4.1. Cooperative Relationship of Systematic Optimal Water Resource Allocation
Water use efficiency is the total output that can be obtained by unit allocation of water, including water use in economic and social aspects. If a socio-economic system can effectively allocate and use resources, it can be considered that the socio-economic system is efficient. In view of the complexity, dynamics and uncertainty of water supply and benefit relationship between upstream, middle and downstream provinces in the balanced allocation of water resources in the basin, in order to improve the utilization efficiency of water resources and maintain the stability of the whole basin ecosystem the initial allocation of water resources is carried out with the maximum overall benefit of water resources allocation, and the incremental benefits generated by the optimal system compared with the current individual and overall benefits are calculated. Different development levels will lead to different water resource utilization rates in different regions and different water use sectors. Accurate assessment of the comprehensive value of unit water use in different regions, such as life, industry, agriculture and ecology, is of great significance for in-depth understanding of water resource utilization efficiency. Taking maximum benefit of water resources utilization as objective function:
where
J is the calculation unit for the number of provinces or alliances in the basin;
Vk1 is the domestic water use benefit;
Vk2 is the industrial water use benefit;
Vk3 is the agricultural water use benefit; and
Vk4 is the ecological water use benefit.
Constraint conditions:
(1) Basin water balance constraints:
where
fu is upstream inflow;
fR is interval inflow;
fd is the downstream water intake;
fl is lost water such as evaporation.
(2) Water consumption constraint:
where
Cj,k is the water consumption of the
k industry of the
j calculation unit;
k is the industry number,
k = 1,2,3,4 are, respectively, life, industry, agriculture and ecology;
Gj is the upper limit of water consumption of the
j calculation unit.
(3) Reservoir constraints:
Water balance constraint:
where
is the initial and final storage capacity of reservoir
in period;
is the natural inflow of reservoir
in period
;
is the water supply of reservoir
in period
;
is the water loss of reservoir
in period
.
Reservoir storage constraint:
where
are the maximum and minimum allowable storage capacity of
reservoir in
period.
is generally dead storage,
is the maximum allowable storage capacity; in non-flood season, it is generally the storage capacity under normal storage level; in flood season, it is the storage capacity under flood control limited water level.
Water supply capacity constraint:
where
,
are the maximum and minimum water supply capacity of
reservoir in
period.
(4) Minimum ecological flow constraint:
where
Ep,t, Rp,t are the minimum ecological flow and actual flow in the
period of the p ecological control section.
4.2. Master–Slave Relationship between Water Resources Allocation Alliances
The Yellow River Basin passes through multiple provinces and regions which are called water users; these water users may form alliances with their upstream or downstream water users; domestic, industrial, agricultural and ecological water use in each alliance are called the water use sectors. The profit of alliance is determined by competition among water users. Limited by the flow direction, there are upstream, midstream and downstream relationships among water users, which is a master–slave game relationship dominated by upstream water users. Therefore, the water use strategy of the upstream water user will affect the decision of the midstream and downstream of the water user, and the water use strategy of the midstream and downstream also limits the upstream water use. In view of the complexity, dynamics and uncertainty of the upstream, midstream and downstream water supply and benefits of the balanced allocation of water resources in the basin, a basin system optimization problem with multi-layer hierarchical structure is established by applying the principle of master–slave game theory. The upstream, midstream and downstream water users form alliances, respectively, among which the upstream includes Qinghai, Sichuan, Gansu, Ningxia and Inner Mongolia; the midstream includes Shaanxi, Shanxi and Henan; and the downstream includes Shandong, Hebei and Tianjin. The locations and sections of the upstream, midstream and downstream of the Yellow River Basin are shown in
Figure 3.
In the allocation of water resources in public rivers, the alliance makes decisions in order. At this time, the alliance formed by the upstream water users first acts, and then the alliance formed by the midstream and downstream water users acts separately until all the decisions of the alliance are completed and the decision ends. However, each alliance has its own objective function and constraint conditions. The high-level objective function is not only related to the decision variables of this level, but also depends on the optimal solution of other low-level problems. The optimal solution of the low-level problem is affected by the high-level decision variables. If the structure of the alliance is {1}, {2}, {3}, that is, the upstream, middle and downstream compete with each other, then considering the upstream, middle and downstream of the three-level planning problem, a three-level master–slave game model of the upstream, middle and downstream is established to reveal the master–slave hierarchical relationship and dynamic correlation between the upstream, middle and downstream of the basin. The general form of the model is:
where
x ∈ Rn1, y∈ Rn2, z∈ Rn3, x,
y and
z are the decision variables in the upper, middle, and lower levels, respectively;
n1,
n2 and
n3 are the numbers of research objects in each level;
Bi(
x,y,z) (
i = 1,2,3) is the objective function of upstream, midstream and downstream, indicating the benefit of the
i participant when choosing strategy (
x,y,z);
ψi (
x,y,z) (
i = 1,2,3) is the constraint condition of each level. The upstream determines the water resources allocation strategy
according to the effective water demand of the water user and transmits it to the midstream model. The midstream water user decision reacts to the upstream decision
to determine its optimal water resources allocation decision
. Finally, the downstream reacts to the upstream decision
and the midstream decision
to determine its optimal water resources allocation decision
. After the above process is completed, the upstream decision is then adjusted according to the midstream and downstream decisions, and the midstream and downstream are adjusted according to the upstream, through the cycle of this process to finally achieve the optimal water allocation decision
for the whole system. The balance solution of this multi-stage dynamic game problem can be obtained, and then the balance water resource allocation scheme obtained by the master–slave relationship between the alliances can be determined. If the structure of the alliance is {1,2}, {3}, that is, the upstream and midstream alliances cooperate and compete with the downstream, then consider the upstream–midstream and downstream two-level planning problem and establish the upstream–midstream and downstream two-level master–slave game model. Then the objective function is:
The constraint conditions are the same as Formula (8). Formula (9) shows that the upstream and midstream alliance {1,2} as a water user first makes decisions, and the downstream alliance {3} will make its own decisions according to the decision of alliance {1,2}.
If the structure of the alliance is {1}, {2,3}, that is, the competition between the upstream alliance and the alliance formed in the midstream and downstream, similarly consider the two-level planning problem of the upstream and midstream–downstream and establish the master–slave game model of the upstream and midstream–downstream. The objective function is:
The constraint conditions are the same as Formula (8). Formula (11) shows that the upstream {1} as an alliance first decision, the middle and downstream {2,3} as an alliance will make their own alliance decisions according to the alliance {1} decision.
If the alliance structure is {1,2,3}, that is, the upstream, midstream and downstream form a large alliance, the whole basin cooperation, pay attention to the interests of the whole basin. The objective function is:
The constraint conditions are the same as Formula (8). The Formula (13) shows that the upstream, middle and downstream water users form an alliance {1,2,3}, and stakeholders pay more attention to the maximization of their own interests, while watershed managers pay more attention to the maximum interests of the whole basin.
4.3. Incremental Benefit Allocation Based on Fuzzy Cooperative Game
Social and economic interests, environmental interests or the benefits brought by the basin itself can be managed in various regions and departments to promote regional cooperation and assess possible local cooperation. Different cooperation scenarios between the alliances allocate the benefits of water use for the alliance, which directly affects the stability of the alliance. The larger the core size, the greater the benefits, indicating that cooperation can bring some benefits. The difference between the benefits generated by alliance cooperation and the allocation of basic water resources is called incremental benefit ΔB.
Cooperative game means that the interests of both sides of the game have increased, or at least one party’s interests have increased and the interests of the other party are not damaged, so the interests of the whole society have increased. At the same time, the cooperative game studies how to allocate the benefits of cooperation, that is, income distribution. The Shapley value method of cooperative game is a game analysis method used to solve the cooperative countermeasures of multiple subjects. The contribution degree of each cooperative subject to its cooperative alliance reflects the importance of each member in the cooperation, and the contribution degree of each cooperative subject is used to allocate the cooperative benefits, which is an effective method to solve the distribution of cooperative benefits. In the conventional alliance (upstream, midstream and downstream alliance) it is required that the players (provinces) of the alliance carry all their resources to participate in a certain alliance, and the benefits of a player in the alliance depend on its contribution to the alliance. In the fuzzy alliance (Aubin, 1974), the player only needs to carry part of the resources (domestic, industry, agriculture, ecological water resources) to participate in each alliance, and the income is equal to the sum of the income obtained by participating in each alliance. Fuzzy alliance does not require the players to carry all the resources they own to participate in a certain alliance, but it allows them to carry some resources to participate in different alliances; that is, fuzzy alliance is to participate in different alliances with different participation rates. In this paper, the fuzzy cooperative alliance is used to allocate incremental benefits. The water use sector can participate in multiple cooperative alliances at the same time, and the water resources obtained in the initial allocation are dispersed in all the cooperative alliances that it participates in. Each water user carries a certain amount of water resources to participate in different fuzzy alliances, and the water resources of each water user will be redistributed among different fuzzy alliances, forming a fuzzy alliance of water resources cooperation in the region. The research on the distribution of the increase in revenue ΔB among the players improves the stability of cooperation among the alliances, realizes the cooperation and interaction of water resources in the distribution, and finally reaches a dynamic balance state.
In this paper, upstream alliance, midstream alliance and downstream alliance are represented by
A,
B and
C; industrial, agricultural and ecological sectors are represented by water use sectors 1, 2 and 3, then water use sectors of different alliances are represented by
,
,
. Assuming that the amount of water resources transfer is
w, the amount of water resources transfer in each water use sector is:
;
;
, and satisfy:
Then the benefit functions in the transfer-out area
A and the transfer-in area
B or
C are expressed as;
, respectively.
Because the water use benefit of the upstream, middle and downstream of the Yellow River is different, the total benefit of all participants in the transfer of water resources is set to
, namely:
Each player can participate in multiple water resources cooperation coalitions at the same time, and the members of the coalition share water resources cooperation and distribute water benefits. Let
denote a fuzzy alliance of water resources cooperation in the basin, where
denotes the participation rate of the
i water user in alliance
s,
;
V(
s) is the benefit of alliance
s. In order to make the target
T optimal, that is, to maximize the overall benefit of the basin, the objective function is:
The constraint condition is:
where
Vi(
s) is the benefit of the
i water user acting alone to participate in the water resources of alliance
s;
b(
i) is the benefit of the unit water volume of the
i water user;
wi is the amount of water initially allocated by the
i water user in the alliance.
where
V(
s) is the benefit of the alliance
s;
B(s) is the benefit generated by unit of water in the alliance s;
W(
s) is the amount of water resources carried by the water users participating in the alliance
s;
Q(
s) is the maximum demand of alliance s for water resources; other symbols are the same as above.
Each water user carries a certain amount of water resources to participate in different fuzzy alliances, the goal is to maximize the benefits of the whole basin system, and then the incremental benefits ΔB generated by the alliance cooperation to maximize the benefits are distributed among the players, and the fairness and efficiency of water use are integrated to achieve the balanced allocation of water resources in the basin. Therefore, the benefits distribution method based on fuzzy Shapley value is a fair and just distribution method. The application of fuzzy Shapley value method to benefit distribution of trans-regional shared water resources needs to meet at least two conditions:
The cooperation benefits obtained by the combination of subsets is more than that obtained by the action of each subset alone, namely:
where
n represents the number of participants in the cooperative game, and
is the set of n participants. For any coalition s of
N, it corresponds to a real value function
V(s), and
V(s) denotes the benefits obtained by coalition s when there is cooperation among participants.
The benefits of each participant from cooperation are greater than those from their individual actions.
where
is the income of the ith water user participating in the alliance
S.
When each participant participates in cooperation, Shapley value can be obtained by the following formula:
where
represents the benefits brought to the cooperative alliance due to the participation of participant
i;
is a weighting factor as the weight assigned under different combinations.
represents the number of alliance
S elements.
Since the cooperative game satisfies superadditivity, the total fuzzy benefit of each water user is equal to the sum of the benefits obtained from each alliance, namely:
where
L(s) is the set of fuzzy coalitions of water resources cooperation, and other formulas have the same meaning as above.