Optimal Pricing Strategy and Government Consumption Subsidy Policy in Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Third-Party Remanufacturer
Abstract
:1. Introduction
- Under what conditions should the government offer a consumption subsidy of remanufactured products?
- How does the consumption subsidy policy affect the firm’s decisions?
- Will consumption subsidies of remanufactured products incentivize consumers to purchase the remanufactured products? Will the consumption subsidy policy cannibalize new product sales?
- What benefits or costs can consumption subsidy policies bring to firms, consumers and society?
2. Literature Review
2.1. Pricing Strategy for Closed-Loop Supply Chains
2.2. Government Policy of Closed-Loop Supply Chains
3. Model Development
- All of the recycled used products can be used for remanufacturing, and is the same for all of the used products.
- . Let , which denotes unit cost savings for remanufacturing. This assumption guarantees that remanufacturing is profitable [60].
- When consumers chooses to purchase the remanufactured product from the TPR, they can obtain a consumption subsidy () from government.
- There is a substitution relationship between the new products and the remanufactured product [26]. is the demand function, which is defined by the sales price of the new product, the cross price competition and the consumption subsidy:Similarly, can be defined as follows:
- In the above definition, we assume that , which means that the market demand is more sensitive to its own sales price than to the sales price of its substitutable product. In addition, we assume , which indicates that a consumer’s acceptance of new products is relatively higher than that of remanufactured products [26].
- The consumer surplus for the new product and the remanufactured product [61] can be computed and expressed as:, respectively.
- Consumer surplus for the recycled product [61], i.e., the difference between the recycling price and the fee level that consumers are willing to pay to bring their used products to remanufacturers can be expressed as .
- The TPR is a rational decision maker that wants to maximize its profit and will set the price so that would be lower than the supply , i.e., .
- A product can be recycled unlimited times.
- Both the OEM and TPR have ample capacity to meet demand for new products and to remanufacture all of the recycled product, respectively. Therefore, all demand can be satisfied.
- OEM and TPR supply chains are disruption-free and the cost of recovery from disruption is negligible [62].
4. Basic Model without Government Consumption Subsidy (Model I)
5. Model with Government Consumption Subsidy (Model Ⅱ)
- and increase in .
- and increase in .
6. Comparisons with Managerial Implications
- (i)
- Increases in ;
- (ii)
- Increases in ;
- (iii)
- Decreases asincreases;
- (iv)
- Decreases asincreases.
- (i)
- The consumption subsidy reduces the consumer’s net payment for the remanufactured product;
- (ii)
- The consumption subsidy will be shared between the consumers of the remanufactured product and the TPR;
- (iii)
- For remanufactured products, ;
- (iv)
- For the demand for remanufactured products:
- i.
- For new products, ;
- ii.
- For the demand for new products, ;
- iii.
- For used product ;
- iv.
- The total demand increases due to the consumption subsidy, that is, .
- (1)
- For the TPR’s profit, if , where , ; otherwise, ;
- (2)
- For the OEM’s profit, if , where ; otherwise, ;
- (3)
- For the CLSC’s profit, if , where , , otherwise, .
7. Numerical Examples
7.1. Parameter Design
7.2. The Conditions of the Government’s Consumption Subsidy Policy
7.3. Impact of Remanufacturing Cost () on CLSC
- When the remanufacturing cost rises, the optimal government consumption subsidy declines.
- increases with , while , and the recycled quantity of the used product, with or without a consumption subsidy, decrease with , and (corresponding to in Corollary 7), (corresponding to in Corollary 7) and (corresponding to in Corollary 7), suggesting that the consumption subsidy policy increases the TPR’s profit and the total supply chain profit, and decreases the OEM’s profit. High product remanufacturability and a government consumption subsidy policy are strong incentives for the TPR to recycle used products and remanufacture.
- The optimal price of the new product and the net payment for the remanufactured product increase with , with or without a consumption subsidy. If the government offers the consumption subsidy, the optimal price of the new product and the net payment for the remanufactured product will be reduced, while the optimal price of the remanufactured product will be raised. These results match those in Corollaries 1, 2, 5(iii) and 6(i), suggesting that the effort to lower the remanufacturing cost could not only positively influence the net payment for the remanufactured product, but also the new product’s price.
- With rising , the demand for remanufactured products declines gradually, with or without a consumption subsidy. Additionally, the demand for remanufactured products increases when the government offers the consumption subsidy. These results suggest that the demand for remanufactured product can be improved by the TPR decreasing the remanufactured cost or the government providing the consumption subsidy, which validates Corollary 5(iv).
- The demand for new products increases with , with or without a consumption subsidy. The demand for new products with a consumption subsidy is lower than that without a consumption subsidy, suggesting that the consumption subsidy cannibalizes the new product’s demand, which validates Corollary 6(ii).
- The consumer surplus follows the order of , and the social welfare follows the order of . These results demonstrate that the consumption subsidy is beneficial to both consumers and society.
- With or without a consumption subsidy, the quantity of used products recycled decreases with , meaning that high remanufacturability induces the TPR to recycle more used products. The quantity of used products recycled with a consumption subsidy is higher than that without a consumption subsidy, suggesting that the consumption subsidy could enhance the environmental performance.
7.4. Impact of on CLSC
- The government consumption subsidy decreases with when
- , and decrease with (corresponding to ), while (corresponding to in Corollary 7), (corresponding to in Corollary 7) and (corresponding to in Corollary 7). These results show that the consumption subsidy policy increases the TPR’s profit and the total supply chain profit, while it decreases the OEM’s profit; when the consumer acceptance of remanufactured products increases, the growth in the TPR’s profit and in the total supply chain’s profit decreases, suggesting that the efficiency of the consumption subsidy policy declines when the consumer’s acceptance of the remanufactured product improves.
- The optimal price of the new product and the net payment for the remanufactured product increase with , with or without a consumption subsidy. If the government offers the consumption subsidy, the optimal price of the new product and the net payment for the remanufactured product will be reduced. These results mean that the consumer acceptance of the remanufactured product could positively influence the price of the new product and that of the remanufactured product.
- With rising (corresponding to ), demand for remanufactured products without a consumption subsidy declines gradually, while that with a consumption subsidy first increases and then declines. Demand for remanufactured products increases when the government offers the consumption subsidy. These results suggest that demand for remanufactured products can be improved by consumers improving the acceptance of remanufactured products or the government providing the consumption subsidy policy.
- Demand for new products increases with , with or without a consumption subsidy, suggesting that the competition from the remanufactured product is beneficial for the sales of the new product. The demand for new products with a consumption subsidy is lower than that without a consumption subsidy, verifying the consumption subsidy’s effect of cannibalization of the new product’s demand.
- The consumer surplus follows the order of , and the social welfare follows the order of . These results demonstrate that the consumption subsidy is beneficial to both consumers and society.
- The quantity of used product recycled, with or without a consumption subsidy, increases with , suggesting that high consumer acceptance of remanufactured products encourages the TPR to recycle more used products, which leads to an improvement of environmental performance. The quantity of used product recycled with a consumption subsidy is higher than that without a consumption subsidy, suggesting that the consumption subsidy could enhance the environmental performance.
8. Conclusions
- The government should implement the consumption subsidy policy only when certain conditions are satisfied.
- We derived the optimal consumption subsidy policy for the government and the optimal pricing strategy for the OEM and TPR. These results are valuable as they provide practical guidance and insights for governments and enterprises to maximize their own objectives.
- Both the remanufacturing cost and the substitution degree between new products and remanufactured products can significantly impact the government’s consumption subsidy policy providing decision. A low remanufacturing cost and low consumers’ acceptance of remanufactured product are crucial for incentivizing the government to offer the consumption subsidy policy.
- The consumption subsidy policy could motivate the consumers to buy more remanufactured products while cannibalizing the market of new products.
- Although the consumption subsidy policy cannibalizes the new product sales, it is not always harmful to the OEM. The OEM could gain more profit under the consumption subsidy when certain conditions are satisfied.
- The consumption subsidy prompts the OEM to decrease the sales price of the new product. The consumption subsidy will be shared between the TPR and consumers while the TPR raises the sales price of the remanufactured product.
- The consumption subsidy does not always improve the firm’s profit, consumer surplus and social welfare.
- Our models consider a duopolistic setting in which the OEM only manufactures new products and the TPR only remanufactures remanufactured products. It is worth studying the duopolistic setting in which the OEM also takes back used products to restrict the capacities of the TPR.
- Our models only consider the price competition between new products and remanufactured products; insights would be gained by expanding our models to incorporate quality competition or warranty competition.
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Appendix A.1. Proof of Proposition 1
Appendix A2. Proof of Proposition 2
Appendix A3. Proof of Corollary 1
Appendix A4. Proof of Proposition 3
Appendix A5. Proof of Proposition 4
Appendix A6. Proof of Corollary 2
Appendix A7. Proof of Corollary 3
Appendix A8. Proof of Corollary 5
Appendix A9. Proof of Corollary 6
Appendix A10. Proof of Corollary 7
Appendix A11. Proof of the Impact of on Optimal Decisions of CLSC Members, Government Decision and So On
Appendix A12. Proof of the Impact of on the Optimal Decisions of CLSC Members, Government Decisions and So On
References
- Dotoli, M.; Fanti, M.P.; Meloni, C.; Zhou, M.C. A multi-level approach for network design of integrated supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Res. 2005, 43, 4267–4287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dotoli, M.F.; Fanti, M.P.; Meloni, C.; Zhou, M.C. Design and optimization of integrated e-supply chain for agile and environmentally conscious manufacturing. IEEE Trans. Syst. Man Cybern. 2006, 36, 62–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, C.-H. Price and service competition between new and remanufactured products in a two-echelon supply chain. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2012, 140, 496–507. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Govindan, K.; Madan Shankar, K.; Kannan, D. Application of fuzzy analytic network process for barrier evaluation in automotive parts remanufacturing towards cleaner production—A study in an Indian scenario. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 114, 199–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Han, X.; Yang, Q.; Shang, J.; Pu, X. Optimal strategies for trade-old-for-remanufactured programs: Receptivity, durability, and subsidy. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 193, 602–616. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, X.; Govindan, K.; Xu, L.; Du, P. Quantity and collection decisions in a closed-loop supply chain with technology licensing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2017, 256, 820–829. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wan, N.; Hong, D. The impacts of subsidy policies and transfer pricing policies on the closed-loop supply chain with dual collection channels. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 224, 881–891. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, X.; Wang, M.; Chen, G.; Chen, X. The effect of implementing trade-in strategy on duopoly competition. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2016, 248, 856–868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, W.-m.; Zhao, Z.; Ke, H. Dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government consumption-subsidy. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2013, 226, 221–227. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Hazen, B.T.; Mollenkopf, D.A. Consumer value considerations and adoption of remanufactured products in closed-loop supply chains. Ind. Manag. Data Syst. 2018, 118, 480–498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, X.; Wang, Z.; Wang, Y.; Li, B. Incentive policy options for product remanufacturing: Subsidizing donations or resales? Int. J. Environ. Res. Public Health 2017, 14, 1496. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Zhu, Q.; Sarkis, J.; Lai, K.-H. Supply chain-based barriers for truck-engine remanufacturing in China. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2014, 68, 103–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ma, Z.-J.; Zhou, Q.; Dai, Y.; Sheu, J.-B. Optimal pricing decisions under the coexistence of “trade old for new” and “trade old for remanufactured” programs. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2017, 106, 337–352. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- He, P.; He, Y.; Xu, H. Channel structure and pricing in a dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with government subsidy. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 213, 108–123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shu, T.; Peng, Z.; Chen, S.; Wang, S.; Lai, K.; Yang, H. Government subsidy for remanufacturing or carbon tax rebate: Which is better for firms and a low-carbon economy. Sustainability 2017, 9, 156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ferrer, G.; Swaminathan, J.M. Managing new and remanufactured products. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 15–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ferrer, G.; Swaminathan, J.M. Managing new and differentiated remanufactured products. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 203, 370–379. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Atasu, A.; Sarvary, M.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Remanufacturing as a marketing strategy. Manag. Sci. 2008, 54, 1731–1746. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Abbey, J.D.; Blackburn, J.D.; Guide, V.D.R. Optimal pricing for new and remanufactured products. J. Oper. Manag. 2015, 36, 130–146. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, C.-H. Strategic and operational decisions under sales competition and collection competition for end-of-use products in remanufacturing. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 169, 11–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, C.-H.; Wu, H.-H. Competitive remanufacturing strategy and take-back decision with OEM remanufacturing. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2016, 98, 149–163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, J.; Wei, J.; Li, M. Collecting channel choice and optimal decisions on pricing and collecting in a remanufacturing supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 167, 530–544. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, X.; Xu, L.; Du, P.; Wang, W. Joint advertising, pricing and collection decisions in a closed-loop supply chain. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2015, 167, 12–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, X.; Zhang, H.; Zhong, Q.; Liu, L. Optimal decisions of a hybrid manufacturing-remanufacturing system within a closed-loop supply chain. Eur. J. Ind. Eng. 2016, 10, 21–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wei, J.; Govindan, K.; Li, Y.; Zhao, J. Pricing and collecting decisions in a closed-loop supply chain with symmetric and asymmetric information. Comput. Oper. Res. 2015, 54, 257–265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, C.-T.; Ren, M.-L. Closed-loop supply chain coordination strategy for the remanufacture of patented products under competitive demand. Appl. Math. Model. 2016, 40, 6243–6255. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xie, J.; Liang, L.; Liu, L.; Ieromonachou, P. Coordination contracts of dual-channel with cooperation advertising in closed-loop supply chains. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 183, 528–538. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gan, S.-S.; Pujawan, I.N.; Suparno; Widodo, B. Pricing decision for new and remanufactured product in a closed-loop supply chain with separate sales-channel. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2017, 190, 120–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Li, W.; Wu, H.; Jin, M.; Lai, M. Two-stage remanufacturing decision makings considering product life cycle and consumer perception. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 161, 581–590. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Liu, Z.; Chen, J.; Diallo, C. Optimal production and pricing strategies for a remanufacturing firm. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2018, 204, 290–315. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kleber, R.; Reimann, M.; Souza, G.C.; Zhang, W. On the robustness of the consumer homogeneity assumption with respect to the discount factor for remanufactured products. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2018, 269, 1027–1040. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zhao, J.; Wang, C.; Xu, L. Decision for pricing, service, and recycling of closed-loop supply chains considering different remanufacturing roles and technology authorizations. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2019, 132, 59–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wu, X.; Zhou, Y. Buyer-specific versus uniform pricing in a closed-loop supply chain with third-party remanufacturing. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2019, 273, 548–560. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, N.; He, Q.; Jiang, B. Hybrid closed-loop supply chains with competition in recycling and product markets. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2019, 217, 246–258. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, W.; He, Y. Optimal policies for new and green remanufactured short-life-cycle products considering consumer behavior. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 214, 483–505. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, W.; Ding, J.; Sun, H. Reward-penalty mechanism for a two-period closed-loop supply chain. J. Clean. Prod. 2018, 203, 898–917. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Webster, S.; Mitra, S. Competitive strategy in remanufacturing and the impact of take-back laws. J. Oper. Manag. 2007, 25, 1123–1140. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Mitra, S.; Webster, S. Competition in remanufacturing and the effects of government subsidies. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2008, 111, 287–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, K.; Zhao, Y.; Cheng, Y.; Choi, T.-M. Cooperation or competition? Channel choice for a remanufacturing fashion supply chain with government subsidy. Sustainability 2014, 6, 7292–7310. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wang, Y.; Chang, X.; Chen, Z.; Zhong, Y.; Fan, T. Impact of subsidy policies on recycling and remanufacturing using system dynamics methodology: A case of auto parts in China. J. Clean. Prod. 2014, 74, 161–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hong, I.-H.; Lee, Y.-T.; Chang, P.-Y. Socially optimal and fund-balanced advanced recycling fees and subsidies in a competitive forward and reverse supply chain. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2014, 82, 75–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Heydari, J.; Govindan, K.; Jafari, A. Reverse and closed loop supply chain coordination by considering government role. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2017, 52, 379–398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, S.; Zhu, Q.; Cui, L. A decision-making model for remanufacturers: Considering both consumers’ environmental preference and the government subsidy policy. Resour. Conserv. Recycl. 2018, 128, 176–186. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Guo, J.; He, L.; Gen, M. Optimal strategies for the closed-loop supply chain with the consideration of supply disruption and subsidy policy. Comput. Ind. Eng. 2019, 128, 886–893. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cao, K.; He, P.; Liu, Z. Production and pricing decisions in a dual-channel supply chain under remanufacturing subsidy policy and carbon tax policy. J. Oper. Res. Soc. 2019, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miao, Z.; Fu, K.; Xia, Z.; Wang, Y. Models for closed-loop supply chain with trade-ins. Omega 2017, 66, 308–326. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cao, K.; Bo, Q.; He, Y. Optimal trade-in and third-party collection authorization strategies under trade-in subsidy policy. Kybernetes 2018, 47, 854–872. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, F.; Zhang, R. Trade-in remanufacturing, customer purchasing behavior, and government policy. Manuf. Serv. Oper. Manag. 2018, 20, 601–616. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhao, L.; Chang, J.; Du, J. Dynamics analysis on competition between manufacturing and remanufacturing in context of government subsidies. Chaos Solitons Fractals 2019, 121, 119–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xiao, L.; Wang, X.-J.; Chin, K.-S. Trade-in strategies in retail channel and dual-channel closed-loop supply chain with remanufacturing. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2020, 136, 101898. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shu, T.; Huang, C.; Chen, S.; Wang, S.; Lai, K.K. Trade-old-for-remanufactured closed-loop supply chains with carbon tax and government subsidies. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3935. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Miao, Z.; Mao, H.; Fu, K.; Wang, Y. Remanufacturing with trade-ins under carbon regulations. Comput. Oper. Res. 2018, 89, 253–268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, X.; Wang, M. Optimal pricing strategy of a hybrid trade old for new and remanufactured products supply chain. Optim. Lett. 2018, 1–17. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nielsen, I.E.; Majumder, S.; Saha, S. Game-theoretic analysis to examine how government subsidy policies affect a closed-loop supply chain decision. Appl. Sci. 2020, 10, 145. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chakraborty, K.; Mondal, S.; Mukherjee, K. Critical analysis of enablers and barriers in extension of useful life of automotive products through remanufacturing. J. Clean. Prod. 2019, 227, 1117–1135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Örsdemir, A.; Kemahlıoglu-Ziya, E.; Parlakturk, A.K. Competitive quality choice and remanufacturing. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2014, 23, 48–64. [Google Scholar]
- Zou, Z.-B.; Wang, J.-J.; Deng, G.-S.; Chen, H. Third-party remanufacturing mode selection: Outsourcing or authorization? Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2016, 87, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Savaskan, R.C.; Bhattacharya, S.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Closed-loop supply chain models with product remanufacturing. Manag. Sci. 2004, 50, 239–252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hua, G.; Wang, S.; Cheng, T.C.E. Price and lead time decisions in dual-channel supply chains. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 205, 113–126. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, W.; Wu, H.; Deng, R. Decision-making based on consumers’ perceived value in different remanufacturing modes. Discret. Dyn. Nat. Soc. 2015, 2015, 278210. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Hong, I.H.; Ke, J.-S. Determining advanced recycling fees and subsidies in “E-scrap” reverse supply chains. J. Environ. Manag. 2011, 92, 1495–1502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Iris, Ç.; Lam, J.S.L. Recoverable robustness in weekly berth and quay crane planning. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2019, 122, 365–389. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Savaskan, R.C.; Van Wassenhove, L.N. Reverse channel design: The case of competing retailers. Manag. Sci. 2006, 52, 1–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Souza, G.C. Closed-loop supply chains: A critical review, and future research. Decis. Sci. 2013, 44, 7–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Iris, C.; Asan, S.S. A review of genetic algorithm applications in supply chain network design. In Computational Intelligence Systems in Industrial Engineering; Kahraman, C., Ed.; Atlantis Press Book: Paris, France, 2012; pp. 203–230. [Google Scholar]
- Qu, Y.; Yu, Y.; Appolloni, A.; Li, M.R.; Liu, Y. Measuring green growth efficiency for Chinese manufacturing industries. Sustainability 2017, 9, 637. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Testa, F.; Nucci, B.; Iraldo, F.; Appolloni, A.; Daddi, T. Removing obstacles to the implementation of LCA among SMEs: A collecting strategy for exploiting recycled wool. J. Clean. Prod. 2017, 156, 923–931. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Parameter | Definition |
---|---|
Unit manufacturing cost | |
Unit remanufacturing cost | |
Unit recycling price of used product | |
Basic collected quantity of zero reward money | |
Recycling price elasticity coefficient of used product | |
Unit sales price of new product | |
Unit sales price of remanufactured product | |
Unit consumption subsidy for consumers who purchase the remanufactured product | |
Potential market size of new product | |
Potential market size of remanufactured product | |
Price elasticity coefficient | |
Substitution coefficient | |
Original equipment manufacturer, third-party remanufacturer, the supply chain | |
Demand volume of new product, demand volume of remanufactured product | |
Quantity of used product recycled | |
Consumer surplus for new product, consumer surplus for remanufactured product, consumer surplus for recycled product |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Meng, L.; Qiang, Q.; Huang, Z.; Zhang, B.; Yang, Y. Optimal Pricing Strategy and Government Consumption Subsidy Policy in Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Third-Party Remanufacturer. Sustainability 2020, 12, 2411. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12062411
Meng L, Qiang Q, Huang Z, Zhang B, Yang Y. Optimal Pricing Strategy and Government Consumption Subsidy Policy in Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Third-Party Remanufacturer. Sustainability. 2020; 12(6):2411. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12062411
Chicago/Turabian StyleMeng, Lijun, Qiang Qiang, Zuqing Huang, Baoyou Zhang, and Yuxiang Yang. 2020. "Optimal Pricing Strategy and Government Consumption Subsidy Policy in Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Third-Party Remanufacturer" Sustainability 12, no. 6: 2411. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12062411
APA StyleMeng, L., Qiang, Q., Huang, Z., Zhang, B., & Yang, Y. (2020). Optimal Pricing Strategy and Government Consumption Subsidy Policy in Closed-Loop Supply Chain with Third-Party Remanufacturer. Sustainability, 12(6), 2411. https://doi.org/10.3390/su12062411