Next Article in Journal
Effect and Mechanism of Environmental Decentralization on Pollution Emission from Pig Farming—Evidence from China
Next Article in Special Issue
The Effects of Experienced Utility and PEEIM on the Purchase Intention of Cross-Border E-Commerce
Previous Article in Journal
Impact of Pavement Defects on Traffic Operational Performance
Previous Article in Special Issue
Understanding Customer Preferences of Delivery Services for Online Grocery Retailing in South Korea
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Research on the Regulation of Algorithmic Price Discrimination Behaviour of E-Commerce Platform Based on Tripartite Evolutionary Game

School of Computer and Information Engineering, Harbin University of Commerce, Harbin 150028, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2023, 15(10), 8294; https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108294
Submission received: 5 March 2023 / Revised: 4 May 2023 / Accepted: 17 May 2023 / Published: 19 May 2023
(This article belongs to the Special Issue E-commerce and Sustainability (Second Volume))

Abstract

:
With the development of the digital economy, the algorithms and big data technologies of e-commerce platforms have gradually turned into double-edged swords. While realising personalised recommendations, they also provide information technology support for the use of algorithmic prices to discriminate and extract residual value from consumers. Consumers frequently use Black Cat and third-party media to complain, resulting in a significant negative impact. Therefore, in order to regulate algorithmic price discrimination, using e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers act as game subjects, taking an evolutionary game approach. We analyse the impact of different situations and factors on the system’s evolutionary stability strategy and conduct its verification via simulation experiments. This study shows that several measures, such as increasing cooperation with the media; establishing clear regulatory rules to reduce the extent of algorithmic price discrimination and the grey revenue of e-commerce platforms; establishing a long-term mechanism for consumer feedback; improving rewards and punishments to increase the probability of successful regulation and penalties by local governments; sharing information to reduce the cost of consumer regulation; and setting reasonable bonus thresholds based on government revenue and consumer regulation costs, can effectively regulate algorithmic price discrimination and promote the sustainable development of e-commerce platforms.

1. Introduction

In the context of the digital economy, e-commerce platforms are able to analyse consumer behaviour data to understand their interest preferences to achieve personalised recommendations, thereby increasing consumer stickiness and order turnover [1]. However, they also provide data to support the use of algorithms for price discrimination [2]. According to the results of a survey conducted by the Beijing Consumers’ Association in 2022 , more than 86.91 % of consumers have been “discriminated” against by e-commerce platforms based on algorithmic pricing. The platforms discriminate against consumers based on their frequency of consumption and personal information in order to extract residual value from consumers via algorithmic pricing [3].
Algorithmic price discrimination has gradually attracted national attention. The Anti-Monopoly Committee of the State Council in its Anti-Monopoly Guidelines for the Platform Economy focuses on the certification factors for algorithmic price discrimination; the State Administration for Market Regulation of China incorporated algorithmic price discrimination into the Provisions on Administrative Punishment for Price Violations in January 2021 , which impose fines and revoke business licenses for e-commerce platforms that violate the provisions. Although government regulators have regulated price discrimination on platforms, platforms still have a fluke mentality and repeatedly use algorithms to discriminate on price in order to make high profits. A search for price discrimination on the Black Cat complaint platform, shows that there are still 692 complaints recorded in 2022 , and statistics show that at least 80 % of them are about price discrimination on e-commerce platforms such as Taobao, Jingdong and Meituan. If algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms is not effectively regulated, it will result in a winner-takes-all monopoly situation, leading consumers to question the fairness of e-commerce product prices, and once consumer trust is lost, it is difficult to regain, which will have irreversible negative effects [4,5].
Therefore, this paper aims to simulate the impact of different factors on the regulation of algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms using an evolutionary game approach. This is validated by simulation experiments, and, then, targeted countermeasures are proposed for the effective regulation of algorithmic price discrimination. This paper is of great practical significance for maintaining consumer fairness, increasing consumer trust and promoting the sustainable development of the e-commerce industry.

2. Literature Review

At present, many scholars have studied various aspects of algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms, including the mechanisms at play and behavioural regulation measures.
In terms of the mechanism of algorithmic price discrimination, the pricing of e-commerce products is an important factor affecting consumers’ purchasing decisions, enterprises and platform revenues [6], and e-commerce platforms are typical market-creating bilateral markets with strong network externalities [7]. Moderate secondary and tertiary price discrimination can increase social welfare and achieve a win–win situation for all parties [8]. However, with the development of big data, algorithms and other technologies, firms are increasingly dependent on them when formulating price strategies [9]. Many experts and scholars believe that the algorithmic price discrimination practiced by e-commerce platforms is close to primary price discrimination [10], in which the algorithm can dynamically achieve “a thousand prices for a thousand people” [11] so as to maximize the payment price per unit of consumer demand while the platforms increase their own benefits and choose to ignore the social responsibility they should bear [12]. At this time, consumers will spend more time and energy to compare product prices, which will significantly affect consumers’ purchase decisions [13]. Consumers have a preference for price fairness [14] and an aversion to privacy intrusion [15], and once they find that prices are unfair, a strong sense of betrayal will arise [16], and they will take action to complain and expand the influence of social opinion [17].
The regulation of the algorithmic price discrimination behaviour of e-commerce platforms is a dynamic and continuous process with multiple influencing factors [18]. Evolutionary games believe that the subject of the game is limited and rational and can effectively analyse the influencing factors in the decision-making process, continuously learn and improve the game strategy [19,20], and finally approach the equilibrium state [21]. They have been widely used in environmental protection [22,23], finance [24,25], medicine [26,27], management [28,29] and other fields. Evolutionary games are consistent with the actual process of behaviour regulation [30,31,32]. Some scholars have applied evolutionary games to the study of algorithmic price discrimination regulation measures: Wu Bin [33] constructs an evolutionary game model between the government and e-commerce platforms, arguing that increasing government penalties can effectively motivate the government to actively regulate and transform the algorithmic price discrimination strategy of e-commerce platforms; Pan Ding [34] argues that consumers are disadvantaged when experiencing algorithmic price discrimination, and, therefore, constructs an evolutionary game model between e-commerce enterprises and the government to consider the optimal strategy choice between traditional and big data regulation methods under the role of different contextual influence coefficients. However, e-commerce platforms have the advantage of asymmetric data information [35] and opaque algorithms [36]. Meanwhile, the government’s single-party regulatory capacity is limited [37], makes it difficult to effectively monitor and regulate their algorithmic price discrimination behaviours [38]. As actual purchasers of products and services, consumers are more price-sensitive [39], and consumers, as stakeholders, can use their social graph radiation to amplify perceived unfair pricing information and compete with algorithmic price discrimination [40]. Therefore, Xing Genshang [41] considers the evolutionary game between consumers and e-commerce platforms on both sides when consumers have the right to data portability and explores the regulation strategy of algorithmic price discrimination behaviour from the user’s perspective.
In summary, the existing research takes the mechanism of algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms as the starting point, revealing its negative impact and affirming the need to regulate algorithmic price discrimination [42]. It uses evolutionary games to analyse the strategy choices of the participants in different situations and proposes targeted recommendations for measures to regulate algorithmic price discrimination [34,35,41].
However, on one hand, the practice has shown that the role of consumer co-regulation in the process of regulating algorithmic price discrimination cannot be ignored, and existing studies often only consider the game between the government and the platform, and the consumer and the platform, and only consider the third party as an influential factor in the game, ignoring the complex interests of the three parties in reality. On the other hand, due to the non-disclosure of platform algorithms, the concealment of dynamic algorithmic price discrimination, it is not always possible for government and consumer regulation to detect algorithmic price discrimination by the platforms [43]. Further consideration needs to be given to the probability of the government and consumers detecting algorithmic price discrimination at the time of regulation and the equilibrium strategy choices of the three parties involved in different contexts.
Therefore, this paper will construct a three-party evolutionary game model of e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers. We comprehensively analyse the evolutionary stabilisation strategies of the three parties involved under the roles of the e-commerce platform’s algorithmic price discrimination strength, the probability of government regulation discovering price discrimination and the consumers’ price fairness preferences and collaborative regulation with the government. We verify these strategies numerically by substituting simulation experiments and analyse the influence of each factor on the equilibrium state of the system. Finally, the conclusions obtained are combined with recommendations for the regulation of price discrimination in e-commerce platforms.
The contribution and innovation of this paper is to consider the complex interests of e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers and, to a certain extent, to broaden the research horizon of algorithmic price discrimination in e-commerce platforms. In addition, the probability of finding algorithmic price discrimination is also considered, making the study more relevant.

3. Basic Assumptions and Model Construction

3.1. Description of the Problem

The process of regulating algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms is complex. Squeezed consumers have no right to enforce the law and can only defend their rights with public opinion. The lower bargaining power often leads to switch channels of consumption. If only local governments were to regulate, on the one hand, the algorithmic black box of e-commerce platforms would make government regulation difficult, and the marginal utility of regulation would be low. On the other hand, algorithmic discrimination could significantly increase the economic revenue of e-commerce platforms, which in turn would, to a certain extent, drive local economic development and increase local government tax revenues. Without the introduction of third-party regulation, local governments may easily choose to collude with e-commerce platforms and turn a blind eye to their short-sighted use of algorithmic price discrimination. That will result in e-commerce platforms recklessly extracting residual value from consumers, causing consumers to lose trust in the platforms and local governments, undermining the credibility of the government and hindering the sustainable development of the e-commerce industry.
Therefore, this paper treats the finite rational e-commerce platform, the local government and the consumers as the three parties involved in the game. Based on the parametric assumptions, a payoff matrix is built, and the replicated dynamic system is constructed and solved according to the expected payoffs. The evolutionary equilibrium state strategy is studied as it continuously learns and improves its own strategy. The game relationship between the participating subjects is shown in Figure 1 below.

3.2. Basic Assumptions

In order to analyse the strategic choices of the e-commerce platforms, the local governments and the consumers in the evolutionary game, the following assumptions are made to ensure that the nature of the actual problem remains unchanged:
Hypothesis 1.
Assume that the e-commerce platform ( P ) has a strategy space of (algorithmic price discrimination, non-algorithmic price discrimination), for which the corresponding choice probability is  ( x , 1 x )  and  0 < x < 1 . Let the normal revenue of the e-commerce platform when it chooses not to use algorithmic price discrimination be  Δ R P  and the additional revenue gained by using algorithmic price discrimination to extract the residual value of consumers be  Δ R P . The daily operation and maintenance cost of the platform is  C P 1 , and the additional technical cost of algorithmic price discrimination is  C P 2 . When algorithmic price discrimination by an e-commerce platform is revealed, it leads to a variety of losses  L P 1  such as reduced reputation, weakened network externalities for loyal consumers and a reduced horse-trading effect for new users.
Hypothesis 2.
Assume that the strategy space of the local government ( G ) is (positive regulation, negative regulation) and that its corresponding choice probability is  ( y , 1 y )  and  0 < y < 1 . Let the tax rate levied by the local government for the e-commerce platform be  g , while its tax is positively related to the revenue of the e-commerce platform. When the local government chooses to actively regulate the cost of technology and manpower, it is represented as  C G 1 . If the local government conspires with the e-commerce platform and chooses to negatively regulate its algorithmic price discrimination, it will bear the burden of declining public trust and accountability penalties from the central government total  L G 1 . When consumers discover that the platform is practicing algorithmic price discrimination and choose a collaborative regulatory strategy to actively report it to the local government, if the local government chooses a negative regulatory strategy, consumers will feel unjust because they have paid the time and energy costs but have no way to complain and have not allowed the platform to receive its due, which will lead to a decline in the credibility of the local government  L G 2 . Conversely, the reputation of local governments will be enhanced when they collaborate with consumers to regulate algorithmic discrimination  R G ; if local governments find that e-commerce platforms are using algorithmic price discrimination in their regulation, they will be penalised with fines  F  and will be required to pay compensation to consumers for the price difference  D .
Hypothesis 3.
Assume that the strategy space for consumers (  C ) is (positive regulation, negative regulation) and their corresponding choice probability is  ( z , 1 z ) , and  0 < z < 1 . Let the consumer’s expected price for the product sold by the e-commerce platform be  P C . When the platform does not carry out algorithmic price discrimination, the price of the product is  P 1  because the platform cannot accurately obtain the expected price of consumers, and, in order to expand product sales, generally  P 1 < P C , the benefits to consumers when the platform does not practice algorithmic price discrimination are  R C 1  ( R C 1 = P C P 1 ). Alternatively, if the platform implements algorithmic price discrimination, with the help of algorithms, big data technology will have the ability to achieve a thousand different prices for a thousand different people. At this point, the product price converges to  P C ; that is, when the platform implements algorithmic price discrimination, the consumer’s benefit  R C  tends to 0. If consumers choose to actively regulate the platform, they will collect evidence and report to the local government if they find algorithmic price discrimination, which will cost them time and effort  C C 1 , and they will receive a bonus  S  from the local government for actively cooperating with the platform.
Hypothesis 4.
Let the degree of algorithmic price discrimination implemented by the platform be  φ  ( φ = P C P 1 P 1 = P C P 1 1 , the implementation of algorithmic price discrimination product premium to the normal price ratio). In order to be realistic and not to lose generality, the additional revenue, additional technical costs, losses, fines and price difference compensation from the platform algorithmic price discrimination are positively related to the degree of algorithmic price discrimination. When algorithmic price discrimination is implemented on a platform, let the consumer’s price fairness preference be  α . A higher preference means that the more concerned about price fairness, the greater the likelihood of detecting algorithmic price discrimination when actively regulated. Let the probability of detecting algorithmic price discrimination when actively regulated by the government be  β . When consumers and the government collaborate in regulation, the probability of being able to effectively detect algorithmic price discrimination on a platform is 1 (  α < 1 ,  β < 1 ).

3.3. Model Construction

Based on the above assumptions, the tripartite evolutionary game model payoff matrix is constructed as shown in Table 1:
From the matrix of payment benefits, the following can be drawn:
The expected benefits of algorithmic price discrimination U P 1 , the expected benefits of non-algorithmic price discrimination U P 2 and the average expected benefits of the e-commerce platforms U P ¯ are as follows:
U P 1 = y z ( ( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 φ ( F + D ) L P 1 ) + y ( 1 z ) ( ( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 β ( φ ( F + D ) + L P 1 ) ) + ( 1 y ) z ( ( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 α L P 1 ) + ( 1 y ) ( 1 z ) ( ( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 )
U P 2 = y z ( ( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1 ) + y ( 1 z ) ( ( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1 ) + ( 1 y ) z ( ( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1 ) + ( 1 y ) ( 1 z ) ( ( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1 )
U P ¯ = x U P 1 + ( 1 x ) U P 2
The replication dynamics equation for e-commerce platforms is
F P ( x ) = d x d t = x ( 1 x ) { y [ z ( ( α + β 1 ) L P 1 + ( β 1 ) φ ( F + D ) ) β ( φ ( F + D ) + L P 1 ) ] z α L P 1 + ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 }
The expected benefits of active regulation U G 1 , the expected benefits of passive regulation U G 2 and the average expected benefits for local governments U G ¯ are as follows:
U G 1 = x z ( g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C G 1 + φ F + R G S ) + x ( 1 z ) ( g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C G 1 + β φ F ) + ( 1 x ) z ( g R P 1 C G 1 S + R G ) + ( 1 x ) ( 1 z ) ( g R P 1 C G 1 )
U G 2 = x z ( g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) L G 1 α L G 2 ) + x ( 1 z ) ( g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) L G 1 ) + ( 1 x ) z ( g R P 1 L G 1 ) + ( 1 x ) ( 1 z ) ( g R P 1 L G 1 )
U G ¯ = y U G 1 + ( 1 y ) U G 2
The replication dynamics equation for local governments is
F G ( y ) = d y d t = y ( 1 y ) x z ( φ F β φ F + α L G 2 ) + β φ F + z ( R G S ) + L G 1 C G 1
The expected benefits of consumers’ choice of regulation U C 1 , the expected benefits of negative regulation U C 2 and the average expected benefits U C ¯ are as follows:
U C 1 = x y ( φ D C C 1 + S ) x ( 1 y ) C C 1 + ( 1 x ) y ( R C 1 C C 1 + S ) + ( 1 x ) ( 1 y ) ( R C 1 C C 1 )
U C 2 = x y β φ D + ( 1 x ) y R C 1 + ( 1 x ) ( 1 y ) R C 1
U C ¯ = z U C 1 + ( 1 z ) U C 2
The replication dynamics equation for consumers is
F C ( z ) = d z d t = z ( 1 z ) x y φ D ( 1 β ) + y S C C 1

4. Analysis of System Evolutionary Stabilisation Strategies

According to the stability theorem of the differential equation, if d F P ( x ) d x < 0 , d F G ( y ) d y < 0 , d F C ( z ) d z < 0 , it means that the e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers tend to stabilise their strategic choices and develop the analysis as follows:

4.1. Analysis of the Stability of E-Commerce Platform Strategies

A first order derivative of the replication dynamics equation for the e-commerce platforms gives the following equation:
d F P ( x ) d x = ( 1 2 x ) { y [ z ( ( α + β 1 ) L P 1 + ( β 1 ) ( φ F + φ D ) ) β ( φ ( F + D ) + L P 1 ) ] z α L P 1 + ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 }
Conclusion 1: When y = z α L P 1 ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P + φ C P 2 z ( α + β 1 ) L P 1 + ( β 1 ) ( φ F + φ D ) β ( φ F + L P 1 + φ D ) (for convenience, it is written it as ϕ 1 ), if 0 < ϕ 1 < 1 and d F P ( x ) d x 0 , the e-commerce platforms are in a stable strategy state regardless of the value of x .
Conclusion 2: When 0 < y < ϕ 1 < 1 , d F P ( x ) d x | x = 0 < 0 and d F P ( x ) d x | x = 1 > 0 , then x = 0 is the stable strategy state. This means that e-commerce platforms will not engage in algorithmic price discrimination when the probability of local governments choosing to regulate is below the threshold ϕ 1 .
Conclusion 3: When 0 < ϕ 1 < y < 1 , d F P ( x ) d x | x = 0 > 0 and d F P ( x ) d x | x = 1 < 0 , then x = 1 is the stable strategy state. This means that e-commerce platforms will engage in algorithmic price discrimination when the probability of local governments choosing to regulate is above the threshold ϕ 1 . The phase diagram of the spatial evolution of e-commerce platforms‘ strategies is shown in Figure 2.

4.2. Analysis of the Stability of Local Government Strategies

A first order derivative of the replication dynamic equation for local governments gives the following equation:
d F G ( y ) d y = ( 1 2 y ) x z ( φ F β φ F + α L G 2 ) + β φ F + z ( R G S ) + L G 1 C G 1
Conclusion 1: When x = z ( R G S ) L G 1 + C G 1 z ( φ F β φ F + α L G 2 ) + β φ F (for convenience, it is written as ϕ 2 ), if 0 < ϕ 2 < 1 and d F G ( y ) d y 0 , the local governments are in a stable strategy state regardless of the value of y .
Conclusion 2: When 0 < x < ϕ 2 < 1 , d F G ( y ) d y | y = 0 < 0 and d F G ( y ) d y | y = 1 > 0 , then y = 0 is the stable strategy state. This means that local governments will adopt a negative regulatory strategy when the probability of e-commerce platforms choosing to price discriminate is below the threshold ϕ 2 .
Conclusion 3: When 0 < ϕ 2 < x < 1 , d F G ( y ) d y | y = 0 > 0 and d F G ( y ) d y | y = 1 < 0 , then y = 1 is the stable strategy state. This means that local governments adopt an active regulatory strategy when the probability of e-commerce platforms choosing to price discriminate is above the threshold ϕ 2 . The phase diagram of the spatial evolution of local governments’ strategies is shown in Figure 3.

4.3. Analysis of the Stability of Consumer Strategies

A first order derivative of the replication dynamic equation for consumers gives the following equation:
d F C ( z ) d z = ( 1 2 z ) x y D ( 1 β ) + y S C C 1
Conclusion 1: When x = C C 1 y S y φ D ( 1 β ) (for convenience, it is written as ϕ 3 ), if 0 < ϕ 3 < 1 and d F C ( z ) d z 0 , the consumers are in a stable strategy state regardless of the value of z .
Conclusion 2: When 0 < x < ϕ 3 < 1 , d F C ( z ) d z | z = 0 < 0 and d F C ( z ) d z | z = 1 > 0 , then z = 0 is the stable strategy state. This means that consumers will adopt a negative regulatory strategy when the probability of e-commerce platforms choosing to price discriminate is below the threshold ϕ 3 .
Conclusion 3: When 0 < ϕ 3 < x < 1 , d F C ( z ) d z | z = 0 > 0 and d F C ( z ) d z | z = 1 < 0 , then z = 1 is the stable strategy state, This means that consumers will adopt an active regulatory strategy when the probability of e-commerce platforms choosing to price discriminate is above the threshold ϕ 3 . The phase diagram of the spatial evolution of consumers’ strategies is shown in Figure 4.

4.4. Stability Analysis of Tripartite Evolutionary Game System

The simultaneous Formulas (4), (8) and (12) form a system of replication dynamic equations, and when F P ( x ) , F G ( y ) , F C ( z ) is 0 , there are 8 local stability points for pure strategies and 1 local equilibrium point for mixed strategies in the three-dimensional interval of S = { ( x , y , z ) | 0 x 1 , 0 y 1 , 0 z 1 } , which include E 1 ( 0 , 0 , 0 ) , E 2 ( 0 , 1 , 0 ) , E 3 ( 0 , 0 , 1 ) , E 4 ( 0 , 1 , 1 ) , E 5 ( 1 , 0 , 0 ) , E 6 ( 1 , 1 , 0 ) , E 7 ( 1 , 0 , 1 ) , E 8 ( 1 , 1 , 1 ) and E 9 ( ϕ 1 , ϕ 2 , ϕ 3 ) .
The partial derivatives of x ,   y ,   z for the replicated dynamic equations and the Jacobian matrix are obtained as follows:
J = F P ( x ) x F P ( x ) y F P ( x ) z F G ( y ) x F G ( y ) y F G ( y ) z F C ( z ) x F C ( z ) y F C ( z ) z
Among them:
  • F P ( x ) x = ( 1 2 x ) { y [ z ( ( α + β 1 ) L P 1 + ( β 1 ) ( φ F + φ D ) ) β ( φ F + L P 1 + φ D ) ] z α L P 1 + ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 } ;
  • F P ( x ) y = x ( 1 x ) [ z ( ( α + β 1 ) L P 1 + ( β 1 ) ( φ F + φ D ) ) β ( φ F + L P 1 + φ D ) ] ;
  • F P ( x ) z = x ( 1 x ) { y [ ( α + β 1 ) L P 1 + ( β 1 ) ( φ F + φ D ) ] α L P 1 } ;
  • F G ( y ) x = y ( 1 y ) [ z ( φ F β φ F + α L G 2 ) + β φ F ] ;
  • F G ( y ) y = ( 1 2 y ) { x [ z ( φ F β φ F + α L G 2 ) + β φ F ] + z ( R G S ) + L G 1 C G 1 } ;
  • F G ( y ) z = y ( 1 y ) { x ( φ F β φ F + α L G 2 ) + R G S } ;
  • F C ( z ) x = z ( 1 z ) [ y φ D ( 1 β ) ] ;
  • F C ( z ) y = z ( 1 z ) [ x φ D ( 1 β ) + S ] ;
  • F C ( z ) z = ( 1 2 z ) { x [ y φ D ( 1 β ) ] + y S C C 1 } .
Since E 9 ( ϕ 1 , ϕ 2 , ϕ 3 ) makes T r ( J ) = 0 , which is the centre point, it does not reach a steady state, and only the stability of the 8 pure strategy local equilibrium points is discussed. According to the Lyapunov first law, if all λ < 0 in the corresponding points of the Jacobian matrix, the point is the stable equilibrium point of the system. If all λ > 0 , the point is unstable. If there is both λ < 0 and λ > 0 , it is a saddle point. The calculated characteristic values of each point are shown in Table 2.
Since the corresponding scenario of the local equilibrium point feature value of the pure strategy is more complex, in order to facilitate analysis and be as close to the actual life situation as possible, and without considering the impact of government and consumer punishment measures, when the e-commerce platform carries out algorithmic price discrimination, the additional benefits obtained far exceed the benefits when there is no algorithmic price discrimination, which is represented as ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 > 0 . The cost of active supervision by local governments is less than the penalties imposed by negative supervision, which is represented as L G 1 C G 1 > 0 ; Moreover, the bonus given by local governments to consumers for active collaborative supervision is less than the reputation-enhancing benefits brought by cooperation, which is represented as S R g < 0 .
When ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 < β ( φ F + φ D + L P 1 ) , when the excess grey income obtained by the e-commerce platform from algorithmic price discrimination is less than the sum of the fines levied by active supervision and the consumer network externalities lost by the platform, it can effectively promote the reasonable pricing of the e-commerce platform, which can be divided into the following two situations:
Situation 1: When S < C C 1 , the collaborative supervision bonus given to consumers by the local government cannot easily cover its regulatory costs, and the characteristic values of E 2 ( 0 , 1 , 0 ) , which is the equilibrium point of the gradual evolution of the system, are negative. At this time, the e-commerce platform chooses the non-algorithmic price discrimination strategy, the local government chooses the active regulatory strategy and the consumers choose the negative regulatory strategy.
Situation 2: When S > C C 1 , the cost of consumer collaborative supervision is less than the bonus given by the local government. The characteristic values of E 4 ( 0 , 1 , 1 ) , which is the equilibrium point of the gradual evolution of the system, are negative, and the bonus is higher than the regulatory cost, which gives consumers the motivation to actively supervise. At this time, the e-commerce platform chooses the non-algorithmic price discrimination strategy, the local government chooses the active supervision strategy and the consumers choose the active supervision strategy.
When ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 > β ( φ F + φ D + L P 1 ) , the excess grey income obtained by the e-commerce platform from algorithm price discrimination is greater than the sum of the fines levied by active supervision and the consumer network externalities lost by the platform. It is difficult to effectively regulate the algorithm price discrimination behaviour of the e-commerce platform, which can be divided into the following two situations:
Situation 3: When C C 1 > ( 1 β ) φ D + S , the cost of active supervision by consumers is greater than the amount of additional price difference compensation brought by active supervision and the bonus given by the local government. The characteristic values of E 6 ( 1 , 1 , 0 ) , which is the equilibrium point of gradual evolution of the system, are negative, at which time the e-commerce platform chooses the algorithm price discrimination strategy, the local government chooses the active supervision strategy and the consumer chooses the negative supervision strategy.
Situation 4: When C C 1 < ( 1 β ) φ D + S , the amount of additional price difference compensation brought by consumers’ active supervision and the bonus given by the local government are greater than the cost consumed by active supervision. The characteristic values of E 8 ( 1 , 1 , 1 ) , which is the equilibrium point of gradual evolution of the system, are negative, at which time the e-commerce platform chooses the algorithm price discrimination strategy, the local government chooses the active supervision strategy and the consumer chooses the active supervision strategy.

5. Numerical Simulation and Analysis of Influencing Factors

5.1. Numerical Simulation

In order to reflect the evolution process of the system more intuitively and accurately, numerical simulation experiments were carried out using Matlab R2021 b. Based on the actual situation, the tax rate paid by the e-commerce platform is g = 0.06 ; according to the results of the Beijing Consumers Association’s questionnaire research results, the degree of price discrimination of the e-commerce platform is φ = 0.85 ; and, referring to Pan Ding [15], when the local government actively supervises, the probability of finding the algorithm price discrimination of the e-commerce platform is β = 0.8 . Combined with the restrictions under different circumstances, set the remaining parameter values as shown in the Table 3 below.
To substitute the parameter values into the three-dimensional replication dynamic system, set the initial willingness loop function as f o r   x ( y , z ) = 0 : 0.2 : 1 for participating tripartite subjects. The experimental results of the numerical simulation for scenarios 1–4 above are obtained as shown in Figure 5a–d. Where the different coloured lines represent the strategy choices of the participating subjects in different initial states. These results validate the inference of asymptotic stability points for the evolution of the system for different scenarios, and, as can be seen from the figure, the initial willingness to choose a strategy by the participating tripartite subjects is positively related to the rate of system evolution to an asymptotically stable state but cannot influence the final system stability outcome. Figure 5b is the most ideal state, in which local governments and consumers actively cooperate in supervision, and the excess grey income from the algorithm price discrimination of e-commerce platforms is less than the sum of regulatory fines and network externalities; that is, the regulatory punishment measures can effectively promote e-commerce platforms to choose non-algorithm price discrimination strategies. Figure 5d shows the least ideal state, in which the regulatory penalties are small, and it is difficult to cover the excess grey income of e-commerce platforms. Additionally, the local governments and consumers actively cooperate with supervision, but the e-commerce platforms still choose to carry out the short-sighted behaviour of algorithm price discrimination in order to obtain huge profits.

5.2. Sensitivity Analysis of Different Influencing Factors for System Evolution

Based on the ideal scenario 2 condition, in order to avoid the influence of the initial intention of the three participants on the system evolution rate, the initial intention is selected as ( 0.5 , 0.5 , 0.5 ) . The analysis of the sensitivity of each influencing factor to the evolution of the system with an asymptotic steady state is described below.

5.2.1. Sensitivity Analysis of the Degree of Algorithm Price Discrimination of E-Commerce Platform for System Evolution

Let the values of the remaining influencing factors be fixed, and consider the degree of the price discrimination of the e-commerce platform algorithm, φ = 0.75 , 0.85 , 0.95 . The system evolution result is shown in Figure 6 below. As can be seen from the graph, as the degree of algorithmic price discrimination on the e-commerce platforms deepens, the rate at which platforms choose not to engage in algorithmic price discrimination gradually slows down, while the rate at which local governments and consumers choose active regulatory strategies accelerates in unison. This shows that when the e-commerce platforms use algorithms to increase the degree of price discrimination, they can continuously squeeze the surplus value of consumers and obtain higher excess grey returns. However, at this time, consumers will be more active in coordinating supervision to protect themselves, while local governments will be more active to increase their credibility, and the punishments for the platforms will also increase. Thus, although the rate of convergence of e-commerce platforms slows down, eventually, non-algorithmic price discrimination will still be chosen.

5.2.2. Sensitivity Analysis of Excess Grey Returns from Algorithmic Price Discrimination on E-Commerce Platforms for System Evolution

Let the values of the remaining influencing factors be fixed and the excess grey income obtained by the algorithm price discrimination of the e-commerce platform be Δ R P = 50 , 100 , 150 . The system evolution result is shown in Figure 7 below. It can be seen from this figure that, when Δ R P is low, the e-commerce platform quickly converges to 0 and chooses a non-algorithmic price discrimination strategy but that the convergence speed slows down with the increase in Δ R P . When the excess grey return exceeds a certain threshold, the platform will choose algorithmic price discrimination, and the rate of convergence between local governments and consumers to active supervision will increase with the increase in Δ R P . It shows that the excess grey income obtained by the algorithm price discrimination of the e-commerce platform will significantly affect its strategy choice. When Δ R P exceeds a certain threshold, the short-sighted behaviour of algorithm price discrimination will be carried out. At this time, it will evolve to the most undesirable situation of ( 1 , 1 , 1 ) . This, in turn, jeopardizes public rights and interests, affects its reputation, undermines the credibility of the government and causes adverse effects. While compelling local governments to increase punishments, consumers use third-party media to expand their influence, use public opinion to amplify network externalities and effectively regulate e-commerce platforms’ algorithm price discrimination.

5.2.3. Sensitivity Analysis of the Probability of Algorithmic Price Discrimination When Local Governments Actively Supervise for System Evolution

Let the values of the remaining influencing factor parameters be fixed and the probability of the actively monitoring local government finding algorithmic price discrimination be β = 0.4 , 0.6 , 0.8 . The system evolution result is shown in Figure 8 below. It can be seen from the figure that, when β is at a low level, the willingness of platforms to carry out algorithmic price discrimination is stronger at first. Local governments and consumers actively supervise at this time, which prompts e-commerce platforms to turn to non-algorithmic price discrimination strategies. Additionally, with the increase in β , the rate of convergence to non-algorithmic price discrimination of platforms gradually increases. The rate of convergence to active supervision by local governments is basically unchanged. In turn, the rate of convergence to active regulation by consumers, out of trust in the government’s ability to regulate and because of a free-rider mentality, gradually decreases, reaching an ideal equilibrium in which the public interest is safeguarded.

5.2.4. Sensitivity Analysis of Local Government Fines for Platform Algorithm Price Discrimination for System Evolution

Let the values of the remaining influencing factors be fixed and the penalty of local governments for price discrimination against platform algorithms be F = 5 , 30 , 55 . The system evolution result is shown in Figure 9 below. It can be seen from the figure that, when F is lower than a certain threshold, the lower penalty will give the platform the opportunity to carry out the short-sighted behaviour of algorithm price discrimination. At this time, local governments and consumers will actively coordinate supervision, and, due to the damage to consumers’ own rights and interests, their willingness to supervise is relatively stronger. With the increase in F , when the penalty breaks the threshold of the platform’s algorithmic price discrimination balance, the platform will converge to a non-algorithmic price discrimination strategy. Additionally, the larger the value of F , the faster the convergence rate. Local governments are gaining more economic benefits from increased fines, so the rate of convergence to active regulatory strategies is increasing. Although consumers will still choose active supervision out of the psychology of free riding, their convergence rate will slow down. At this time, by increasing the amount of compensation, the sharing price data and information to reduce the cost of public supervision, the enthusiasm of consumers will also increase.

5.2.5. Sensitivity Analysis of the Cost of Active Consumer Regulation for System Evolution

Let the values of the remaining influencing factors be fixed and the active supervision cost of consumers be taken as C C 1 = 4 , 8 , 12 . The system evolution result is shown in Figure 10 below. As shown in the figure, with the increase in C C 1 , the rate of convergence of e-commerce platforms to non-algorithmic price discrimination gradually decreases, and the rate of convergence between local governments and consumers to active supervision also gradually decreases. When C C 1 increases to a certain threshold, it will lead consumers to choose negative regulatory strategies. This shows that the cost of active supervision of consumers only affects the convergence speed of the platform and the local government. As the remaining values of the influencing factors remain unchanged, it is not possible to change the strategy choices of either party. For consumers themselves, when the platform chooses non-algorithm price discrimination, if their regulatory costs exceed the incentives given by the local government S , they will not be able to cooperate with the government to actively supervise. At this time, the local government can reduce the cost of active supervision of consumers by sharing price data information, encouraging the establishment of third-party price comparison platforms, etc. This will give consumers the motivation to actively coordinate supervision.

5.2.6. Sensitivity Analysis of Consumers’ Active Collaborative Regulation Reward for System Evolution

Let the parameter values of the remaining influencing factors be fixed, and consider the bonus to be S = 5 , 10 , 45 . The system evolution result is shown in Figure 11 below. It can be seen from the figure that, when S is at a low level, the rate of convergence of e-commerce platforms to non-algorithmic price discrimination strategies is low. Local governments have a stronger willingness to actively supervise, and consumers choose negative regulatory strategies due to the lack of regulatory motivation. With the gradual increase in S , the convergence rate of e-commerce platforms accelerates. At this time, the willingness of local governments to regulate is slightly weakened, but they still choose to actively supervise. Appropriate bonuses will prompt consumers to turn to active regulatory strategies. When S increases to a certain threshold, although the high bonus brings strong regulatory momentum to consumers, it also increases the regulatory cost of local governments. Their strategy choices will fall into cyclical shocks, and wavering decisions will also make the strategic choices of e-commerce platforms change cyclically. Thus, the incentive given by local governments to consumers for active collaborative supervision does not linearly increase with the increase in the reward. The bonus threshold should be reasonably set according to its own costs and consumers’ costs, and, at the same time, the local governments should actively improve the relevant reward rules. This will enhance consumers’ willingness to actively cooperate with supervision.

6. Conclusions and Recommendations

6.1. Conclusions

This paper constructs a three-party evolutionary game model for e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers. To a certain extent, it broadens the perspective of existing research in the field of algorithmic price discrimination. We conducted analyses on the asymptotic stability of the system under different scenarios, the corresponding strategy choices of the three parties and comparative experiments by controlling the values of the variables. In doing so, we explored the influence of various factors on the evolution of the system. Based on the above model derivation and simulation experimental results, the following conclusions are drawn:
(1)
When the sum of the fines levied and the consumer network externalities lost by the platform is greater than the excess grey income, which is obtained by the e-commerce platform from algorithmic price discrimination, it can promote the platform to set reasonable prices. The initial willingness of the three-party strategy choice will not change the final evolutionary result, but a higher initial willingness will promote the system to evolve to a stable state faster.
(2)
When the degree of algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms increases, although the rate of active collaborative supervision between local governments and consumers accelerates, the rate of platforms tending towards non-algorithmic price discrimination slows down. Therefore, it is necessary to cooperate with the media to increase the length of reporting on platform algorithm price discrimination, to improve consumers’ price fairness preferences [44] and to publicize the government’s determination to rectify the chaos of algorithm price discrimination. To curb the short-sighted behaviour of platform algorithm price discrimination, it is also necessary to strengthen industry self-discipline and safeguard public rights and interests.
(3)
The increase in excess grey gains from algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms will significantly change the strategic choices of the platforms. When the potential excess grey income exceeds a certain threshold, the platforms will engage in algorithmic price discrimination for short-term gain, thereby ignoring the long-term brand reputation benefits brought by consumer network externalities. Therefore, government regulators need to set up clear rules for punishments to quantify the losses caused by the short-sighted behaviour of the platforms and to make the platforms aware of their social responsibilities [45]. In addition, consumers should actively use the advantages of self-media and network externalities to maintain their right to pursue price fairness.
(4)
The greater the probability that actively regulating local governments find algorithmic price discrimination, the faster the rate at which e-commerce platforms choose non-algorithmic price discrimination. However, local governments alone are limited in their ability to regulate and still need the active collaboration of consumers. Therefore, government regulatory authorities need to unblock complaint channels and establish a long-term mechanism for consumer feedback [46]. Positive consumer synergy is well received, which, in turn, increases the willingness of consumers to actively regulate.
(5)
The strength of local government fines against platforms for algorithmic price discrimination is positively correlated not only with the rate of active regulation but also with the rate at which platforms converge to non-algorithmic price discrimination. The rate at which consumers opt for active regulation is negatively correlated with the strength of fines due to their free-rider mentality [47]. Therefore, government regulatory authorities should also choose appropriate rewards and punishments, improve reward and punishment mechanisms, curb platform algorithm discrimination and give consumers the motivation to actively coordinate supervision.
(6)
Consumers’ strategy choices are extremely sensitive to the impact of their active regulatory costs. The lower the regulatory cost, the higher the return during active supervision, and the more it will prompt them to choose an active collaborative strategy. At the same time, it can effectively increase the rate of platform choice of non-algorithmic price discrimination. Therefore, on the one hand, the government regulatory department shares price data information, reduces the degree of market information asymmetry and promotes price transparency [48], while, on the other hand, consumers should also continuously improve their own price comparison capabilities and make reasonable use of third-party price comparison platforms to reduce regulatory costs.
(7)
The amount of money awarded for active co-regulation by consumers is more disruptive to the evolution of the system. A low incentive for consumer regulation when the bonus is too low and an imbalance in local government revenues and expenditures when the bonus is too high will lead to cyclical shocks and a cyclical change in the e-commerce platform. Therefore, the amount of money received by consumers should not be too high or too low but should be within a certain threshold, taking into account the benefits to the government and the costs to consumers. This will not only effectively regulate the platform algorithm price-discriminatory behaviour but also achieve active co-regulation between the local government and consumers and, thus, a win–win situation for all parties.

6.2. Recommendations

Curbing the short-sighted behaviour of algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms is important for maintaining consumer fairness, enhancing consumer trust and, thus, promoting the sustainable development of e-commerce platforms. Based on the above research, the following recommendations are made from the perspectives of e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers, respectively:
(1)
E-commerce platforms should focus on brand reputation, enhance social responsibility and strengthen industry self-regulation. In a highly competitive market environment, e-commerce platforms must focus on consumer word-of-mouth and establish a good brand reputation if they are to have longevity. In addition, the e-commerce platform should consciously fulfil its social responsibility and actively cooperate with local government supervision. At the same time, industry associations should improve the industry norms for e-commerce platforms and strengthen industry self-discipline. This will create a good atmosphere for the development of the e-commerce industry.
(2)
Local governments should improve reward and punishment mechanisms, increase publicity efforts and open up channels for consumer complaints; establish a sound complaint mechanism and accountability system for algorithmic price discrimination on e-commerce platforms and set the reasonable rewards and penalties within a threshold; place publicity announcements on government websites, public websites and third-party media to alert e-commerce platforms of punishments for algorithmic price discrimination; promote information technology and visualization as a means of big data regulation; and reduce the level of information asymmetry in the e-commerce market. Meanwhile, the complaint channels will reduce the cost of co-regulation by consumers.
(3)
Consumers should enhance their awareness of their rights and actively improve their ability to compare prices. They should establish a correct consumer mindset, enhance their awareness of their rights and be brave enough to use legal means to defend their rights and interests in the face of unfairness. In addition, they should actively make use of third-party price comparison platforms and others to enhance price comparison capabilities. They should be adept at harnessing the power of public opinion, moving from passive acceptance to active participation and co-regulation.

6.3. Limitations and Further Research

There are still limitations in this study, which only concern the evolutionary game between e-commerce platforms, local governments and consumers. The influence of merchants and third-party media on stakeholders’ participation has not been considered. Therefore, in future research, more stakeholders can be considered as participants, and a multi-stakeholder evolutionary game model can be constructed for a more comprehensive analysis.

Author Contributions

J.L. is mainly responsible for designing the outline and writing guidance; X.X. is mainly responsible for writing the article, designing the models and conducting the simulation experiments; Y.Y. is responsible for article polishing. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research was supported by the 2022 Heilongjiang Philosophy and Social Science Research Planning Project, grant number 22SHE416; the 2022 Harbin University of Commerce “Innovation” Project Support Program, grant numbers XW0093 and XW0145; and the Harbin Science and Technology Plan Self-Financing Project, grant number ZC2022ZJ014004.

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

Not applicable.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Islek, I.; Oguducu, S.G. A hierarchical recommendation system for E-commerce using online user reviews. Electron. Commer. Res. Appl. 2022, 52, 101131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Gonçalves, M.J.A.; Pereira, R.H.; Coelho, M.A.G.M. User Reputation on E-Commerce: Blockchain-Based Approaches. J. Cybersecur. Priv. 2022, 2, 907–923. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Abrardi, L.; Cambini, C.; Rondi, L. Artificial intelligence, firms and consumer behavior: A survey. J. Econ. Surv. 2021, 36, 969–991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Keller, A.; Vogelsang, M.; Totzek, D. How displaying price discounts can mitigate negative customer reactions to dynamic pricing. J. Bus. Res. 2022, 148, 277–291. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Wang, J.; Shu, T.; Zhao, W.; Zhou, J. Research on Chinese Consumers’ Attitudes Analysis of Big-Data Driven Price Discrimination Based on Machine Learning. Front. Psychol. 2022, 12, 6683. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Liu, X.; Zhang, Z.; Qi, W. The Strategy Analysis of Grouped Bid Evaluation in Reverse Auction: A Tripartite Evolutionary Game Perspective. IEEE Syst. J. 2021, 16, 88–99. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Shen, L.; Lin, F.; Wang, Y.; Su, X.; Li, H.; Zhou, R. Advertising Decisions of Platform Supply Chains Considering Network Externalities and Fairness Concerns. Mathematics 2022, 10, 2359. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Hu, L.; Zhang, Y.; Chung, S.-H.; Wang, L. Two-tier price membership mechanism design based on user profiles. Electron. Commer. Res. Appl. 2022, 52, 101130. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Peiseler, F.; Rasch, A.; Shekhar, S. Imperfect information, algorithmic price discrimination, and collusion. Scand. J. Econ. 2022, 124, 516–549. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Liu, W.; Long, S.; Xie, D.; Liang, Y.; Wang, J. How to govern the big data discriminatory pricing behavior in the platform service supply chain? An examination with a three-party evolutionary game model. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2020, 231, 107910. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Aparicio, D.; Misra, K. Artificial intelligence and pricing. Artif. Intell. Mark. 2023, 20, 103–124. [Google Scholar]
  12. van der Rest, J.-P.; Sears, A.M.; Kuokkanen, H.; Heidary, K. Algorithmic pricing in hospitality and tourism: Call for research on ethics, consumer backlash and CSR. J. Hosp. Tour. Insights 2022, 5, 771–781. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Liu, J.; Wang, C.; Lu, J. Equilibrium Analysis of Price Discrimination Economic Phenomenon Based on Big Data Monitoring of Netizen Sensors. Mob. Inf. Syst. 2022, 2022, 5913819. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Hufnagel, G.; Schwaiger, M.; Weritz, L. Seeking the perfect price: Consumer responses to personalized price discrimination in e-commerce. J. Bus. Res. 2022, 143, 346–365. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Lin, X.; Huang, X.; Liu, S.; Li, Y.; Luo, H.; Yu, S. Competitive Price-Quality Strategy of Platforms under User Privacy Concerns. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2022, 17, 571–589. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Wu, Z.; Yang, Y.; Zhao, J.; Wu, Y. The Impact of Algorithmic Price Discrimination on Consumers’ Perceived Betrayal. Front. Psychol. 2022, 13, 825420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Li, X.; Xu, Z. Superior Knowledge, Price Discrimination, and Customer Inspection. Mark. Sci. 2022, 41, 1097–1117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Zha, Y.; Wang, Y.; Li, Q.; Yao, W. Credit offering strategy and dynamic pricing in the presence of consumer strategic behavior. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2022, 303, 753–766. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Friedman, D. On economic applications of evolutionary game theory. J. Evol. Econ. 1998, 8, 15–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Luo, J.; Huang, M.; Bai, Y. Promoting green development of agriculture based on low-carbon policies and green preferences: An evolutionary game analysis. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 2023. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Bai, S.; Liu, Z.; Lv, Y. Evolutionary Game Analysis of Consumer Complaint Handling in E-Commerce. Discret. Dyn. Nat. Soc. 2022, 2022, 3792080. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Li, J.M.; Jiang, S.S. How can governance strategies be developed for marine ecological environment pollution caused by sea-using enterprises?—A study based on evolutionary game theory. Ocean. Coast. Manag. 2023, 232, 106447. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Cui, N.; Li, J.; Tu, J.; Zhou, M. Evolutionary Game Analysis of Non-Governmental Organizations Participating in Garbage Management under the Background of Internet of Things. Sustainability 2022, 14, 13008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Wang, Q.; Liu, X.; Zhang, C. Evolutionary game analysis of FinTech transformation: A social co-governance pattern of peer-to-peer lending market in China. Front. Psychol. 2022, 13, 954132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Xu, Y.; Bao, H. FinTech regulation: Evolutionary game model, numerical simulation, and recommendations. Expert Syst. Appl. 2023, 211, 118327. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Huang, Z.; Wang, X.; Feng, Z.; Chen, B. Regulating the product quality of COVID-19 antigen testing reagents: A tripartite evolutionary game analysis under China’s legal framework. Front. Public Health 2022, 10, 1060079. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Sun, X.; Zhou, W.; Feng, Y. Mobile healthcare platforms’ sustainability: The perspective of health information quality. Front. Public Health 2023, 10, 1059252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  28. Sun, C.; Wang, M.; Man, Q.; Wan, D. Research on the BIM Application Mechanism of Engineering-Procurement-Construction Projects Based on a Tripartite Evolutionary Game. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2023, 149, 04022182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Dong, J.; Yan, S. Evolutionary game analysis between employees and employers about working overtime from the perspective of information asymmetry. BMC Psychol. 2022, 10, 95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Liu, C.; Song, Y.; Wang, W.; Shi, X. The governance of manufacturers’ greenwashing behaviors: A tripartite evolutionary game analysis of electric vehicles. Appl. Energy 2023, 333, 120498. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Wang, Q.; Liu, J.; Zheng, Y. Evolutionary game analysis of community elderly care service regulation in the context of “Internet +”. Front. Public Health 2022, 10, 1093451. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  32. Wang, W.; Song, Z.; Zhou, W.; Jiang, Y.; Sun, Y. Evolutionary Game Analysis of Government and Enterprise Behavior Strategies in Pub-lic-Private-Partnership Farmland Consolidation. Agriculture 2022, 12, 1874. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Bin, W.U. Evolutionary game analysis of “killing maturity” phenomenon of e-commerce platform from the perspective of psychological account. Oper. Res. Manag. 2020, 29, 37–44. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  34. Ding, P.A.; Han, X.I. The evolutionary game between government regulation and the “killing” behavior of e-commerce en-terprises under the digital economy. Econ. Manag. 2021, 35, 77–84. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  35. Ye, X.; Fu, Y.-K.; Wang, H.; Zhou, J. Information asymmetry evaluation in hotel E-commerce market: Dynamics and pricing strategy under pandemic. Inf. Process. Manag. 2023, 60, 103117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Airoldi, M.; Rokka, J. Algorithmic consumer culture. Consum. Mark. Cult. 2022, 25, 411–428. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. He, H.; Zhang, B. Strategy Analysis of Multi-Agent Governance on the E-Commerce Platform. J. Theor. Appl. Electron. Commer. Res. 2022, 18, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. de Marcellis-Warin, N.; Marty, F.; Thelisson, E.; Warin, T. Artificial intelligence and consumer manipulations: From consumer’s counter algorithms to firm’s self-regulation tools. AI Ethics 2022, 2, 259–268. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Feng, N.; Chen, J.; Feng, H.; Li, M. Promotional pricing strategies for platform vendors: Competition between first- and third-party products. Decis. Support Syst. 2021, 151, 113627. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Nunan, D.; Di Domenico, M.L. Value creation in an algorithmic world: Towards an ethics of dynamic pricing. J. Bus. Res. 2022, 150, 451–460. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Genshang, X.I.G.; Fang, L.U.; Zhongbao, Z.H.U.; Jinlong, Y.E. Can the right to data portability govern “big data kills familiarity”? Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2022, 30, 85–95. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  42. Seele, P.; Dierksmeier, C.; Hofstetter, R.; Schultz, M.D. Mapping the Ethicality of Algorithmic Pricing: A Review of Dynamic and Personalized Pricing. J. Bus. Ethic 2019, 170, 697–719. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Heidary, K.; Custers, B.; Pluut, H.; van der Rest, J.-P. A qualitative investigation of company perspectives on online price discrimination. Comput. Law Secur. Rev. 2022, 46, 105734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Wang, X.; Wang, X.; Liu, Z.; Chang, W.; Hou, Y.; Zhao, Z. Too generous to be fair? Experiments on the interplay of what, when, and how in data breach recovery of the hotel industry. Tour. Manag. 2022, 88, 104420. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Rita, P.; Ramos, R.F. Global Research Trends in Consumer Behavior and Sustainability in E-Commerce: A Bibliometric Analysis of the Knowledge Structure. Sustainability 2022, 14, 9455. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Arya, V.; Paul, J.; Sethi, D. Like it or not! Brand communication on social networking sites triggers consumer-based brand equity. Int. J. Consum. Stud. 2021, 46, 1381–1398. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Zhang, X.; Xu, Y.; Chen, X.; Liang, J. Pricing Decision Models of Manufacturer-Led Dual-Channel Supply Chain with Free-Rider Problem. Sustainability 2023, 15, 4087. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Shen, B.; Dong, C.; Tong, X.; Ngai, E.W. Emerging technologies in e-commerce operations and supply chain management. Electron. Commer. Res. Appl. 2022, 55, 101203. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Figure 1. Diagram of the game relationship between the participating players.
Figure 1. Diagram of the game relationship between the participating players.
Sustainability 15 08294 g001
Figure 2. Phase diagram of the strategic evolution of e-commerce platforms.
Figure 2. Phase diagram of the strategic evolution of e-commerce platforms.
Sustainability 15 08294 g002
Figure 3. Phase diagram of the strategic evolution of local governments.
Figure 3. Phase diagram of the strategic evolution of local governments.
Sustainability 15 08294 g003
Figure 4. Phase diagram of the strategic evolution of consumers.
Figure 4. Phase diagram of the strategic evolution of consumers.
Sustainability 15 08294 g004
Figure 5. Numerical simulation in four scenarios.
Figure 5. Numerical simulation in four scenarios.
Sustainability 15 08294 g005aSustainability 15 08294 g005b
Figure 6. The effect of φ on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Figure 6. The effect of φ on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Sustainability 15 08294 g006
Figure 7. The effect of Δ R P on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Figure 7. The effect of Δ R P on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Sustainability 15 08294 g007
Figure 8. The effect of β on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Figure 8. The effect of β on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Sustainability 15 08294 g008
Figure 9. The effect of F on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Figure 9. The effect of F on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Sustainability 15 08294 g009
Figure 10. The effect of C C 1 on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Figure 10. The effect of C C 1 on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Sustainability 15 08294 g010
Figure 11. The effect of S on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Figure 11. The effect of S on the evolution of the system to an asymptotic steady state.
Sustainability 15 08294 g011
Table 1. Matrix of payoffs for the three-party evolutionary game.
Table 1. Matrix of payoffs for the three-party evolutionary game.
E-Commerce PlatformsLocal GovernmentsConsumers
Active Regulation ZNegative Regulation 1 − Z
Algorithmic price
discrimination
x
Active
regulation
y
( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 φ ( F + D ) L P 1 ( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 β [ φ ( F + D ) + L P 1 ]
g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C G 1 + φ F S + R G g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C G 1 + β φ F
D C C 1 + S β D
Negative
regulation
1 y
( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2 α L P 1 ( 1 g ) ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) C P 1 φ C P 2
g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) L G 1 α L G 2 g ( R P 1 + φ Δ R P ) L G 1
C C 1 0
Non-algorithmic
price
discrimination
1 x
Active
regulation
y
( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1 ( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1
g R P 1 C G 1 S + R G g R P 1 C G 1
R C 1 C C 1 + S R C 1
Negative
regulation
1 y
( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1 ( 1 g ) R P 1 C P 1
g R P 1 L G 1 g R P 1 L G 1
R C 1 C C 1 R C 1
Table 2. Jacobian matrix eigenvalues of local equilibrium points of pure strategies.
Table 2. Jacobian matrix eigenvalues of local equilibrium points of pure strategies.
Local Equilibrium Point λ 1 λ 2 λ 3
E 1 ( 0 , 0 , 0 ) ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 L G 1 C G 1 C C 1
E 2 ( 0 , 1 , 0 ) ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 β ( φ F + φ D + L P 1 ) C G 1 L G 1 S C C 1
E 3 ( 0 , 0 , 1 ) ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 α L P 1 L G 1 C G 1 S + R g C C 1
E 4 ( 0 , 1 , 1 ) ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P φ C P 2 ( φ F + φ D + L P 1 ) C G 1 L G 1 + S R g C C 1 S
E 5 ( 1 , 0 , 0 ) φ C P 2 ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P L G 1 C G 1 + β φ F C C 1
E 6 ( 1 , 1 , 0 ) φ C P 2 ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P + β ( φ F + φ D + L P 1 ) C G 1 L G 1 β φ F ( 1 β ) φ D C C 1 + S
E 7 ( 1 , 0 , 1 ) φ C P 2 ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P + α L P 1 L G 1 C G 1 + α L G 2 + φ F S + R g C C 1
E 8 ( 1 , 1 , 1 ) φ C P 2 ( 1 g ) φ Δ R P + φ F + φ D + L P 1 C G 1 L G 1 α L G 2 φ F + S R g C C 1 ( 1 β ) φ D S
Table 3. Setting parameter values under different circumstances.
Table 3. Setting parameter values under different circumstances.
ScenarioΔRPLP1CP2FCG1LG1LG2RGαSCC1D
1100302030204520150.5101830
2100302030204520150.510830
3100302030204520150.510185
4100302030204520150.51085
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Li, J.; Xu, X.; Yang, Y. Research on the Regulation of Algorithmic Price Discrimination Behaviour of E-Commerce Platform Based on Tripartite Evolutionary Game. Sustainability 2023, 15, 8294. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108294

AMA Style

Li J, Xu X, Yang Y. Research on the Regulation of Algorithmic Price Discrimination Behaviour of E-Commerce Platform Based on Tripartite Evolutionary Game. Sustainability. 2023; 15(10):8294. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108294

Chicago/Turabian Style

Li, Jianjun, Xiaodi Xu, and Yu Yang. 2023. "Research on the Regulation of Algorithmic Price Discrimination Behaviour of E-Commerce Platform Based on Tripartite Evolutionary Game" Sustainability 15, no. 10: 8294. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108294

APA Style

Li, J., Xu, X., & Yang, Y. (2023). Research on the Regulation of Algorithmic Price Discrimination Behaviour of E-Commerce Platform Based on Tripartite Evolutionary Game. Sustainability, 15(10), 8294. https://doi.org/10.3390/su15108294

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop