manufacturers’ CSR investment is accompanied by a larger reduction extent in the price of new products and a larger increase extent in CSR investment, the market demand also has larger increase extent at this time.
Wang et al. [
27] shows that the implementation of CSR subsidy by the government is conducive to improving the recovery rate and CSR investment level. And our research further shows that government subsidy can also improve the recovery rate and CSR investment level. Meanwhile, we find that the recycling decision in the CLSC is inherently consistent with the CSR investment decision, that is, there is no conflict between the economic benefits brought by recycling and remanufacturing and the social benefits brought by CSR investment. Therefore, the internal relationship between the recycling and the CSR investment decision of the CLSC should be taken into account when the members of the CLSC make decisions, so as to achieve the synchronous increase of economic benefits, environmental benefits, and social benefits. This conclusion also provides some reference for the government department to formulate policies on corporate recovery and CSR implementation.
Property 1 and Property 2 jointly reveal that whether the manufacturer or the retailer makes CSR investment, with the increase of government subsidies, it is not only beneficial to reduce the wholesale price and retail price of new products and stimulate consumption, but also to improve the recycling rate of waste products and CSR investment level of CLSC. Furthermore, the government’s policy can achieve the best effect by recycling and remanufacturing subsidy when the manufacturer makes CSR investment.
Property 3. , , . Where, .
Property 3 shows that in the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, whether the manufacturer or the retailer makes CSR investment, the overall profits of the manufacturer, retailer, and whole CLSC will increase with the government’s subsidy. This is because the increase of government subsidies not only enhances the waste product recycling and remanufacturing, but can also effectively improve the CSR investment level of CLSC, thus greatly stimulating consumption and enhancing market demand, therefore, the CLSC members and the whole system can benefit accordingly.
Wan et al. [
9] pointed out that government recycling and remanufacturing subsidy is conducive to increasing the profits of all CLSC members. Meanwhile, we further reveal that in the CLSC with CSR investment by the manufacturer or retailer, the government recycling and remanufacturing subsidy mechanism is not only conducive to improving the recycling rate of waste products and increasing the profits of CLSC members, but also conducive to improving the CSR investment level.
In terms of joint Property 1, 2, and 3, whether the manufacturer or the retailer makes CSR investment, the government subsidy will not only help to reduce the wholesale and retail prices of new products, but also improve the recycling rate of waste products, market demand, and CSR investment level, increasing the profits of CLSC members and the whole system. Therefore, government subsidy is beneficial to consumers, environment, social welfare, and the CLSC members and system as a whole. Moreover, government subsidy policy has the best effect when the manufacturer makes CSR investment.
Property 4. (1) , , , , , (2) , , . Where, .
Property 4 shows that in the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, whether the manufacturer or the retailer makes CSR investment, as the consumers become more sensitive to CSR investment, the wholesale and retail price, market demand, the recovery rate of used product, and CSR investment level will all increase. Meanwhile, the profits of CLSC members and whole system will also increase. This is because whether the manufacturer or retailer makes CSR investment, it will actively increase their CSR investment levels in order to better attract consumers. Since the cost of CSR investment has increased, the manufacturer or retailer will make up for their losses in CSR investment by increasing wholesale or retail prices. However, the rise in wholesale and retail price will not significantly affect consumers’ purchase needs, and consumers are also more willing to pay for companies that actively undertake CSR (in fact, without considering government subsidy mechanisms, Panda et al. [
30] also show that consumers are willing to pay higher prices for products with CSR attributes). At the same time, the increase in market demand for new products and the recovery rate of used products will also increase the profits of CLSC members and whole system.
Property 4 reveals that the CSR investment behavior of manufacturer or retailer increases their own costs, and consumers need to share a certain amount of corporate CSR investment costs, which reduces the effectiveness of consumers in purchasing products to a certain extent. On the whole, the CSR investment behavior of the enterprise has brought higher market demand and the recovery rate of waste products. Therefore, the CSR investment is extremely beneficial to CLSC members, social benefits, and environmental protection.
Proposition 1. In the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, when the manufacturer or retailer makes CSR investment under decentralized decision-making, the wholesale price satisfies.
Proposition 1 shows that in the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, compared with manufacturer makes CSR investment, it is more conducive to reducing the wholesale price of new product when the dominant retailer makes CSR investment. In fact, as the follower of CLSC, the manufacturer already makes less profit than the dominant retailer (Proposition 3 also shows that the dominant retailer always makes more profit than the manufacturer). Therefore, when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, she will relatively increase the wholesale price in order to make up for its own CSR investment cost. On the other hand, the increase in demand caused by the CSR investment in the end will be stronger than the decrease in demand caused by the wholesale price, so it is more advantageous for the manufacturer to set a higher wholesale price at this time.
Proposition 1 reveals that when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, it will increase the wholesale prices compared to the retailer makes CSR investment. At this time, the manufacturer’s CSR investment will have two effects on the demand terminal. On one side, the increase in market demand brought by CSR investment; on the other hand, the decrease in market demand caused by the increase in wholesale prices. And by the analysis of equilibrium solution, it can be found that the effect of increasing CSR investment on demand is stronger than the effect of decreasing demand caused by rising wholesale prices. Therefore, in a retail-oriented CLSC when the manufacturers make CSR investment, it can appropriately increase the wholesale prices to add their own profits.
Proposition 2. In the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, the decision variables in three different models satisfy, , . Consequently, we have.
Proposition 2 shows that in a CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, compared with decentralized decision-making, the retail price of new products is the lowest under centralized decision-making and the recycling rate of waste products, CSR investment level, and market demand are the highest. Under decentralized decision-making, compared with the retailer’s CSR investment, when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, the retail price of new product is lower, the recycling rate of waste products, CSR investment level, and market demand are higher.
In fact, under centralized decision-making, the manufacturer and retailer make decisions as a whole, which effectively eliminates the “double marginal” effect in the CLSC. Therefore, each equilibrium result under centralized decision-making is better than that of decentralized decision-making. Under decentralized decision-making, compared with the dominant retailer, the manufacturer has weaker bargaining power in the CLSC and is more dependent on market demand, so the manufacturer will provide higher CSR investment levels when she makes CSR investments and aims to stimulate consumption more effectively; finally, it can obtain higher profits (Proposition 3 also shows that the profit of manufacturer is greater when the manufacturer makes CSR investment). At the same time, the manufacturer will be more motivated to recycle more used products to reduce production costs and ultimately increase profits. At this time, the retailer as the leader of CLSC fully enjoys the benefits brought by the manufacturer’s CSR investment, so in order to maintain its dominant position, it will provide a relatively low retail price to stimulate consumption and make up for the manufacturer’s CSR investment costs, while achieving the purpose of motivating manufacturer to further increase the CSR investment level.
Proposition 2 reveals that the retailer’s CSR investment will increase its own cost, which will affect the retailer’s pricing strategy for new products. This aspect shows that the CSR investment will bring direct costs to enterprises, but in the long run, it can bring more profits and stable development to enterprises. On the other hand, consumers need to share a certain amount of cost for the company’s CSR investment, but reduce the environmental pollution caused by waste products, so as to increase the company’s profits, and it will bring about larger society welfare.
Modak et al. [
26] pointed out that in the CLSC with a dominant manufacturer, the CSR investment behavior of the dominant manufacturer was conducive to improving the recovery rate of waste product and market demand of new product. We further show that in the retail-led CLSC, the CSR investment of the dominant retailer and manufacturer both are conducive to improving the recovery rate of waste product, CSR investment level, and market demand of new product. Moreover, the manufacturer’s CSR investment is significantly better than retailer’s CSR investment.
Comparing Proposition 1 and Proposition 2, in a CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, when the manufacturer or retailer makes a CSR investment, the changes in wholesale price and retail price of new product are not completely consistent. Specifically, the wholesale price is lower when the retailer makes CSR investment, while the retail price is lower when the manufacturer makes CSR investment. This shows that enterprises will have a certain cost increase due to the CSR investment, so the manufacturer will correspondingly increase the wholesale price when it makes CSR investment, and the retailer will correspondingly increase the retail price when it makes CSR investment. On the other hand, it also shows that in the CLSC, the CSR investment behavior of the enterprises indirectly affects the pricing decision, and that the CSR investment of different entities has different impacts on the pricing decision.
Proposition 3. In the CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, the profits of CLSC members in three different models satisfy, , , . Consequently, we have.
Proposition 3 shows that in a CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, under decentralized decision-making, compared with the retailer making CSR investment, the profit of the manufacturer, retailer, and whole CLSC system are all greater when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, but the total profits of the CLSC system is still lower than that of centralized decision-making. Regardless of whether the retailer makes the CSR investment, the retailer as the leader of CLSC always obtains more profit than the manufacturer. This is because when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, the waste product recovery rate and the demand for new product are relatively large, so the manufacturer, retailer, and CLSC system all make greater profits when the manufacturer makes CSR investment.
From the perspective of CSR conscientiousness, Panda et al. [
30] pointed out that in the CLSC dominated by a manufacturer, the profit of manufacturer will decline due to its CSR behavior. However, from the perspective of CSR investment, we show that in a retail-led CLSC, the CSR investment behavior of manufacturer is more conducive to improving the performance of all CLSC members. This conclusion also provides some reference for the membership in the CLSC to implement CSR in a certain way.
To sum up, in a CLSC considering government subsidy and CSR investment, whether from the perspective of consumers, society, and the environment, or improving the profits of CLSC members, centralized decision-making is better than decentralization. Under decentralized decision-making, compared with the dominant retailer making CSR investment, when the manufacturer makes CSR investment it is more conducive to lowering retail prices, increasing market demand and CSR investment levels. On the other hand, it is more conducive to mitigating the double marginal effects of CLSC, improving the members and overall performance of CLSC, and promoting the long-term stable development of CLSC. At this time, the implementation of government recycling and remanufacturing subsidy mechanisms is more effective when the manufacturer makes CSR investment. Therefore, the government departments can guide the dominant retailer to jointly formulate reasonable pricing strategies to encourage the manufacturer to increase CSR investment level, which is extremely beneficial to consumer, social benefits, environmental protection, the CLSC members, and whole system.
6. Channel Coordination
Through the analysis in the previous section of this paper, it is found that under decentralized decision making, regardless of the CSR investment of manufacturer or retailer, the profits of the entire CLSC system can be improved to a certain extent, and compared with the retailer’s CSR investment, when the manufacturers makes CSR investment it is more conducive to increasing the total profits of the CLSC, but it still cannot reach the optimal level under centralized decision-making. Therefore, it is necessary to design a reasonable contract to coordinate the CLSC when the manufacturer makes CSR investment, so as to reach the optimal level under centralized decision-making.
In this section, we will design a CSR cost sharing contract
to achieve the coordination of CLSC when the manufacturer makes CSR investment. The specific steps are: Primarily, the dominant retailer cannot only enjoy the benefits brought by the manufacturer’s investment, and should take the initiative to bear a certain CSR investment cost for the manufacturer (
,
) and reduce the retail price to the centralized decision-making level, and to encourage the manufacturer to increase the level of CSR investment and waste product recovery rate to reach the level of centralized decision-making. At the same time, the manufacturer re-offers a new wholesale price
to respond to retailers’ aggressive price decreases. Therefore, under this CSR cost sharing contract, the profit functions of manufacturer and retailer can be expressed as (use “MS” to represent the coordination model when manufacturer makes CSR investment under government’s subsidy)
Proposition 4. When the CSR cost sharing contract parameters satisfy, , the CSR cost sharing contract can fully realize the coordination of CLSC, where, , , , . Further, the profits of the manufacturer and the retailer under the contract can be obtained as, . Where, , . Let, , . Under the assumption of scale parameters, .
Proposition 4 shows that the CSR cost sharing contract can effectively achieve the coordination of the CLSC. The retail price of new products, CSR investment level, waste product recovery rate, and market demand under the contract are the same as the optimal decision under centralized decision, and the total profits of the CLSC system has reached the level under centralized decision. At the same time, under this CSR cost sharing contract, there is a range for the retailer’s share of the CSR cost of the manufacturer, and the specific commitment ratio can be negotiated between the manufacturer and the retailer. Contrary to intuition, when the retailer bears a high proportion of CSR costs (when it is small), the dominant retailer can use the leadership position to obtain all the incremental profits brought by coordination, and the manufacturer can only obtain retained profits under decentralized decision-making, but at this time the recovery rate of waste products and CSR investment levels have been improved, which is beneficial to consumers, the environment, and the CLSC system.
Furthermore, in the current economic environment, CSR investments by companies are not only related to their own interests, but also to the overall performance of other members and entire CLSCs. Therefore, as the leader of CLSC, the retailer takes the initiative to bear certain CSR investment costs for the manufacturer, which is not only conducive to better fulfillment of CSR in CLSC, but also to their own development and can bring more social and environmental benefits. For example, HP (Hewlett-Packard) has taken the initiative to bear certain CSR investment costs for its manufacturers, which not only increased the CSR investment level, but also improved the supply chain performance [
60].