1. Introduction
In this paper, we examine the impact of two key attributes—the degree of adoption of renewable energy resources by a country, and whether high country environmental sustainability ratings alter two well-established relationships between: (a) gross domestic product per capita (GDP) and CO2 emissions per capita (CO2)—the environmental Kuznets curve), and (b) foreign direct investment net inflows (FDI) and CO2 (the pollution haven hypothesis). As a secondary objective, we also examine whether the degree of host country urbanization affects pollution in these countries and whether the degree of economic development impacts these relationships. We believe that to the best of our knowledge, the literature does not examine the impact of these intervening variables on the well-established relationships documented earlier, especially for low and middle-income countries.
There are persistent attempts to reduce global pollution by encouraging global industries and countries to adopt renewable energy sources [
1,
2,
3,
4,
5,
6,
7,
8,
9,
10,
11]. Research also documents that these attempts have been successful mostly in developed countries. Studies indicate a negative renewable energy/CO
2 relationship in EU countries [
2], and in Malaysia [
1], while others find no relationship for Turkey [
12]. Furthermore, recent evidence suggests that renewable energy adoption can successfully reduce pollution, at least in high-income countries [
13]. Clearly, these results imply that the benefits of adoption of renewable energy sources may only extend to high-income countries and not to developing countries. However, despite recent literature on the renewable energy/CO
2 relationship, there seems to be ambiguity on the exact nature of this relationship as it pertains to the impact of renewable energy adoption on the environmental Kuznets curve and the pollution haven hypothesis, especially for low-and middle-income countries.
There is also extensive literature documenting the complex relationship between environmental pollution and GDP in host countries. While the literature adopts both linear and non-linear methodologies, there seems to be a consensus that the relationship between CO
2 based pollution and GDP is inherently complex. For instance, economic growth levels of host countries matter: during the early (later) stages of economic growth, pollution output is associated positively (negatively) with GDP and is the environmental Kuznets curve [
14,
15,
16,
17,
18,
19,
20,
21,
22,
23,
24,
25,
26,
27,
28]. Overall, the nature (and significance) of this relationship seems to depend on whether the sample country is developed or developing as well as on the selected time-period for examination. In this study, we introduce several new wrinkles: is this relationship impacted if the developing country adopts renewable energy sources? Studies involving high-income countries indicate that use of renewable energy can reduce carbon dioxide-based pollution. Do these results also extend to developing countries? To the best of our knowledge, this question has not been empirically examined in the literature. This is the first research question addressed in this study.
Next, extant literature suggests that FDI into host countries gravitates from countries with strict environment regulations into countries with lax environmental regulations, referred to as the pollution haven hypothesis [
29,
30,
31,
32,
33,
34,
35,
36,
37,
38,
39,
40,
41,
42]. Similarly, the pollution halo hypothesis contends that developing countries attract FDI from higher technology/high standard production process multinational firms, thereby potentially reducing host country CO
2 emissions [
43,
44,
45]. In this study, we contend that if host countries can reduce CO
2 emissions by attracting firms making ‘cleaner’ investments, then the pollution haven relationship may be affected. Countries can signal their willingness to accept clean FDI (as well as their desire to use renewable energy sources) via the published environmental sustainability ratings. In this paper, we ask whether environmental sustainability ratings and renewable energy usage also alter the pollution haven/halo hypotheses. This is the second research question addressed in this study.
Finally, a significant third strand of literature examines how the degree of host country urbanization affects CO
2 emissions. Empirical results using both linear and nonlinear methodology are mixed: some find a positive relationship [
46,
47] while others document a negative relationship. Another segment suggests that country development levels matter [
48]: a positive (negative) relationship is documented for low/middle (upper middle and high) income countries. Still more find complex relationships between the two variables emerge [
49,
50] and still others find no relationship [
51]. Based on these results, the degree of urbanization (particularly in developing countries) has the potential to alter the relationship between CO
2 and host country GDP. This is the third research question addressed in this study.
Formally, this study will explore the impact of the adoption of renewable energy sources and the impact of urbanization on the environmental Kuznets curve and the pollution haven hypothesis for a sample of high-end and low-end middle-income countries for data over the 2005–2014 period. The empirical results presented here can enable us to better understand the impact of renewable energy adoption on the pollution/GDP relationship and the factors that influence foreign direct investment net inflows. Policy wise, are countries better off if they use renewable energy sources? If developing countries adopt renewable energy sources and possess high environmental sustainability ratings, then there is potential to lower pollution and attract non-polluting foreign direct investment net inflows. In turn, these developments can increase GDP while reducing pollution—a very desirable outcome. We believe that there is paucity of research relating renewable adoption and environmental sustainability ratings to the well-established relationships referenced above, especially for low and middle-income countries.
Formally, the research questions addressed in this study are as follows:
- (a)
Does the adoption of renewable energy sources alter the environmental Kuznets curve relationship and the pollution haven relationship for low- and middle-income sample countries?
- (b)
Does the adoption of strong environmental sustainability ratings by host countries assist in reducing pollution while attracting non-pollution inflows into low and middle-income countries?
- (c)
Does the degree of urbanization alter the relationships of interest?
The paper is organized as follows. The literature review in
Section 2 is followed by sample description in
Section 3. The adopted research methodology and empirical results are presented in
Section 4. Discussion of results in
Section 5 is followed by conclusion in
Section 6.
2. Literature Review
2.1. Literature Related to the Validity of the Environmental Kuznets Curve
The extant literature documents a confusing array of linear and non-linear relationships between GDP and CO
2 in host countries. For instance, using nonlinear OLS models, Tucker documents evidence that GDP and CO
2 emissions were positively related for a group of low, middle, and high-income countries [
52]. In contrast, other researchers document a plethora of complex relationships involving the variables of interest. For instance, using nonlinear methodology, Onafowora and Owoye detect an inverted “U” shape relationship for Japan and Korea (developed countries), and an “N” shape for developing countries (Brazil, China, Egypt, Mexico, Nigeria, and South Africa [
53]). More recently, and using nonlinear methodology, Apergis document an inverted U shape relationship for 12 of 15 developed countries while controlling for their development growth over the 1960–2010 period [
54]. Similarly, and using a nonlinear methodology, Youssef, Hammoudeh, and Omri document that an inverted U shape exists for 56 sample countries that accommodate high-, middle-, and low-income countries in the sample [
55].
Finally, using OECD country data and nonlinear methodology, Churchill et al. found that the precise shape of the relationship is sample specific [
56]. Similarly, using data from eight OECD countries, Isik et al. found that the environmental Kuznets curve (EKC) hypothesis is supported for data from four of eight sample countries by the undecomposed GDP, but not by the decomposed GDP [
18]. Next, using data from five emerging countries (Brazil, India, China, South Africa, and Turkey), Dogan et al. also found that the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis is not supported when considering environmental degradation [
19].
Overall, it appears that the data show preference for nonlinear methodology, presumably because it best captures the underling complex relationship. Furthermore, the exact economic development/CO2 relationship seems to depend on sample periods/countries.
2.2. Does Urbanization Impact the CO2 Emissions/Economic Development Relationship?
Another literature stream examines how the degree of host country urbanization affects CO
2 and on whether this relationship depends on the degree of economic development of host countries. Several studies (using linear models) document that urbanization positively influences CO
2 in sample countries [
46,
47] while others have found a negative relationship [
57]. Another segment suggests that the impact of urbanization on CO
2 depends on the degree of economic development of the host country. For instance, the impact of urbanization on CO
2 differs depending on the level of economic development of host countries [
48]. Both researchers find a positive CO
2/urbanization relationship in low and middle-income countries but a negative CO
2/urbanization relationship in the upper middle and high-income countries. Results are similarly mixed when nonlinear models are used. Some document an inverted U relationship for some developing country targets [
49,
50], while others find no relationship using emerging country data [
51]. Clearly, the degree of urbanization in developing countries has the potential to alter the relationship between CO
2 and host country GDP. Recent evidence seems to favor a nonlinear formulation over the linear one and indicate that the relationship may be inherently nonlinear.
2.3. FDI and CO2 Emissions
The link between FDI and CO
2 remains empirically uncertain. Clear evidence suggests FDI from pollution strict countries gravitate towards countries with lax pollution control countries [
31,
32,
33,
34,
36,
40,
58]. This is the pollution haven hypothesis. Furthermore, some host countries attract FDI from higher technology/high standard production process multinational firms, which can reduce host country CO
2 [
43,
44,
45]. This is the pollution halo hypothesis. However, Bulus and Koc find that there is no significant relationship between FDI and CO
2 in Korea [
39].
If host countries can reduce CO2 by attracting firms making ‘cleaner’ investments, then this influences the pollution haven hypothesis. If host countries promote renewable energy, then this can alter well-established relationships between GDP, economic development, CO2, host country urbanization levels, and FDI.
2.4. Renewable Energy Adoption in High, Middle-, and Low-Income Developing Countries
Research documents a negative renewable energy/CO
2 relationship in EU countries [
2], in Malaysia [
1], and in Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece, and Spain [
11]. However, others find no relationship for Turkey [
12]. Recent evidence suggests that renewable energy consumption is negatively associated with CO
2 only for the high-income country subsamples [
13]. In contrast, unlike the results reported for high-income countries, the renewable energy consumption/CO
2 relationship is documented to be an inverted N curve in the short run in Egypt [
10]. However, Gyamfi et al. found no relationship between renewable energy consumption and CO
2 in the short run in Brazil, China, India, Indonesia, Mexico, Russia, and Turkey [
9]. Taken together, these results imply that the benefits of adoption of renewable energy sources may only extend to high-income countries and not to low-income countries.
2.5. High Environmental Sustainability Ratings on Pollution in Middle and Low-Income Developing Countries
Environmental policies can encourage renewable energy consumption, subsequently generating sustainable economic development [
59]. Renewable energy adoption can negatively impact CO
2 while positively influencing local income, energy security, social economics, and the environment [
60]. Low and middle-income countries may face socio-economic and other barriers towards adoption of renewable energy resources. Consequently, enforced government environmental policy prescriptions can reduce perceived/actual barriers towards renewable energy adoption [
61]. Low/middle-income countries with strong special-interest groups do hinder CO
2 reduction efforts [
62,
63]. In contrast, high-income countries receive support from private/public stakeholders for use of renewable energy to reduce pollution while maintaining long-run economic growth [
60]. Le, Chang, and Park show that proper governmental environmental policies can reduce CO
2 but only in high-income countries [
13]. Finally, Sys et al. show that petrochemical lobbies shape government environmental regulation policies to inhibit the use of renewable energy in these countries [
64]. Others argue that coordination between environmental regulatory/governance/energy technology policies can generate sustainable economic development [
65,
66].
In this research, we expect our results to differ from those presented in Le, Chang, and Park [
13]. We argue that the correlation between better pollution reduction technologies that reduce CO
2, and effective (and enforced) governmental environmental regulation policies can enable the successful adoption of renewable energy resources to generate economic growth in low- and middle-income countries while reducing pollution output. In contrast, Le, Chang, and Park found that governmental economic policy initiatives on adoption of renewable energy resources are uncorrelated with economic growth in low and middle-income developing countries [
13].
In summary, the extant literature presents evidence of a complex relationship between host country CO2, GDP, economic development, and urbanization levels, independent of methodology used. Despite these conclusions, we believe that inclusion of a renewable energy adoption proxy can alter these relationships further. Presumably, renewable energy is pollution friendly. Stated differently, renewable energy adoption by hosts can serve as an intervening variable in influencing stated relationships. We investigate whether the introduction of the renewable energy variable alters the CO2/state of development/GDP/urbanization relationship for middle-income and low-income countries. We aim to present evidence that effective coordination between governmental policies and the adoption of renewable energy resources can enhance economic growth in low and middle-income developing countries while reducing global pollution.
3. Sample Data
Using the most recent publicly available World Bank data, the selected sample consists of annual balanced panel data from 64 mid and low-income (39 middle income and 25 low income) countries and spans the 2005 to 2014 period. We selected carbon dioxide emissions per capita (captured by CO2 as stated earlier) as the pollution proxy and the dependent variable in the study. Following prior literature, the selected independent variables for inclusion are GDP (as defined earlier, this is gross domestic product per capita), renewable energy consumption (REC), urbanization (URBAN), CPIA business regulatory environment rating (BRER), CPIA policy and institutions for environmental sustainability rating (PIESR), CPIA transparency, accountability, and corruption in the public sector rating (TACR), and foreign direct investment net inflows (FDI).
The CO
2 data are metric tons per capita. GDP data are in constant 2010 U.S. dollars. REC is the renewable energy consumption as a percentage of total energy consumption. URBAN is percentage of urban population growth minus percentage of population growth. A higher CPIA business regulatory environment rating (BRER) represents a better regulatory environment. A high CPIA policy and institutions for environmental sustainability rating (PIESR) represents a better environmental sustainability. A high CPIA transparency, accountability, and corruption in the public sector rating (TACR) represents a better public sector environment for the country. FDI data are in current U.S. dollars using natural logarithms. Variable definitions are shown in
Table 1. For classification based on income levels, we adopted the World Bank scheme. Data are retrieved from the World Bank database (
http://www.worldbank.org/, accessed on 1 November 2021).
Sample descriptive statistics and correlations are presented in
Appendix A Table A1 (descriptive statistics) and
Table A2a (sample countries). Next, we test mean differences between the low and middle-income countries across key sample variables and present these results in
Table A2b. Finally,
Table A3a (correlation coefficients for the entire sample),
Table A3b (correlation coefficients for the low-income country sample), and
Table A3c (correlation coefficients for the middle-income country sample) are presented.
Based on the presented preliminary statistics, some key observations are made. First, from
Table A1, average CO
2 and average GDP seem to be lower for low-income countries in the sample than for middle-income countries. There also seems to be a greater degree of urbanization in sample low-income countries than in sample middle-income countries. Curiously, there seems to be a higher degree of adoption of renewable energy (as a percentage of total energy consumption) in low-income sample countries than in middle-income sample countries. FDI also seems to be higher in middle-income countries when compared to low-income countries. These preliminary findings suggest some clear differences between the two subgroups with respect to the dependent variable and key independent variables. These statistics seem to imply that economic development leads to increased CO
2 and urbanization, and lowered rate of adoption of renewable energy. Next, the results presented in
Table A2b suggest significant differences in sample means all key variables (except for FDI) across the two groups and justify partitioning the data into low and middle-income countries.
Finally, the correlation matrix for the full sample presented in
Table A3a provides some interesting findings. First, CO
2 is negatively correlated with REC, which suggests that CO
2 can be reduced with the adoption of renewable energy. Next CO
2 are also negatively associated with URBAN in sample countries, suggesting that urbanization can mean higher CO
2. Finally, the negative correlation between GDP and REC (and between GDP and CO
2) may indicate that economic development can unfortunately lead to decreased adoption of renewable energy sources in sample countries.
We now split the sample into low-income and middle-income countries. Correlation results from
Table A3b (low-income countries) and
Table A3c (middle-income countries) suggest that there are differences only in the relationship between CO
2 and GDP, and between CO
2 and URBAN. CO
2 is significantly negatively correlated with GDP for middle-income countries, whereas they are significantly positively correlated for the full sample and the low-income countries. In addition, CO
2 is negatively correlated (but not statistically significantly) with URBAN for the middle-income sample whereas they are significantly negatively correlated for the other samples. These findings suggest that whereas economic development leads to higher CO
2 in middle-income countries, urbanization does not seem to influence CO
2 in such countries. However, since the literature indicates a more complex set of nonlinear relationships between the variables of interest, we will investigate further using appropriate nonlinear methodology described in the next section.
4. Research Methodology and Empirical Results
4.1. Research Methodology
Specifically, we utilize the Panel Smooth Transition Regression (PSTR) methodology developed by González, Teräsvirta, and Van Dijk [
67] and Fok, Van Dijk, and Franses [
68]. The PSTR model is a generalized version of the Panel Threshold Regression (PTR) model and used extensively where there is a need to generate smooth “transitions” from one economic regime to another.
The purpose of this paper is to examine whether the degree of adoption of renewable energy resources and published country environmental sustainability ratings separately alter the relationships between GDP and CO2 (the environmental Kuznets curve), and between FDI and CO2 (the pollution haven hypothesis). Since economic conditions can change over time, i.e., via a structural break and/or nonlinearity, model parameters may be time dependent. Given these conditions, the PSTR model is ideally suited to examine the research questions. Specifically, the PSTR model accommodates a small number of extreme regimes with extreme values of the transition function and allows for heterogeneity and time instability of variables while accommodating a variety of nonlinear paths. Sample country data used exhibit differences across independent variables and possible nonlinearity of sample variables. Hence, we adopt the PSTR methodology to examine the linkages between economic growth, renewable energy, environmental sustainability regulations, and CO2 for the entire sample and separately for low-income and middle-income sample countries.
Following prior literature, a two-step procedure was used for the overall data and for each of the two subsamples. As a first step, we determined whether each variable was stationarity for the overall sample and for each subsample by using the panel unit root test. Next, the balanced panel variables were used to examine the relationship between CO2 and the other independent variables. Since we used the nonlinear specification, there was no need for the “coefficient stability assumption” as required for the linear model. Hence, we allowed for changing parameter estimates by using the PSTR model.
In our case, the simplest PSTR model containing two extreme regimes and one transition function is as follows:
where
is CO
2 (CO
2 emissions per capita);
is a k-dimensional vector of time-varying exogenous variables described earlier but stated again here for easy reference: GDP (GDP per capita), renewable energy consumption (REC), urbanization (URBAN). CPIA business regulatory environment rating score (BRER), CPIA policy, and institutions for environmental sustainability rating score (PIESR), CPIA transparency, accountability, and corruption in the public sector rating score (TACR), and FDI (foreign direct investment net inflows), i = 1,…, N; t = 1,…, T; and N and T are the cross section and time dimensions of the panel, respectively. g(·) is the transition function that depends on slope parameters γ and location parameters c.
is the transition variable GDP. The transition function g(·) is normalized to be bounded between 0 and 1; these extreme values are associated with regression coefficients
and
[
69,
70,
71]. The multi-level PSTR model is a generalized version of the PSTR model that allows for multiple regimes and is captured as:
where the transition functions
depend on slope parameters γ, and on location parameters c
j [
67,
68].
The PSTR modeling process requires 3 stages, namely, the specification, estimation, and evaluation stages. The homogeneity tests and the selection of the transition variable are integral components of the specification stage. The parameters are estimated by a nonlinear least square method (the estimation stage). The number of regimes, i.e., the r in Equation (2) of the panel, are specified in the evaluation state.
4.2. Nonlinearity Tests
The results of the cross-sectional dependence tests are shown in
Table A4. Both the Breusch-Pagan LM test and the Pesaran scaled LM test show that the null hypothesis of no cross-sectional dependence between sample variables is rejected at the 1% level for the full, low-income, and middle-income samples. The Pesaran CD test shows that the null hypothesis can be rejected at the 10%, 5%, and 1%, respectively, for the full, low-, and middle-income samples.
Next, panel unit root tests across sample variables using the Levin, Lin, and Chu t test [
72] are shown in
Table A5, and they show that the unit root process is rejected at the 1% level for all variables, including CO
2, GDP, REC, URBAN, BRER, PIESR, TACR, and FDI. The linearity tests for each independent variable, including the Wald tests (LM), the Fisher tests (LMF), and the LRT tests (LRT) in
Table A6 show that the linearity hypotheses are rejected at 1% level. The optimal combination of r(m) for the transition function is shown in
Table A7 [
69].
The results of linearity tests for the full sample and for each of the low-income and the middle-income subsamples and using GDP as the transition variable, are shown in
Table A6. Since all linearity tests (the LM, LMF, and LRT tests) reject the linearity hypothesis at the 1% level, nonlinear models are used to examine the relationships between the dependent variable and independent variables with GDP as the transition variable.
The number of regimes for the full sample, low and middle-income country subsamples are shown in
Table A7 [
69]. The optimal number of regimes for the full sample, the low-income country subsample, and the middle-income country subsample are respectively 2(1), 1(1), and 2(1).
Table A8 shows checks for any remaining nonlinearity. Results show that the null hypotheses, PSTR with r = 1, are rejected at 1% only for the full sample and the middle-income subsample. Based on the RSS test results, the best fit for the full sample, low-income country subsample, and the middle-income country subsample are r = 2, r = 1, and r = 2, respectively. In the next section, we present empirical tests using the PSTR nonlinear methodology for the overall sample and for each of the subsamples.
4.3. PSTR Model Estimation Results
The PSTR model estimation results with GDP as the transition variable are shown in
Table A9. For the full sample and for each of the subsamples, two sets of PSTR model estimation results (the basic model (first column of
Table A9) and the model with the interaction term (second column of
Table A9) are presented. Results indicate that the CO
2 -GDP relationship varies across the full sample and the subsamples across regimes. In the full sample, the stated relationship is negative (significantly negative, significantly positive) for regimes 1(2, 3). Second, the relationships between CO
2 and other sample variables similarly vary across samples and regimes. For instance, REC is significantly negatively (significantly positively, significantly negatively) related to CO
2 for regimes 1(2, 3). Third, URBAN is significantly negatively (positively, positively) related to CO
2 in regimes 1(2, 3). Fourth, CPIA policy and institutions for environmental sustainability rating (PIESR) is significantly positively (significantly negatively, significantly positively) related to CO
2 in regimes 1 (2, 3). The dummy variable, DPIESR, is assigned a value of 1 if the PIESR of a country is greater than or equal to the PIESR median value of all sample countries, otherwise DPIESR = 0. This interaction term captures the conditional effect of FDI on CO
2 for countries with high levels of environmental sustainability ratings. The results presented under column two in
Table A9 for the full sample show that the interaction term (DPIESR* FDI) is significantly positively (negatively, significantly positively) related to CO
2 in regimes 1(2, 3, and 4).
Clearly, the full sample results differ from subsample results. For instance, the CO2/GDP relationship and the interaction term (which examines the impact of environmental sustainability ratings on the FDI/CO2 relationship) are subsample specific. Estimates for the low-income subsample suggest a significantly negative relationship between the dependent variable and GDP for both regimes whereas results for the middle-income subsample are regime specific with sign changes. A positive (negative) sign on the interaction term shows that for countries with high environmental sustainability ratings, foreign direct investment net inflows positively (negatively) correlate with CO2.
4.4. Marginal Effects: Full Sample
Table A10 presents the marginal effects separately for the full sample and for each subsample for the basic and the interaction term models. The overall results are presented in summary form in
Table 2.
For the full sample, the marginal effects of GDP on CO2 are −0.045, −0.237, and −0.153 for regimes 1(2, 3), respectively (an inverse S curve) with a smaller negative (larger negative, smaller negative) slope in regime 1(2, 3). The marginal effects of renewable energy on CO2 are −0.009, 0.004, and −0.014 for regimes 1(2, 3), respectively (an inverse N curve) with a negative (positive, negative) slope in regime 1(2, 3). Next, the marginal effects of URBAN on CO2 are −0.095, −0.001, and 0.012 for regimes 1(2, 3), respectively (a V curve) with negative slopes in regimes 1 and 2, and a positive slope in regime 3. Finally, for the full sample, the marginal effects of FDI on CO2 are 0.002, −0.007, and 0.007 for regimes 1 (2, 3), respectively (an N curve) with a positive (negative, positive) slope in regime 1(2, 3).
Collectively, these results indicate a strong nonlinear relationship between the dependent variable and variables of interest. They also show that the subsample results are generally different from the full sample marginal effect results. For the full sample, an increase in FDI is positively associated with CO2 when GDP is low and support the pollution haven hypothesis. In contrast, an increase in FDI is negatively associated with CO2 up to a threshold increase in GDP. Beyond this threshold, increases in FDI are positively associated with CO2, and reaffirms the nonlinear nature of this relationship among sample variables.
Next, the interaction term captures the impact of the environmental sustainability ratings on FDI. For the full sample (for countries with high environmental sustainability ratings), the marginal effects of FDI on CO2 are respectively 0.005, −0.5365, −0.5336, and −0.078 in regimes 1 (2, 3, 4), and suggest that for high rating countries, FDI positively (negatively) correlate with CO2 only when GDP is low (high). Clearly, high GDP countries adopting measures to increase environmental sustainability ratings can benefit with increased FDI while reducing CO2. If low GDP countries enact enforceable policies to increase their environmental profiles, they can attract FDI while reducing pollution.
4.5. Marginal Effects: Low-Income Sample
For the low-income subsample, the marginal effects of GDP on CO2 are, respectively −1.0 × 1010 (−1.910) for regimes 1(2) and suggest a smaller (larger) negative relationship between GDP and pollution (we use CO2 and pollution interchangeably) in regime 1(2). Furthermore, the marginal effects of adopting renewable energy policies on CO2 are −1.0 × 1010 (0.061) for regime 1(2), respectively. Hence, for low (high) GDP is associated with higher (lower) pollution (a V curve) and imply that adoption of renewable energy sources by low-income countries can decrease pollution. Finally, we present results on the impact of urbanization on pollution. The marginal effects of urbanization on CO2 are −1.0 × 1010 (−0.675) for regime 1(2), respectively, implying a weak negative relationship between urbanization and pollution for regime 1, and a stronger negative relationship for regime 2. Clearly, urbanization hurts low-income countries in terms of pollution output.
Next, for the low-income subsample, the marginal effects of FDI on pollution are 1.0 × 1010 (0.008) for regime 1(2). These positive slopes imply that increases in FDI increases pollution in low-income countries. Finally, for low-income countries with high environmental sustainability rating levels, the impacts of FDI on pollution are 1.0 × 1010 (−0.123) in regime 1(2), respectively, and suggest that for countries with high environmental sustainability ratings, FDI are positively correlated with pollution only if GDP is low. For high GDP countries, the FDI/pollution link is negative. Hence, countries with relatively higher incomes in this subsample can attract foreign direct investment net inflows if they possess high levels of environmental sustainability ratings while simultaneously reducing pollution.
4.6. Marginal Effects: Middle-Income Subsample
For the middle-income subsample, three regimes (low, mid, high GDP) emerge from the tests. The marginal effects of GDP on pollution are −0.099 (−0.377, −0.249) for regime 1(2, 3), respectively, and imply an inverse S curve pattern with a relatively smaller negative slope in regime 1, a larger negative slope in regime 2, followed by a smaller negative slop in regime 3. Similarly, the marginal effects of renewable energy on pollution are −0.007 (0.004, −0.013) for regime 1(2, 3), respectively, and suggest an inverse N curve pattern with a negative slope in regime 1, a positive slope in regime 2, followed by another negative slope in regime 3.
Next, the marginal effects of urbanization on pollution are −0.237 (−0.097, 0.010) for regimes 1(2, 3), respectively. These findings reveal a/−/−/+/relationship-V curve pattern for the three regimes. In addition, for the middle-income subsample, the marginal effects of FDI on pollution are 0.007(−0.006, 0.006) for regime 1 (2, 3). These findings suggest a/+/−/+/ (a N curve) for the three regimes. Clearly, for the middle- income subsample, FDI are positively (negatively, positively) associated with pollution for low (middle, high) GDP countries. These countries must attempt to maintain a delicate balance between attracting FDI and reducing pollution while improving domestic GDP.
Third, the interaction term provides evidence on the marginal effects of FDI when countries enjoy high levels of environmental sustainability ratings. For this subsample with high ratings, the relationship between FDI and pollution is 0.088 (0, 1.0 × 107) in regime 1(2, 3), respectively. FDI and pollution are positively (unrelated, strongly positively) related for low (medium, high) GDP countries, and indicate a quandary for middle-income countries boasting a high environmental sustainability rating—they can attract FDI only at the cost of higher pollution.
5. Discussion
In this paper, we show that adding a key intervening variable (a proxy for usage of renewable energy sources in the host country, REC) not utilized in the literature examining the environmental Kuznets curve relationship and the pollution haven hypothesis, alters these relationships. In addition, and unlike extant literature, we examine the impact of local government environmental regulations and foreign direct investment net inflows by explicitly introducing an interaction term of foreign direct investment net inflows and an environmental sustainability ratings proxy. We present our major findings highlighting differences in findings with the extant literature.
For the environmental Kuznets curve, the literature documents an N curve for selected developing countries [
53]; an inverted U curve relationship for developed countries [
53]; an inverted U curve for 12 of 15 developed countries [
54]; and an inverted U curve for 56 sample countries, including low, middle, and high-income countries [
55]. Some researchers argue against the long run validity of the inverted U-shape environmental Kuznets curve [
73]. In addition, empirical findings vary between countries and regions [
16,
29,
74,
75]. In contrast, our results indicate that this relationship is an inverse S curve for the full sample and for each subsample, but at different subsample specific negative rates. Our findings suggest that the GDP/CO
2 relationship is also country economic development level specific.
Next, the literature documents a negative relationship between renewable energy adoption and CO
2 in developed countries [
1,
13]. Others find no evidence of any such relationship for low and middle-income countries [
12,
13]. However, we provide evidence that the renewable energy adoption/CO
2 relationship is an inverse N curve for the full and the middle-income samples, but a V curve for the low-income sample and indicate that low-income countries can reduce pollution by adopting renewable energy sources. However, our results also suggest that pollution can increase even with renewable energy adoption in high-income sample countries.
Third, the literature presents inconclusive evidence on the validity of the pollution haven hypothesis. Some show a positive relationship [
31,
32,
33,
34,
58], while others find evidence of a negative relationship [
43,
44,
45]. Here, we find evidence of a complex relationship between the variables of interest: an N curve for the full and the middle-income samples, but a smaller (larger) positive FDI/pollution relationship in regime 1(2) in the low-income subsample. These results affirm the selective validity of the pollution haven hypothesis only for low-income sample countries.
Finally, and unlike the extant literature, we investigate the impact of environmental sustainability ratings on the FDI/pollution relationship with an interaction term. Our findings indicate that high levels of environmental sustainability ratings in countries with relatively high incomes in low-income countries can attract foreign direct investment net inflows while reducing pollution while middle-income countries with high environmental sustainability ratings can attract foreign direct investment net inflows only with a small increase in pollution output.
Clearly, our results differ from extant literature in several different ways. Here we provide a summary of our key findings and relate it to prior research. First, with respect to the pollution haven hypothesis, in addition to examining the FDI/CO2 relationship, we add an intervening variable (environmental sustainability ratings) and find that this variable alters the well-established FDI/CO2 relationships documented in the literature, for our sample of countries. These differences from extant literature have been documented earlier. In addition, in contrast to prior research, our findings potentially alter established policy prescriptions for governments. We show that governments can attract FDI while simultaneously reducing CO2 emissions. Moreover, governments that enhance their environmental sustainability ratings can signal a positive environmental climate to potential firms, which in turn allows host countries to attract needed pollution reducing FDI into the country.
6. Conclusions
The results from the full sample runs clearly demonstrate that GDP is negatively associated with CO2 in the inverse S form (small negative for regimes 1 and 3, and large negative for regime 2). In addition, the renewable energy/CO2 relationship is an inverse N curve (negative, regimes 1 and 3; positive regime 2). Next, urbanization affects CO2 in the form of a V curve (negative in regimes 1 and 2; positive in regime 3. The impact of FDI on CO2 is an N curve (positive regimes 1 and 3; negative in regime 2). Finally, relatively high-income full sample countries can increase FDI while reducing CO2 by strengthening their environmental sustainability ratings. Our findings differ from those reported in the literature under the environmental Kuznets curve and the pollution haven hypothesis.
When analyzing the results separately for low-income and middle-income sample countries, we found that the results selectively differ by sample country income levels. For the low-income subsample, higher levels of GDP reduce CO2, albeit at different rates. Next, the adoption of renewable energy reduces CO2 for low GDP countries but increases pollution for high GDP countries. Third, urbanization decreases pollution output for low and mid GDP countries but at different rates. Fourth, FDI into low-income countries cause pollution to increase as a function of GDP. Finally, low-income countries can take initiatives to enhance their environmental sustainability ratings since this move attracts foreign direct investment net inflows while reducing pollution output. Again, these findings differ from those reported under the environmental Kuznets curve hypothesis and the pollution haven hypothesis. One important finding is that we provide evidence that low-income countries can enhance their environmental sustainability ratings to attract foreign direct investment net inflows while reducing pollution output.
Our results for the middle-income countries are also selectively different from those observed for low-income countries. For the middle-income subsample, the relationship between GDP and pollution is an inverted S curve-higher levels of GDP reduces CO2, albeit at different rates. Next, the adoption of renewable energy reduces CO2 for low and high GDP but increases pollution for mid GDP (an inverted N curve). Third, urbanization decreases (increases) pollution output for low and mid (high) GDP countries (a V curve). Fourth, FDI into middle-income countries cause pollution to increase (decrease) for low and high (mid) GDP countries (an N curve). Fourth, we show that if middle-income countries enhance their environmental sustainability ratings, they can attract FDI while reducing pollution output. Finally, our findings suggest a quandary for high GDP middle-income countries enjoying high levels of environmental sustainability ratings—they can only attract FDI by allowing a slight increase in pollution. As argued earlier, these findings have not been reported in the literature.
We offer several policy implications and suggestions for further research. Practically, from a policy perspective, we suggest that existing prescriptions based on tests of the environmental Kuznets curve and the pollution hypotheses should also consider the impact of a country’s GDP status on relationships of interest. Second, low- and middle-income countries should consider adopting (or strengthening existing) enforceable environmental sustainability ratings to attract FDI while reducing pollution output. Third, low-income countries should consider replacing traditional energy sources with renewable ones. Fourth, our findings suggest that renewable energy adoption for moderate growth GDP increases pollution output for both low-income and middle-income sample countries. Adoption of such resources for low and high-output sample countries can reduce pollution output. Therefore, countries at the mid end of the output spectrum should consider ambitious policies to reach higher output plateaus so that economic success comes with increased use of renewable energy resources while reducing overall pollution output—a desirable outcome. Next, urbanization policies reduce overall pollution output for mid-range and low-end GDP per capita output countries. However, urbanization at high GDP output should be discouraged since they lead to higher pollution output. For middle-income countries, they should attempt to reach high levels of output since this strategy is associated with lower pollution output. Attraction of FDI increases with high output but at a small pollution cost if countries enforce environmental sustainability policies.
For academics and practitioners, this research can be extended to other developed countries to examine whether the relationships examined here hold. The literature (and the results presented here) already document that the results are sample and time specific. Given these findings, researchers may find a different set of results using a different sample set and different time periods. Their work can enhance our knowledge of the relationships of interest as well as provide insights regarding the importance of renewable energy adoption in reducing CO2 locally and globally. Furthermore, since there is evidence that renewable energy costs have decreased substantially in recent years and that consumer interest on the environment and CO2 have increased, there is scope to address whether reduced renewable energy costs and increased stakeholder interest have motivated firms/countries to adopt these technologies. Research can also determine whether these adoptions have indeed reduced CO2. Finally, this paper only uses data spanning the years 2005 to 2014 (inclusive). Future research can extend the study to include more recent data as they become available. The addition of more countries can also determine whether the conclusions documented in this paper are robust.
The recent COVID-19 pandemic may also have structurally impacted the documented relationships. Given the game-changing nature of the pandemic, it is possible that global pollution may have decreased (due to decreased economic activity because of the pandemic) and that renewable energy adoption measures may have been postponed by domestic countries. Ample scope exists to address these issues.
From a theoretical perspective, research can also examine whether these relationships differ when oil producing vs. oil consuming countries are examined. Presumably, oil-producing countries may inhibit development of renewable energy resources since their economics are heavily dependent on carbon-based products. Finally, this research can be extended by identifying different types of renewable energy sources to determine the optimal path that simultaneously allows countries to develop economically, reduce pollution, and increase the income levels of its citizens.
As is typical, there are several limitations of this study. One key limitation (as documented earlier) is the limitations on data availability. Next, we do not consider explicitly the relative costs of adoption of renewable energy (vis a vis fossil fuel energy) in the modeling process. Arguably, this variable may alter our conclusions. Similarly, other factors documented in the literature as influencing the two key relationships (the environmental Kuznets curve and the pollution haven hypothesis) have not been introduced in our models, primarily because they further attenuate data for analysis. There is ample scope for researchers to address these limitations as more data become available.