Next Article in Journal
An Exploration of the Decline in E-Scooter Ridership after the Introduction of Mandatory E-Scooter Parking Corrals on Virginia Tech’s Campus in Blacksburg, VA
Next Article in Special Issue
Exploration of the Role of Human Capital in China’s High-Quality Economic Development and Analysis of Its Spatial Characteristics
Previous Article in Journal
Smart City, Digitalization and CO2 Emissions: Evidence from 353 Cities in China
Previous Article in Special Issue
ICT and Economic Resilience during COVID-19: Cross-Country Analysis
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Coordination vs. Competitiveness of Effective Average Tax Rates in Relation to FDI: The Case of Emerging EU Economies †

Department of Economic Theory and Policy, Faculty of Economics, University of Novi Sad, 24000 Subotica, Serbia
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
The first draft of this paper titled The Relationship between Effective Average Tax Rates and FDI in Emerging EU Economies: Non-Stationary Heterogeneous Panel Approach was presented at 41st Eurasia Business and Economics Society (EBES) Conference, Berlin, Germany, 12–14 October 2022.
Sustainability 2023, 15(1), 227; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010227
Submission received: 14 November 2022 / Revised: 17 December 2022 / Accepted: 19 December 2022 / Published: 23 December 2022
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Economic Sustainability of the Economy)

Abstract

:
Due to the single market within the European Union (EU), capital mobility has created many challenges in the field of tax policy, especially whether taxes should be coordinated or governments should retain fiscal sovereignty for the sake of tax competitiveness. In order to attract foreign direct investment (FDI), emerging EU economies most often choose the policy of tax reduction and particularly lowering the effective average tax rates (EATR). The purpose of this paper is to empirically assess the impact of changes in the EATR on the decision to localize FDI in emerging EU economies in the period 1998–2021, in the framework of cross-sectional dependent, non-stationary, heterogeneous panels. Using the (Pooled) Mean Group estimator, the long-run relationship between the EATR and the FDI is revealed. The error-correction parameters are significant and heterogeneous, showing that the speed of adjustments towards equilibrium is different, but the highest in Estonia. Accession to the EU contributed faster adjustments to the long-run relationship in the majority of the emerging EU economies, while a broader set of potential determinants of FDI localization is taken into consideration and estimated using the Panel-corrected standard error method. Results showed de facto tax competitiveness in the group of emerging EU economies, instead of de jure tax coordination in the EU.

1. Introduction

Capital mobility has emphasized the importance of tax competitiveness, meaning that economies have the freedom to participate in the market struggle and to adjust tax policies for the sake of attracting foreign direct investment (FDI). In the case of the European Union (EU), which is characterized by a single market, capital mobility has created many challenges in the field of tax policy. In past two decades, within the EU, there have been various attempts to coordinate some aspects of business taxation (both tax rates and tax bases), including EU institution proposals for the introduction of a single EU corporate tax. Although there is still a tendency to coordinate tax systems in order to avoid harmful tax competition, EU member states have retained the right to fiscal sovereignty, since their attitudes about whether or not to pursue further corporate tax coordination are divided. Namely, member states have jealously retained most taxing powers within their hands and conceded only limited prerogatives at the European level [1]. Therefore, governments have the opportunity to compete with each other for foreign capital inflow. Among all the EU economies, tax competition between the old and new EU economies exists; namely, emerging EU economies are tempted to offer corporate taxes that are low [2]. Attracting FDI generates a “race to the bottom” in capital income taxation, since tax rates are competed down to zero [3], creating tax competition as an opposite trend to tax coordination [4].
Hence, in order to attract FDI, policy makers create favorable tax systems. In order to ensure foreign capital inflow, policy makers choose the policy of tax reduction [5] and particularly the policy of effective average tax rate (EATR) lowering. Namely, the EATR measures the difference in the before-tax and after-tax net present value of a real FDI profitability, meaning that differences in the EATR across countries affect the location of the FDI. Specific interest in this paper is oriented towards different tax strategies chosen by emerging EU economies in the periods before membership and after accession for EATR, since tax coordination is de jure expected in the EU; however, de facto there is evidence of tax competitiveness.
This paper empirically assesses the impact of changes in the EATR on the decision to localize FDI in the emerging EU economies (Bulgaria, Croatia, Cyprus, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia) using available empirical data in the period 1998–2021. Namely, the paper analyses tax competitiveness existence in the emerging EU economies, through the empirical estimation of the EATR reduction and the effects on FDI inflow. Various authors have dealt with this relationship with the statutory (corporate income tax) rate; however, some have just authenticated the impact of the EATR on the decision to allocate investment in emerging EU economies [6,7,8]. Since the EATR is not the only factor that determines investors, it is important to consider the global crisis effects because investment priorities were radically changed after the outbreak of the global financial crisis in 2008 (Zaubir et al., 2020), as well as other determinants of FDI in emerging EU economies such as the business environment [9,10,11]. Therefore, the goal of this paper is twofold: (a) to empirically assess the long-run relationship between the EATR and FDI and the heterogeneity adjustments of 13 emerging EU economies in the period 1998–2021 and in the post-accession period (2004–2021); (b) to estimate key determinants of FDI along with the EATR (macroeconomic variables, corruption and competition index, the effects of the global crisis). These goals are analyzed in the framework of cross-sectional dependent, non-stationary, heterogeneous panels, using the Pooled Mean Group (PMG) estimator to reveal the long-run relationship between the EATR and FDI and heterogeneous error-correction parameters, while other determinants are identified in a robust model estimated by the Panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE) estimator. To the best of our knowledge, these specific econometric estimators have not been used in the literature on the effects of the EATR on FDI. Therefore, the main hypotheses of this paper are:
Hypothesis (H1):
A long-run relationship between FDI inflow and EATR exists in emerging EU economies, with heterogeneous adjustments towards the long-run relationship in the period 1998–2021.
Hypothesis (H2):
The speed of adjustment to the long-run relationship between FDI inflow and EATR is faster in emerging EU economies for the period 2004–2021, namely, after joining the EU in 2004.
Hypothesis (H3):
Effective average tax rates influence negatively on FDI, while GDP per capita, the corruption index and the effects of the global crisis are significant for decisions on investment allocation in the emerging EU economies.
The results of this paper indicate that emerging EU economies used tax competition in the period 1998–2021, since the homogeneous long-run relationship is significant between the EATR and FDI, while the adjustment parameters are heterogeneous, but higher in the post-accession period (2004–2021). Namely, accession to the EU contributed faster adjustments towards the long-run relationship in the majority of the emerging EU economies. This finding of tax competitiveness contrary to the expected coordination may contribute to future strategies for favorable tax systems in the EU economies. Namely, EU policymakers should reconsider whether downward pressures on the EATR in the emerging EU could be a possibility for tax coordination within the EU but at lower tax levels, defining a floor for tax competitiveness in the EU similar to the global minimum tax rate defined by the OECD [12].
The paper is structured as follows. After the Introduction section, Section 2 reviews the existing evidence in the empirical literature. Section 3 deals with competitive tax systems and FDI in the emerging EU economies. Section 4 presents the methodology and data, while Section 5 discusses estimation results. The final section outlines the concluding remarks.

2. Literature Review

This paper draws on the literature based on the competitive tax policies in emerging EU economies. Many economic policy makers have emphasized the importance of tax policies as a key factor for the smooth functioning of an economy [13]. Every tax system should be based on the trade-off between efficiency and equality, and therefore tax systems differ in nature and form. Devereux et al. [14] pointed out that capital mobility enables the redirection of investments from economies with higher tax rates to economies with lower ones. That is in accordance with Desaia et al. [15], who pointed out that taxes influence companies’ decisions about the location, establishment and expansion of their businesses. Thus, tax policy is a significant factor that can be a generator or negative factor for FDI inflow [16]. That is in line with the assumption that higher tax rates reduce profits for investors [17], enlarging labor costs firstly and then taxing profits. Taking into consideration all of the above, the important factors for tax systems could be summarized as: (i) globalization, (ii) the specificities of EU economies, (iii) the EATR and (iv) the effects on FDI inflow.
An important aspect of the analysis of changes in tax rates is globalization, as it induces reforms of tax systems [18] with the aim of achieving tax competitiveness in a market struggle. Namely, Hong et al. [19] pointed out that if the tax system burdens taxpayers too much, it will inevitably lead to tax avoidance schemes, while Stewart [20] confirmed from the example of Ireland that lowering corporate income tax rates can attract a significant amount of FDI to the country, and thus achieve an economic boom. As Keightley et al. [21] pointed out in their research, one way to achieve tax competitiveness without compromising public revenues is to lower corporate tax rates while expanding the tax base [22].
Papers that deal with the tax position within the EU were analyzed, since the tax systems of EU economies are of great importance for the paper. Member states retained fiscal sovereignty; regardless of this however, tax coordination has been insisted on for many years, in order to eliminate harmful tax competition between member states. According to Baldwin and Krugman [23], the failure of tax coordination can be explained by the fact that it cannot suit all economies equally. In fact, if harmonization occurs, it will harm at least one economy, given that in core countries the EU elasticity of investment movements in relation to tax changes is lower than in peripheral countries [24]. Thus, according to Sørensen [25], the tax coordination of EU countries should remain at the level of reducing the cost of tax liabilities, tax administration and improving the ability of governments to maintain a redistributive welfare state. That is in line with Wasserfallen [26], who indicated that after the central and eastern European countries’ accession, the prospects of tax policy coordination starkly decreased. However, Glavaški et al. [27] emphasized the importance of strengthening the fiscal framework, stimulating the coordination between national and supranational fiscal arrangements.
A series of papers also underlines the impact of effective average tax rates. Bénassy-Quéré et al. [28] claimed that following statutory tax rates, investors/capital owners could be misled. Although the statutory tax rate is decreased, the tax burden can be unchanged [29] Thus, Auerbach [6] emphasized the effective tax rate role in understanding FDI location decisions. Egger et al. [8], in their empirical study, confirmed that unilateral effective tax rates significantly affect the production and location decisions of multinational firms. That is in line with Barrios et al. [7], who stressed that the effective tax rate is more suitable for investment decisions since it reflects tax incentives. In October 2021, the international community of 136 economies agreed a landmark deal involving a two-pillar solution to address the tax challenges arising from the globalization process in the context of the EATR. The two pillars introduce domestic rules that establish a global minimum effective corporate tax rate of 15% for large multinational enterprises (MNEs), which is characterized as a floor for tax competitiveness [12].
The growing importance of multinational corporations and FDI allocation have far-reaching consequences for national tax policies [30]. Higher transnational capital mobility exerts a downward pressure on corporate tax rates [31]. In an effort to attract new investors and retain existing producers, governments use corporate tax rates as a policy tool for investment attraction, resulting in inter-state tax competition [29]. Tax competitiveness motivates capital owners on resource allocation [14], since one of the key determinants for multinational companies’ decisions about the location and expansion of businesses is taxes [15]. Foreign direct investment has become the largest source of external finance, surpassing official development assistance [32]. Hence, in order to attract FDI, policy makers create favorable tax systems. Tax incentives are commonly used by emerging and developing countries, with some variation across sectors and regions. In this paper, the focus is on emerging EU economies, where Hunady et al. [33] noted that FDI is recognized as a main generator of economic growth [34,35,36]. The inflow of foreign capital and the presence of multinational companies plays a crucial role in the successful transition of these countries [37,38]. Namely, FDI affects rises in employment, competition, technology transfer, a better position on the international market and a rise in exports and foreign currency inflow [39,40]. After the financial crisis, the global economic environment changed [41]; however, other business environment factors such as the corruption index significantly influence investment decisions [11]. The idea of this paper is to fill the gap that exists in the literature regarding the EATR impact on FDI localization decisions in emerging EU economies using Pooled Mean Group Estimator and the Panel-corrected standard errors estimator, given the obvious scarcity of scientific papers dealing with this topic before and after the accession of the emerging EU economies to the EU.

3. Competitive Tax Strategies and FDI

Tax reforms in the EU are motivated by concerns about equity and efficiency and by the idea of deeper integration in the field of tax policy, and more broadly in the context of fiscal unification. The subtlety of this question is related to the tax structures of interconnected member states, which certainly affect their competitiveness. Tax rates i.e., the tax burden, can be a crucial factor for the foreign investment afflux/reflux, and consequently the level of employment [16]. Therefore, if tax rates are increased, investor profits are reduced [17], due to increasing labor costs and reduced net income. Thus, tax evasion is inevitable [19].
The national governments of emerging EU economies [18], in order to achieve tax competitiveness, have been particularly active in reforming their tax systems. Corporate income tax accentuates as the most important tax form, since lower rates make the country more attractive for investment. According to Keightley et al. [21], tax competition can be attained without public revenue decrease, by lowering corporate income tax rates while expanding the tax base [22]. However, that can be misleading since low statutory rates can be offset by a broader definition of taxable income [28].
Accordingly, there is a significant difference between the statutory tax rate and effective tax rate. Corporate income tax rates (statutory) are widely used, although even defining this rate is less straightforward than might be expected [14]. The effective rate represents what corporations actually pay after deductions, tax credits, write-offs and foreign income allocations [6,29]. The incentives generated by the tax system depend on the form of the investment project, including the type of asset purchased and the way it is financed [14], meaning, effective tax rates correctly reflect tax incentives, and are better candidates to gauge the impact of the taxation of FDI decisions by firms [7,28].
Achieving tax competitiveness has created certain problems within the EU, especially due to the shortcomings of the unfinished EU project [27]. Namely, corporate tax rates and the EATR ‘race to bottom’ have triggered various issues within the single market considering four freedoms. Different tax rates within the single market lead to the “migration” of capital from member states with higher tax rates to member states with lower rates, significantly affecting economic growth and the unemployment rate. For that reason, the European Commission has put forward ambitious plans for a Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) within the EU [42]. This EU initiative involves a common tax base, aimed at eliminating mismatches between national systems that aggressive tax planners often exploit, and consolidating reporting at the level of a multinational group, aimed at reducing the administrative burden. Namely, EU tax coordination includes both corporate and EATR [15,24], since uncoordinated national tax regimes give rise to strategic tax planning often operated by multinationals in order to minimize their overall tax liabilities. However, the tax harmonization perspective is questionable since low-tax countries oppose the pooling of tax authority because, for them, European tax intervention is associated with higher costs, while high-tax countries support tax harmonization [26]. Thus, room for capital mobility is still left. This is in line with Baldwin et al. [23], who stressed that tax coordination cannot suit all economies equally. There is a valid fear that, if it occurs, tax coordination will harm at least one economy, due to the diverse investment elasticities between peripheral states and core states [24]. This can be confirmed by empirical data analysis based on corporate income tax rates in selected EU economies, and potential effects on investment’s localization decisions.
The tendencies of lowering the EATR in the period 1998–2021 in all the analyzed emerging EU economies are unquestionable (Figure 1). Moreover, almost all emerging economies after their accession to the EU in 2004 lowered the EATR (Figure 1). Although the accession year for Romania and Bulgaria was 2007, and for Croatia 2013, the lowering of the EATR occurred in 2004 as well. Slovakia significantly decreased the EATR from 1998 to 2004, from 36.7% to 16.5%, slightly increasing it after 2013. Lithuania significantly changed the EATR even before membership in 2002; however, after two years of membership the EATR was raised. Hungary also recorded an EATR increase in 2007, from 16.7% to 19.5%, maintaining that rate until 2017, when the EATR notably dropped, from 19.3% to 11.1%. After lowering the EATR in 2005 from 34% in 1998 to 14.7%, Romania has had quite an unchangeable EATR (around 14.8%). Furthermore, Malta’s EATR did not change until 2017, and even after the reduction the EATR was the highest compared to other emerging EU economies (24.4%).
On the other hand, FDI movements recorded more fluctuations in comparison to changes in the EATR in the emerging EU economies. The majority of the emerging EU economies were countries of former socialist systems (Soviet Union and Yugoslavia). The economic organization of those systems implied that decisions on investments, production and allocation were based on a planned economy. New socio-political circumstances have conditioned the transition of emerging economies towards a market economy, in which a laissez faire system applies. The transformation from state or social property to private property has been primary. Namely, privatization enables the inflow of foreign capital, which in emerging EU economies is recognized as an essential driver of economic growth and development [33,34]. Thus, the entry of multinational companies into the market has significantly contributed to the successful transformation of the system [37]. Furthermore, in addition to capital, FDI in the emerging EU economies brought new technology and knowledge as well [35], which enabled a significant increase in labor productivity, and thus an economic boom [40,43].
Moreover, the investment priorities were radically changed after the outbreak of the global financial crisis in 2008 [41]. Accordingly, it is imperative to identify the factors that determine investment location. A competitive EATR was recognized as a stimulator for FDI influx, often leading economic policymakers to cut tax rates. Besides the EATR, the attractiveness of the host country as an investment location is notably determined by the business environment [10,11].
From the beginning of the observed period until 2003, Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Croatia, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovenia, Slovakia and Romania recorded a positive trend in foreign capital inflow (Figure 2). Right before accession to the EU, the Czech Republic, Slovakia and Lithuania had a drastic drop in their FDI share to GDP, while a notable FDI inflow was recorded in Estonia in their first year of joining (with around 20% of FDI share to GDP). A significant decline in FDI in relation to GDP in the observed emerging EU economies was recorded after the outbreak of the global financial crisis. Consequently, the further growth of FDI inflows did not ensure the pre-crisis share of FDI to GDP. On the contrary, Hungary, Malta and Cyprus, from the beginning of the observation period until 2002, experienced a similar and almost negligible FDI inflow. After 2002, the situation changed drastically for Malta’s economy, since a greater FDI inflow occurred until 2007. In Cyprus, more notable inflows appeared after 2008; therefore, the movement of FDI in Cyprus is opposite to other countries. The investment trend was variable until 2017, when a significant decline was recorded.
Consequently, the descriptive analysis points to causality in the movement of investments towards the EATR, since the positive trend of FDI inflow is recorded in the period of the EATR lowering. The subject of the econometric analysis in the continuation of the paper will be the evaluation of this relationship using the panel model.

4. Methodology and Data

The analysis is based on a panel data econometric framework, which allows research on the long-run relationship between FDI and EATR (as well as other factors that effect FDI) across emerging EU countries and over time. The whole sample contains the data on 13 emerging EU economies (N = 13), and total observed period is 1998–2021 (T = 24), meaning relatively large panels (macro panels). That period of time was the longest possible, due to availability of data related to the EATR. When time dimension is longer, it is necessary to account for heterogeneity across panels, (non)stationarity and cross-section dependence. Namely, the asymptote of large N and large T dynamic panels is different from the asymptotic of traditional large N and small T dynamic panels [44]. Small T panel estimation usually relies on fixed- or random-effects estimators, based on pooling individual groups and allowing only the intercepts to differ across the groups. However, in the large T panels, the assumption of homogeneity of slope parameters is often inappropriate. In this paper, we use methods with large T dynamic panels in order to analyze: (a) Hypotheses (H1) and (H2) by PMG Estimator, and (b) robust panel estimation to analyze Hypothesis (H3) by PCSE estimator.

4.1. Pooled Mean Group vs. Mean Group Estimator

Since the intention is to analyze whether long-run relationship between FDI inflow and EATR exists, as well as adjustment mechanisms (Hypothesis (H1)), this research applies the estimators proposed by Pesaran et al. [45] and Pesaran et al. [46] based on non-stationary heterogeneous dynamic panels. The assumptions of homogeneity of slope parameters and stationarity are often inappropriate in macro panels [47]; therefore, we used Mean-Group (MG) and Pooled Mean-Group (PMG) techniques to estimate non-stationary heterogeneous panels. Mean-Group is based on estimation of N time-series regressions and average coefficients, while PMG is based on equal long-run relationship across all panel units and averaging of coefficients. Since the short-run adjustments are heterogeneous in both models, only difference is directed towards restriction in long-run coefficients. In order to distinguish whether to use MG or PMG estimator, Hausman test could be used [48]. Namely, if long-run relationship is homogeneous, restriction in PMG model is true and provides efficient and consistent estimates. Mean-Group model assumes heterogeneous long-run equilibrium relationships and provides consistent estimates in both cases. Since those methods are defined as panel error-correction model, model could be described as [44]:
Δ y i t = φ i ( y i t 1 θ i X i t ) + j = 1 p 1 λ i j Δ y i t 1 + j = 0 q 1 δ i j Δ X i t j + μ i + u i t
where the cross-section units are represented by i = 1, 2,…, N; the number of periods t = 1, 2,…, T; X i t is a k × 1 vector of explanatory variables; φ i is error-correction parameter, indicating speed of adjustment to long-run equilibrium relationship for each emerging EU economy—error-correction parameter is expected to be significantly negative under the assumption that long-run relationship exists and variables show a return to long-run equilibrium, otherwise, φ i = 0 means that there is no evidence about long-run equilibrium; θ i represents long-run equilibrium relationship between variables; λ i j is coefficient of lagged dependent variable, δ i j is short-run parameter for each panel unit (emerging EU economy), μ i represents individual effects and u i t stochastic disturbance term. Using described specification, we estimated following model:
Δ f d i i t = φ i ( f d i i t 1 θ i e f e c i t ) + j = 1 p 1 λ i j Δ f d i i t 1 + j = 0 q 1 δ i j Δ e f e c i t j + μ i + u i t
where dependent variable fdi represents FDI inflow share in GDP of 13 emerging EU economies during the period 1998–2021 obtained by World Bank, while variable efec shows EATR for each emerging EU economy during the period 1998–2021, based on Devereux/Griffith methodology available in the paper of Spengel et al. [49] (Detailed descriptions of data are given in Appendix A, Table A1). Namely, we did not use regular data on corporate taxes available in standard data source; rather, we downloaded data from EU project effective tax levels using the Devereux/Griffith methodology, which provides precise data on EATR, which is more reliable data in our analysis in comparison to corporate tax rates. In the case of FDI location and its relationship with effective tax rates, PMG and MG estimators are particularly useful in exploring long-run relationship between those variables and could be expected to be homogeneous across emerging EU countries. On the other hand, short-run coefficients could vary depending on emerging EU economies’ characteristics and represent speed of adjustment to the long-run relationship.

4.2. Panel-Corrected Standard Errors (PCSE) Estimator

Another goal of the paper was to analyze negative relationship between EATR and FDI, as well as influence of other factors that affect FDI (Hypothesis (H3)). Due to restricted availability of important factors that could influence investment localization from the year 1998, e.g., level of corruption and competitiveness index, we observed period 2004–2021 for 13 emerging EU economies. This change indicated classical panel model estimators to be applied, based on pooling individual groups and allowing only the intercepts to differ across the groups; namely, restricted heterogeneity in slope coefficients is allowed by inclusion of dummy variables. Beck and Katz [50] recommended use of Panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE) estimator in order to encompass heteroskedastic, autocorrelated and/or contemporaneously correlated disturbances. Empirical model can be written as follows:
y i t = b 0 + b 1 X i t + b 2 D i + μ i + λ t + u i t
where y it is FDI of country i in the year t; X it containing determinants that vary over i and t; D i is dummy variable for groups of economies i, or outliers in the empirical data; individual effect s μ i , time effects λ t and stochastic disturbance are represented by term u i t .
Dependent variable, y it , FDI, could be defined and measured in different ways. The focus in this paper is on FDI inflow (fdi), which is measured as percent of GDP or net inflows (current dollars). Following the main results in the empirical studies, a set of potential determinants,   X it , are employed: EATR, GDP per capita, short-run and long-run interest rate, business environment variables and dummy variables representing outliers. Detailed descriptions and sources of each used variable in the paper are presented in Appendix, Table A1. The most important independent variable is EATR variable, efec it , because it can be implemented to show the effects of tax competition between economies on FDI localization decisions. It is expected that reduction of EATR provides FDI inflow, while influences of GDP per capita and interest rates are expected to be positive. Mentioned variables are defined using data from OECD, World Development Indicators and Eurostat statistics.
Business environment is encompassed in the model by introduction of competition indexes (comp) and corruption indexes (corr). The competitiveness index consists of 98 variables that are organized into 12 pillars: (1) institutions, (2) infrastructure, (3) adoption of ICT, (4) macroeconomic stability, (5) health, (6) workforce skills, (7) product market, (8) labor market, (9) financial system, (10) market size, (11) business dynamics and (12) ability to innovate. It is expected to affirm positive relationship between FDI and competitiveness index, since favorable business environment could attract foreign capital. Another business environmental factor that influences the decision of investment localization is corruption index in the public sector. Capital owners redirect their investments according to corruption index; 0 index indicates corruption at the highest level and 100 indicates economy without corruption. Thus, investments gravitate towards more competitive countries (where the presence of corruption is reduced to a minimum) compared to the other countries. Thus, positive relationship in the model between corruption index and FDI is expected, since economies with less corruption (higher corruption index) attract investments.
Finally, dummy variable is defined for Malta (dummy_M), due to extremely high FDI inflow in the period 2004–2008 (122.48; 339.78; 369.34; 449.08; 163.22% of GDP, respectively). Dummy variable is defined to take value 1 for Malta in the period 2004–2008, and 0 otherwise. Another dummy variable is defined to capture outliers identified in the case of Hungary (dummy_H) in the years 2015 and 2016. In those years, extreme negative values of FDI were recorded. Therefore, dummy variable dummy_H is defined to take value 1 for the years 2015 and 2016 in Hungary, and 0 otherwise. Therefore, the baseline model, derived from theoretical framework to test Hypothesis (H3), could be specified as:
f d i d i t = b 0 + b 1 e f e c i t + b 2 s i r i t + b 3 l i r i t + b 4 c o m p i t + b 5 c o r r i t + + b 6 G D P p c i t + b 7 d u m m y H i + b 8 d u m m y M i + μ i + λ t + u i t .

5. Discussion of Results

5.1. Pooled Mean Group vs. Mean Group Estimator Results

The procedure performed in order to obtain the long-run relationship and short-run dynamic estimates between the FDI inflow and the EATR (Hypotheses (H1) and (H2)) consists of the following empirical steps. Since that sample included the period 1998–2021 for the 13 emerging EU economies, firstly, cross-sectional dependence (CSD) in the panel is tested. The results of the Pesaran CD test are presented in Table 1 (panel a)—Table 1, Table 2, Table 3 and Table 4 simultaneously represent analysis related to Hypothesis (H1) (for the period 1998–2021) and Hypothesis (H2) (for the period 2004–2021)—and imply that the null hypothesis of cross-section independency has to be rejected for the variables efec and fdi. Detected dependence is expected due to the strong institutional framework in EU economies and common policies. Although the sample covers a longer period of time and preparation phase for membership, the majority of the analyzed economies became members of the EU in 2004 (2004 for the Czech Republic, Cyprus, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia, 2007 for Bulgaria and Romania and 2013 for Croatia). Cross-section dependence is therefore expected, since the institutional design of the EU includes the common market, common agricultural policy, customs union, tax harmonization and finally monetary union for some of the emerging EU economies, which inevitably leads to connections, spill-over effects and dependencies between EU countries [51].
Due to the test results of CSD, the second generation panel unit root test is used—the Pesaran CIPS test (2007), which allows for CSD. The results of the Pesaran CIPS test for variables in the level and at the first difference in the model with the constant are shown in Table 1 (panel b). The panel unit root tests fail to reject the null hypothesis of the non-stationarity of the variable at the 5% significance level, meaning that the variables fdi and efec are non-stationary in the levels. Therefore, in the next step, the stationarity of first differences is tested, and the results show that all variables are stationary in first differences.
The next step in the procedure implies cointegration analysis. Since both variables are integrated at order 1, the Westerlund cointegration test is implemented because it allows the existence of CSD in the model. The null hypothesis of no cointegration, against the alternative hypothesis, cointegration existence between non-stationary variables, is estimated. The results based on the Westerlund test show that the null hypothesis of no cointegration has to be rejected, meaning that FDI and the EATR are cointegrated (Table 1, panel c).
The estimated homogeneous coefficients obtained using the PMG estimator are given in Table 2. It is observed that a significant long-run relationship exists between the FDI inflow and the EATR dynamic (0.8826) in the period 1998–2021. The homogeneous estimates confirm the long-run relationship, since the error-correction parameter is significant and negative, showing the speed of adjustments towards the long-run equilibrium. It is concluded that each year 51.97% of the EATR dynamic is corrected towards the equilibrium. A similar result is provided by the MG estimator in the context of the error-correction parameter, although the long-run equilibrium is not significant in the MG model. However, the PMG model is detected as efficient using the Hausman test, and therefore the dynamic of the heterogeneous adjustment coefficient is analyzed using the PMG estimator heterogeneous coefficient (Table 3).
The estimated homogeneous coefficients obtained using the PMG estimator are given in Table 2. It is observed that there exists a significant long-run relationship between FDI inflow and EATR dynamics (0.8826) in the period 1998–2021. The homogeneous estimates confirm the long-run relationship, since the error-correction parameter is significant and negative, showing the speed of the adjustments towards the long-run equilibrium. It is concluded that each year 51.97% of EATR dynamics is corrected towards the equilibrium. A similar result is provided by the MG estimator in the context of the error-correction parameter, although the long-run equilibrium is not significant in the MG model. However, the PMG model is detected as efficient using the Hausman test, and therefore the dynamic of the heterogeneous adjustment coefficient is analyzed using the PMG estimator heterogeneous coefficient (Table 3).
The main advantage of heterogeneous panels is estimates of each emerging EU economy in the context of error-correction parameters. The error-correction term, indicating correction towards long-run equilibrium, is significantly negative in Bulgaria, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Croatia, Latvia, Lithuania, Malta, Poland, Slovenia and Slovakia. The highest coefficient is detected in the Czech Republic, meaning over-correction, since the value is higher than 1. Therefore, the speed of adjustment towards equilibrium is highest in Estonia, meaning that this small open economy using tax competition in the context of the EATR has succeeded in attracting FDI, converging towards equilibrium. On the other hand, the error-correction parameter is not significant in Cyprus, Hungary and Romania. The reason in the case of Cyprus can be found in the extremely high FDI inflow in the period from 2009 to 2015, achieving values of FDI inflow of 280% of GDP, which can not only be related to the lowering of the EATR. The high fluctuation of FDI inflows in Hungary parallel to the constant lowering of the EATR did not lead to a long-run relationship.
We could conclude that on average in the emerging EU economies, a long-run equilibrium relationship exists between the EATR and FDI, while adjustments towards equilibrium are heterogeneous in the context of speed and existence, namely in Cyprus, Hungary and Romania; that kind of adjustment is not confirmed.
Hypothesis (H2) is oriented towards the assumption that the speed of the adjustment to a long-run relationship between FDI inflow and the EATR is faster in emerging EU economies for the period 2004–2021 due to joining the EU. We repeated the whole procedure of estimation for the subsample of the 13 emerging EU economies for the period 2004–2021: (i) the results of the Pesaran CD test showed the existence of CSD in the subsample for the variables fdi’ and efec’ (Table 1, panel a); (ii) the Pesaran CIPS test indicated stationarity in first differences for variables (Table 1, panel b); (iii) Westerlund cointegration confirmed cointegration between fdi’ and efec’ (Table 1, panel c); (iv) using the PMG and MG estimates, the Hausman test showed that the preferred specification is PMG (Table 2). According to the results of the homogeneous coefficients, the long-run relationship between the variables fdi’ and efec’ is significant, while the average (homogeneous) error-correction parameter is higher in comparison to the whole sample; namely, the average speed of adjustment is 0.5745 for the period 2004–2021, while it is 0.5127 for the period 1998–2021 (Table 2). This result indicates that accession to the EU contributed to a faster achievement of the equilibrium relationship between FDI inflow and the EATR in the emerging EU economies. More precisely, Table 3 shows the dynamic of adjustment speed in each emerging EU economy. It is obvious that in almost all the economies higher values for the error-correction parameter are estimated. In Slovakia, the biggest increase in the error-correction parameter is noted, from 55.45% of adjustment in one year for the sample 1998–2021, to 77.94% in one year after joining the EU. On the other hand, in Malta and Lithuania the decrease in the error-correction parameter is identified after accession, while in Cyprus, Hungary and Romania the error-correction parameters are still insignificant.

5.2. Robustness Check

A robustness check of the results was undertaken using changed methods of estimation. We used the Dynamic Fixed Effects (DFE) model, since that method is appropriate for the analyzed sample. Although the DFE estimator restricts the coefficients of the cointegrating vector to be equal across all the panels, for example the PMG estimator, the DFE model also restricts the speed of the adjustment coefficient to be equal [44].
Similar to the results of the PMG estimation, according to the homogeneous parameters in the DFE model, the error-correction parameters are significant and negative showing adjustments towards long-run equilibrium. Once again, in both samples the error corrections estimated by DFE are significant, but in the period 2004–2021 are higher (Table 4). Although the same dynamic of adjustment is noted, the magnitude of the adjustments is slightly lower in the model estimated by the DFE estimator in comparison to PMG (42.03% against 51.97% in the period 1998–2021, while 48.02% against 57.45% in the period 2004–2021). Moreover, between the PMG and DFE estimators, the Hausman test indicates that PMG is preferred over the DFE model.
The robustness check using the DFE method of estimation showed that in the homogeneous part of the model the same relationship was significant, with the same sign and similar influence for the average of emerging EU economies. Hence, we could claim that the results are stable in both samples across different estimators.

5.3. FDI Inflow Determinants—Panel-Corrected Standard Error (PCSE) Estimator Results

In the previous analysis, we concluded that the variable FDI inflow (fdi and fdi’) and EATR (efec and efec’) are nonstationary and cointegrated, and that the sample is heterogeneous, containing cross-section dependence. In this part of the paper, the focus of the analysis is on the potential determinants of FDI in the period 2004–2021 for 13 emerging EU economies; therefore, the properties of those new variables in the analysis need to be checked. The same procedure is implemented in order to find out whether those variables are stationary and whether cross-section dependence exists in the data.
The results of the Pesaran CD test are presented in Table A2 (Appendix, panel a), which shows that the null hypothesis of cross-section independency has to be rejected in all variables. In the next step, the Pesaran CIPS panel unit root tests fail to reject the null hypothesis at a 5% significance level (Table A2, panel b), meaning that all the variables are non-stationary. In the next step, the stationarity of first differences is tested, and the results show that the variables are stationary in first differences with optimal lag length 1 (Akaike information criteria).
Due to the detected problem of the nonstationarity of variables and cross-section dependence in the variables, classical panel methods are limited. However, Beck and Katz [50] recommended the use of the Panel-corrected standard errors (PCSE) estimator, which allows for heteroskedastisity, autocorrelation and contemporaneous correlation across panels. Due to the detected problems of autocorrelation (Wooldridge test, BFN-DW, Baltagi-Li), heterokcedasticity (Wald test) and cross-section dependence (Pesaran CD test), a robust estimator, the PCSE estimator, is implemented based on Equation (4). The problem of nonstationarity is solved using the transformation of all the variables in terms of first differences (we add prefix “d” in order to emphasize the first difference of the variable).
Table 5 represents only the significant variables in the model: the EATR, GDP per capita, business environment variables and dummy variables representing outliers. It is expected that the reduction of the EATR provides FDI inflow, which is confirmed in the PSCE model with the negative sign and significant variable defec. Otherwise, an increase in the EATR would mean a reduction in the FDI inflow. The GDP per capita effects FDI positively; namely, an increase in variable dgdp promotes FDI inflow. Moreover, the business environmental variable “corruption” is significant in the model, showing a positive relationship with the FDI inflow; namely, each increase in the corruption index in the emerging EU economies increases the FDI inflow. On the other hand, the variables related to interest rates (short-run or long-run) are not significant in the model, as well as variables representing the level of competition. Namely, competition is already obtained in the model by the EATR, and therefore the variable competition index is not significant.
The extremely high FDI inflow in the period 2004–2008 is captured by the dummy variable for Malta, while the dummy variable for Hungary captures outliers in the years 2015 and 2016 in the context of an intensive reduction of the EATR. The variables dummy_H and dummy_M are significant in the model, showing that the reduction of taxes influenced inversely on FDI. Negative FDI inflow in Hungary is detected in 2015 and 2016, and further, Hungarian policymakers reacted with a sharp corporate tax reduction in 2017 from 19% to 9%, and consequently on the EATR. Although constant lowering of the EATR in Hungary is present, a high fluctuation of FDI inflows was identified, and therefore did not lead to a long-run relationship in PMG (Table 3) and represents an outlier in the PSCE model (Table 5). Similar to the case of Cyprus in the PMG model with an extremely high FDI inflow in the period 2009–2015, the increase in Malta’s FDI in the period 2004–2008 could not be related only and dominantly to the EATR reduction.
The findings represented in Table 5 might be interpreted as an acceptance of Hypothesis (H3) that the negative link between the EATR and FDI inflows is significant, and that variable EATR, GDP per capita, corruption index and the effects of global crisis are significant for decisions on investment allocation in the emerging EU economies.

6. Conclusions

Changes in the EATR and their impacts on FDI influx have been an important topic of debate amongst academics and policymakers, since there are divided opinions as to whether or not to pursue further corporate tax coordination against harmful competitiveness in the EU. This research contributes to the literature that analyzes the impacts of EATR changes on FDI localization by focusing on the emerging EU economies that typically have lower corporate tax rates and EATR in comparison to developed EU countries. The main findings of the paper can be summarized as follows: (i) The results of the dynamic panel models (PMG estimator) based on thirteen emerging EU economies for the period 1998–2021 show that a significant long-run relationship between EATR dynamics and FDI inflow exists [8]. Thus, speed of adjustment towards equilibrium is heterogeneous; in Estonia it is the highest, meaning that this small open economy using tax competition to lower the EATR has succeeded in attracting FDI, converging towards equilibrium. On the other hand, in Cyprus, Hungary and Romania that kind of adjustment is not confirmed. (ii) Using the PMG estimator for the period 2004–2021, it is confirmed that accession to the EU contributed to the faster achievement of an equilibrium relationship between the EATR and FDI influx in almost all the emerging EU economies due to easier capital, labor, goods and services movement between members [2]. Namely, Slovakia noticed the biggest increase in adjustment in one year after joining the EU compared to the sample 1998–2021, while Malta and Lithuania experienced the opposite result. Additionally, the long-run relationships in Cyprus, Hungary and Romania are insignificant. (iii) The Dynamic Fixed Effects (DFE) model is implemented as a robustness check since that method restricts the coefficients of the cointegrating vector to be equal across all panels, as well as restricting the speed of the adjustment coefficient to be equal. The DFE model confirmed the conclusions based on the PMG model, since the results show there are adjustments towards long-run equilibrium. However, the Hausman test indicated that PMG is preferred over the DFE model. (iv) Significant variables were also included in the PCSE model (EATR, GDP per capita, interest rates, business environment variables and dummy variables representing outliers). The PSCE model confirmed that a decrease in EATR generates FDI inflow, while GDP per capita effects FDI positively. Moreover, FDI inflow is positively influenced by the ‘corruption index’ as a business environmental variable since an increasing corruption index in emerging EU economies increases FDI inflow. Two dummy variables show that the reduction of taxes influenced FDI inversely. Namely, although in Hungary EATR cuts are present, a high fluctuation of FDI inflows is identified, and therefore a long-run relationship in PMG is not detected, representing an outlier in the PSCE model. The results for Cyprus and Malta could not be related only and dominantly to EATR reduction.
To sum up, the empirical analyses in the paper showed that tax competition in the emerging EU economies exists and is oriented towards FDI inflow. The downward pressures of the EATR were present during the period 1998–2021, meaning a race to a bottom, and moving away from tax coordination with the developed EU economies. Despite attempts by EU institutions to reduce harmful tax competition within the EU, most of the emerging EU economies have achieved considerable success by implementing the mentioned policy. Therefore, it is necessary for EU policymakers: (i) to further reconsider the harmfulness/advantages of tax competition in comparison to tax coordination, given that tax coordination can also negatively affect economies with lower tax rates [24], while success in FDI attraction is confirmed in this paper; (ii) to examine whether downward pressures and the lowering EATR tendency in the observed period could be characterized as a possibility for tax coordination within the EU but at lower tax levels, in order to prevent a further race to a bottom defining a floor for tax competitiveness in the EU.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, O.G., E.B.P. and M.B.; methodology, O.G. and S.S.; software O.G. and S.S.; validation O.G. and E.B.P.; formal analysis O.G.; investigation O.G. and M.B.; resources, O.G. and M.B.; data curation, O.G. and M.B.; writing—original draft preparation O.G. and M.B., writing—review and editing, O.G., E.B.P. and M.B., visualization, O.G. and E.B.P. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

The research is funded by the Provincial Secretariat for Higher Education and Scientific Research, Autonomous Province of Vojvodina, Republic of Serbia within the project: Coordination of Economic Policies in the Function of European Integration, number 142-451-2650/2021-01/2.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. Variables’ sources and description.
Table A1. Variables’ sources and description.
SymbolSampleDescriptionSource
fdi13 emerging EU economies; 1998–2021Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP)World Bank, World Development Indicators
fdi’13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2021
fdi_d13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2021Foreign direct investment, net inflows (current dollars)
efec13 emerging EU economies; 1998–2021Effective average tax rates, large corporations in non-financial sector (computed at corporate level, for average asset composition and funding sources), %Spengel, Christoph et al. (2019), Effective tax levels using the Devereux/Griffith methodology, Project for the EU Commission TAXUD/2019/DE/312;
Data are taken from Section C
efec’13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2021
sir13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2021Short-term interest rateOECD
lir13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2021Long-term interest rateOECD
GDP_pc13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2021Gross domestic product in current prices, million eurosEurostat
Comp13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2019Competitiveness index, consisting of 98 variables, based on twelve pillars: (1) institutions, (2) infrastructure, (3) adoption of ICT, (4) macroeconomic stability, (5) health, (6) workforce skills, (7) product market, (8) labor market, (9) financial system, (10) market size, (11) business dynamics and (12) ability to innovate.Trading economics
Corr13 emerging EU economies; 2004–2019Corruption index in public sector; 0—corruption at the highest level; 100—economy without corruption.Trading economics
Source: authors’ presentation.
Table A2. Pesaran CD test and Pesaran CIPS unit root test for FDI and potential determinants.
Table A2. Pesaran CD test and Pesaran CIPS unit root test for FDI and potential determinants.
Sample: 13 Emerging EU Economies, 2004–2021
(a)(b)
VariablesPesaran CD Testp-ValuesLagsPesaran (CIPS) Panel Unit Root Test in the Level;
Z( t - )-Stat.
p-ValuesPesaran (CIPS) Test at the First Differences;
Z( t - )-Stat.
p-Values
fdi_d10.480.0000−1.0810.140−5.3050.000
1−3.6810.000−6.6780.000
22.8210.998−3.3220.000
Fec1.990.0490−0.9730.165−5.0660.000
11.7620.961−1.2010.000
23.4091.000−4.6710.000
Corr6.740.0000−1.0370.150−5.6250.000
10.1640.565−0.2900.000
21.3490.9110.0790.532
Comp31.640.0000−1.3630.086−3.3300.000
1−0.0240.490−1.7650.039
2−3.5150.000−4.9330.000
GDP_pc17.660.0000−0.1610.436−13.0940.000
10.2510.599−4.0200.000
20.8160.793−1.5470.061
Sir14.610.0000−1.9740.024−7.4310.000
1−0.6850.753−2.8430.002
2−1.0960.137--
Lir15.530.0000−1.1460.126−6.4080.000
10.3020.619−2.9540.002
21.4780.930--
Source: authors’ own calculations.

References

  1. Nicodème, G. Corporate Tax Competition and Coordination in the European Union: What Do We Know? Where Do We Stand? European Commission: Brussels, Belgium, 2006; ISSN 1725-3187. [Google Scholar]
  2. Jakubiak, M.; Markiewicz, M. Regional Research Competition Capital Mobility and Tax Competition between Old and New EU Member State; CERGE-EI; Center for Social and Economic Research: Warsaw, Poland, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  3. Keuschnigg, C.; Loretz, S.; Winner, H. Tax Competition and Tax Coordination in the European Union: A Survey; Working Papers in Economics and Finance; No. 2014-04; University of Salzburg: Salzburg, Austria, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  4. Conconi, P.; Perroni, C.; Riezman, R. Is partial tax harmonization desirable? J. Public Econ. 2008, 92, 254–267. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  5. Helcmanovská, M.; Andrejovská, A. Tax Rates and Tax Revenues in the Context of Tax Competitiveness. J. Risk Financ. Manag. 2021, 14, 284. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Auerbach, A. Capital Income Taxation, Corporate Taxation, Wealth Transfer Taxes and Consumption Tax Reforms. In The Empirical Foundations of SupplySide Economics; The Becker Friedman Insitutute, University of Chicago: Chicago, IL, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  7. Barrios, S.; Nicodème, G.; Sanchez Fuente, A.J. Effective Corporate Taxation, Tax Incidence and Tax Reforms: Evidence from OECD Countries; Working Paper Series 5017; CESifo: Munich, Germany, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  8. Egger, P.; Loretz, S.; Pfaffermayr, M.; Winner, H. Bilateral effective tax rates and foreign direct, Investment. Int. Tax Public Financ. 2009, 16, 822–849. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Dornean, A.; Chiriac, I.; Rusu, V.D. Linking FDI and Sustainable Environment in EU Countries. Sustainability 2022, 14, 196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Dunning, J.H.; Zang, F. Foreign Direct Investment and the Locational Competitiveness of Countries. Transnatl. Corp. 2008, 17, 1. [Google Scholar]
  11. Dunning, J.H. The Global Economy, Domestic Governance, Strategies and Transnational Corporations: Interactions and Policy Implications. Transnatl. Corp. 1992, 1, 7–45. [Google Scholar]
  12. OECD. Tax Incentives and the Global Minimum Corporate Tax: Reconsidering Tax Incentives after the GloBE Rules; OECD Publishing: Paris, France, 2022. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Blechová, B. Effect of Different Corporate Income Tax Rates on Foreign Direct Investments within the European Union Single Market. Int. Atl. Econ. Soc. 2016, 22, 239–240. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Devereux, M.P.; Griffith, R.; Klemm, A. Corporate income tax reforms and international tax competition. Econ. Policy 2002, 17, 449–495. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Desaia, A.M.; Foley, C.F.; Hines, R.J., Jr. Foreign direct investment in a world of multiple taxes. J. Public Econ. 2003, 88, 2727–2744. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  16. Janeba, E. Corporate income tax competition, double taxation treaties, and foreign direct investment. J. Public Econ. 1993, 56, 311–325. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  17. Bellak, C.; Leibrecht, M. Do low corporate income tax rates attract FDI? Evidence from Eight Central- and East European Countries. Appl. Econ. 2009, 41, 2691–2703. [Google Scholar]
  18. Budryte, A. Corporate income taxation in Lithuania in the context of the EU. Res. Int. Bus. Financ. 2005, 19, 200–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Hong, Q.; Smart, M. Praise of Tax Havens: International Tax Planning and Foreign Direct Investment; Working Paper No. 1942; CESifo: Munich, Germany, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  20. Stewart, J. Corporation Tax: How Important is the 12. 5% Corporate Tax Rate in Ireland? Financ. Times 2011, 8, 12. [Google Scholar]
  21. Keightley, P.M.; Sherlock, F.M. The Corporate Income Tax System: Overview and Options for Reform. Congr. Res. Serv. 2014. [Google Scholar]
  22. de Mooij, R.A.; Nicodème, G. Corporate tax policy and incorporation in the EU. Int Tax Public Financ. 2008, 15, 478–498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  23. Baldwin, E.R.; Krugman, P. Agglomeration, Integration and Tax Harmonization; National Bureau of Economic Research: Cambridge, MA, USA, 2002; Available online: https://www.nber.org/papers/w9290 (accessed on 25 August 2022)Working Paper 9290.
  24. Gropp, R.; Kostial, K. The Disappearing Tax Base: Is Foreign Direct Investment Eroding Corporate Income Taxes? Working Paper 31; European Central Bank: Frankfurt, Germany, 2000. [Google Scholar]
  25. Sørensen, B.P. Company Tax Reform in the European Union. Int. Tax Public Financ. 2004, 11, 91–115. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  26. Wasserfallen, F. Political and Economic Integration in the EU: The Case of Failed Tax Harmonization. J. Common Mark. Stud. 2014, 52, 420–435. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Glavaški, O.; Beker Pucar, E. Fiscal Consolidation in the EU-28: Multiyear versus cold shower episodes. Econ. Horiz. 2020, 22, 17–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Bénassy-Quéré, A.; Fontagné, L.; Lahrèche-Révil, A. How Does FDI React to Corporate Taxation? Int. Tax Public Financ. 2005, 12, 583–603. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Anguelov, N. Lowering the Marginal Corporate Tax Rate: Why the Debate? Inst. Econ. Aff. 2017, 37, 213–228. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  30. Devereux, M.P.; Fuest, C. Corporate income tax coordination in the European Union. Transf. Eur. Rev. Labour Res. 2010, 16, 23–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Marques, M.; Pinho, C.; Menezes, M.T. The effect of international income shifting on the link between real investment and corporate taxation. J. Int. Account. Audit. Tax. 2019, 36, 100268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Gonzalez, A.; Qiang, C.Z.; Kusek, P. Foreign Investment Is a Major Contributor to Development Global Investment Competitiveness Report: Foreign Investor Perspectives and Policy Implications; The World Bank: Washington, DC, USA, 2017. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Hunady, J.; Orviska, M. Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment in EU Countries—Do Corporate Taxes Really Matter? Procedia Econ. Financ. 2014, 12, 243–250. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Andrašić, J.; Mirović, V.; Kalaš, B. Impact of Macroeconomic Factors on Foreign Direct Investment in Selected Southeastern European Countries. TEME 2018, 42, 1237–1251. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Ercegovac, D.; Beker, P.E. FDI Inflows in Selected Emerging European Economies with Reflections on Economic Growth. Ekonomika 2021, 67, 11–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Stanišić, N. Do Foreign Direct Investments Increase the Economic Growth of Southeastern European Transition Economies? South-East. Eur. J. Econ. 2008, 6, 28–29. [Google Scholar]
  37. Bevan, A.A.; Estrin, S. The determinants of foreign direct investment into European transition economies. J. Comperative Econ. 2004, 32, 775–787. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Walkenhorst, P. Economic Transition and the Sectoral Patterns of Foreign Direct Investment. Emerg. Mark. Financ. Trade 2004, 40, 5–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Ercegovac, D.; Beker, P.E. Greenfield FDI Inflows in Selected Emerging European Economies with Reflections on External Balance. In Proceedings of the 26th International Scientific Conference: Strategic Management and Decision Support Systems in Strategic Management, Subotica, Serbia, 21 May 2021. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. OECD. Tax Effects on Foreign Direct Investment. Policy Brief. Organ. Econ. Co-Oper. Dev. 2008. Available online: https://www.oecd.org/investment/investment-policy/40152903.pdf (accessed on 17 March 2022).
  41. Zubair, S.; Kabir, E.; Huang, X. Does the financial crisis change the effect of financing on investment? Evidence from private SMEs. J. Bus. Res. 2020, 110, 456–463. [Google Scholar]
  42. Álvarez-Martinez, M.T.; Salvador Barrios, S.; d’Andria, D.; Gesualdo, M.; Pontikakis, D.; Jonathan Pycroft, J. Modelling corporate tax reform in the EU: New calibration and simulations with the CORTAX model. Fisc. Policy Anal. Jt. Res. Cent. Seville Eur. Comm. 2016. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Ercegovac, D.; Beker, P.E. The nexus between FDI and external balance in selected Emerging European Economies—A panel data approach. Ann. Fac. Econ. Subot. 2022, 58, 147–164. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Blackburne, E.; Frank, M. Estimation of nonstationary heterogeneous panels. Stata J. 2007, 7, 197–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Pesaran, H.M.; Smith, R.P. Estimating long-run relations from dynamic heterogeneous panels. J. Econom. 1995, 68, 79–113. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Pesaran, H.; Shin, Y.; Smith, R. Pooled Mean Group Estimation of Dynamic Heterogeneous Panels. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 1999, 94, 621–634. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Im, K.S.; Pesaran, M.H.; Shin, Y. Testing for Unit Roots in Heterogeneous Panels. J. Econom. 2003, 115, 53–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Hausman, J.A. Specification Tests in Econometrics. Econometrica 1978, 46, 1251–1271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  49. Spengel, C.; Schmidt, F.; Heckemeyer, J.H.; Nicolay, K.; Bartholmeß, A.; Ludwig, C.; Steinbrenner, D.; Buchmann, P.; Bührle, A.T.; Dutt, V.; et al. Effective Tax Levels Using the Devereux/Griffith Methodology, Project for the EU Commission TAXUD/2019/DE/312: Final Report 2019, ZEW-Gutachten und Forschungsberichte; ZEW-Leibniz-Zentrum für Europäische Wirtschaftsforschung: Mannheim, Germany, 2019. [Google Scholar]
  50. Beck, N.; Katz, J. What to Do (and not to Do) with Time Series Cross-Section Data. Am. Political Sci. Rev. 1995, 89, 634–647. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Josifidis, K.; Mitrović, R.D.; Glavaški, O.; Supić, N. Public Policies Influence on Fiscal Deficit in the EU-28: Common Correlated Effects Approach. Hacienda Pública Española/Rev. Public Econ. 2018, 227, 63–101. [Google Scholar]
Figure 1. Effective average tax rates in emerging EU economies in the period 1998–2021. Source: Authors’ presentation based on data from trading economics.
Figure 1. Effective average tax rates in emerging EU economies in the period 1998–2021. Source: Authors’ presentation based on data from trading economics.
Sustainability 15 00227 g001
Figure 2. Inflow of FDI in emerging EU economies in the period 1998–2021. Source: Authors’ presentation on OECD database.
Figure 2. Inflow of FDI in emerging EU economies in the period 1998–2021. Source: Authors’ presentation on OECD database.
Sustainability 15 00227 g002
Table 1. Pesaran CD test, Pesaran CIPS test and Westerlund cointegration test (all estimations are carried out in Stata 15).
Table 1. Pesaran CD test, Pesaran CIPS test and Westerlund cointegration test (all estimations are carried out in Stata 15).
Sample: 13 Emerging EU Economies, Period 1998–2021
(a)(b)(c)
VariablesPesaran CD Testp-ValuesLagsPesaran (CIPS) Panel Unit Root Test in the Level;
Z( t - )-Stat.
p-ValuesPesaran (CIPS) Test at the First
Differences;
Z( t - )-Stat.
p-ValuesWesterlund Cointegration Testp-Value
fdi10.600.0000−4.4810.000−15.2590.000Gt−2.7240.000
10.7350.769−10.1400.000
21.1630.878−3.4920.000Ga−8.4610.000
efec27.560.0000−0.2030.419−11.6880.000
1−0.6500.258−6.6330.000Pt−6.8790.000
20.0520.521−4.8410.000Pa−5.2970.000
Sample: 13 emerging EU economies; period 2004–2021
fdi’11.240.0000−3.1080.001−12.4230.000Gt−2.6050.000
11.4510.927−7.1250.000
21.5990.945−6.0080.000Ga−6.3600.021
efec’4.760.0000−0.1250.450−11.5110.000
1−0.1790.429−4.4030.000Pt−6.1570.000
2−0.0810.468−2.7140.003Pa−4.1670.000
Source: authors‘ own calculations.
Table 2. The PMG and MG Estimator results for homogeneous coefficient for emerging EU economies in the periods 1998–2021 and 2004–2021.
Table 2. The PMG and MG Estimator results for homogeneous coefficient for emerging EU economies in the periods 1998–2021 and 2004–2021.
Sample: 13 Emerging EU Economies, Period 1998–2021
Dependent Variable: fdiLong-Run Equilibrium ( θ ) Error-Correction
( Φ i )
Δ l e f e c μ i
MGCoef.p-valueCoef.p-valueCoef.p-valueCoef.p-value
0.09540.869−0.59350.000−0.65400.3110.25360.084
PMG0.88260.003−0.51970.000−0.891320.099−0.54340.001
Hausman test statistic2.200.1383
Sample: 13 emerging EU economies; period 2004–2021; dependent variable fdi’
MG−4.08790.324−0.61800.000−0.61580.5782.33070.401
PMG2.30180.000−0.57450.000−1.41400.127−2.79840.000
Hausman test statistic2.200.1380
ARDL (1, 1)
Source: authors‘ own calculations.
Table 3. The PMG Estimator results for heterogeneous coefficient for emerging EU economies in the periods 1998–2021 and 2004–2021.
Table 3. The PMG Estimator results for heterogeneous coefficient for emerging EU economies in the periods 1998–2021 and 2004–2021.
Sample: 13 Emerging EU Economies; Period 1998–2021
Dependent Variable: fdi
Sample: 13 Emerging EU Economies; Period
2004–2021
Dependent Variable: fdi’
(a)(b)
PMG
Estimator
Error-Correction
( Φ i )
Δ l e f e c μ i Error-Correction
( Φ i )
Δ l e f e c μ i
Emerging EU EconomiesCoeff.p-ValueCoeff.p-ValueCoeff.p-ValueCoeff.p-ValueCoeff.p-ValueCoeff.p-Value
Bulgaria−0.29820.005−1.34140.087−0.18060.426−0.38380.001−2.02920.018−1.42790.016
Czech Republic−1.22640.000−3.49970.221−1.45120.208−1.42370.000−1.14110.670−7.52020.001
Estonia−0.91750.000−5.48330.001−0.54090.502−0.99660.000−8.81240.000−4.53570.003
Croatia−0.70370.000−0.38020.902−1.04410.135−0.73490.0021.95850.800−4.03080.016
Cyprus−0.15640.1240.67460.4940.33470.160−0.30950.1130.19050.918−0.35950.523
Latvia−0.51210.013−1.07320.452−0.63870.190−0.52380.017−3.24540.192−2.49000.042
Lithuania−0.54140.0080.01540.988−0.59340.245−0.31320.0410.82190.634−1.43830.193
Hungary−0.06460.6362.17540.4100.19490.247−0.22380.1601.27310.695−0.30070.626
Malta −0.39980.019−0.28530.9420.27290.577−0.38520.044−0.76310.852−1.63010.120
Poland−0.79300.000−1.85040.326−1.26480.100−0.80210.0010.77130.935−4.46010.010
Romania−0.21710.137−0.08560.900−0.36570.187−0.18050.227−0.13920.877−1.04260.197
Slovenia−0.37130.0230.68460.714−0.56970.183−0.41150.0420.40920.814−2.34230.085
Slovakia−0.55450.003−1.13770.557−1.21840.068−0.77940.002−7.67690.192−4.80040.013
Source: authors’ own calculations.
Table 4. Robustness check using Dynamic Fixed Effects Model vs. PMG for emerging EU economies in the periods 1998–2021 and 2004–2021.
Table 4. Robustness check using Dynamic Fixed Effects Model vs. PMG for emerging EU economies in the periods 1998–2021 and 2004–2021.
Sample: 13 Emerging EU Economies; Period 1998–2021
Dependent Variable: fdiLong-Run Equilibrium ( θ ) Error-Correction
( Φ i )
Δ l e f e c μ i
DFECoef.p-valueCoef.p-valueCoef.p-valueCoef.p-value
−0.10430.825−0.42030.000−0.23190.6280.82750.150
PMG0.88260.003−0.51970.000−0.891320.099−0.54340.001
Hausman test
statistic7.090.0077
Sample: 13 emerging EU economies; period 2004–2021
DFE1.12570.297−0.48020.000−0.73600.333−0.68800.633
PMG2.30180.000−0.57450.000−1.41400.127−2.79840.000
Hausman test
statistic71.190.000
ARDL (1, 1)
Source: authors‘ own calculations.
Table 5. PSCE Estimator for emerging EU economies in the period 2004–2021.
Table 5. PSCE Estimator for emerging EU economies in the period 2004–2021.
Robust Estimates—Panel-Corrected Standard Errors (PCSE)
Dependent Variable:
dfdi_d
Coef.Std. Errorp > (t)
Defec−1.66486.15890.007
Dgdp39807.8617138.550.020
Dcorr3.91112.02170.053
Cons1.06891.19880.371
dummy_M−1.90725.90770.001
dummy_H−7.57883.83170.048
R20.2042
Wald chi2132.150.000
Number of observations233
Source: authors‘ own calculations.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Glavaški, O.; Beker Pucar, E.; Beljić, M.; Stojkov, S. Coordination vs. Competitiveness of Effective Average Tax Rates in Relation to FDI: The Case of Emerging EU Economies. Sustainability 2023, 15, 227. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010227

AMA Style

Glavaški O, Beker Pucar E, Beljić M, Stojkov S. Coordination vs. Competitiveness of Effective Average Tax Rates in Relation to FDI: The Case of Emerging EU Economies. Sustainability. 2023; 15(1):227. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010227

Chicago/Turabian Style

Glavaški, Olgica, Emilija Beker Pucar, Marina Beljić, and Stefan Stojkov. 2023. "Coordination vs. Competitiveness of Effective Average Tax Rates in Relation to FDI: The Case of Emerging EU Economies" Sustainability 15, no. 1: 227. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010227

APA Style

Glavaški, O., Beker Pucar, E., Beljić, M., & Stojkov, S. (2023). Coordination vs. Competitiveness of Effective Average Tax Rates in Relation to FDI: The Case of Emerging EU Economies. Sustainability, 15(1), 227. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15010227

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop