1. Introduction
The majority of countries that are most affected by climate change do not have the fiscal space for scaling up climate-related investments, as stressed in [
1]. Furthermore, many authors have found that climate vulnerability is associated with higher sovereign costs of debt (for example see [
2]).
In addition to the effects of climate change, developing and poor countries are especially affected by several overlapping crises, such as abrupt increases in energy and food costs, the COVID-19 pandemic, and others (see, for example, [
3]).
In this context, sovereign debt relief or standstill programs have been implemented (see [
4] for an overview of relevant IMF programs), while many more are being proposed, as in [
3]. Key questions for the design and effectiveness of such programs regard their financing and whether they should be accompanied by specific constraints (conditionality). For example, ref. [
5] find that sovereign default risk is hump-shaped in the intensity of conditionality in the long-run. Furthermore, ref. [
6] finds that debt relief that is substantially based on incentive-compatible conditions promotes fiscal reform and investment and argues for a combination of outright grants and “soft” loans. One should also note that sovereign pre-emptive restructurings are frequent and can result in lower output losses ([
7]).
The 2022 Geneva Report on the World Economy [
1] presents alternative financing instruments to fund actions that can mitigate climate change, including grants, debt relief, green bonds, and others. In the context of sovereign debt-related instruments, the authors highlight that future debt restructurings should be based on debt sustainability analyses “at explicitly account for the fiscal costs of climate-related expenditures and include enforceable climate conditionality” [
8].
In this paper, we develop a formal model to present a policy proposal where a (quasi) debt relief can be used to promote productive public capital while reinforcing economic growth and debt sustainability.
To provide a practical example, we use the context of international creditors supporting a sovereign developing or poor country through a setup where debt payments are redirected to investments on green energy infrastructure in the country. These investments facilitate economic growth and achieve a sustained debt-to-output level. This is in effect our policy proposal.
We develop a typical decentralized competitive general equilibrium endogenous-growth model, extend the standard endogenous growth literature framework by distinguishing internal from external public debt, and add a conditionality clause linking public investment on productive infrastructure associated with the cost of servicing external public debt.
The financial scheme proposed is that a fraction of external debt service is returned to the sovereign government in the form of foreign aid under the binding agreement that this inflow is fully used for investments in green productive public capital. This is in effect the conditionality clause. A typical example are investments in electricity transmission networks that are essential for integrating (new) electricity generation especially from renewable energy sources (RES). It should be noted that transmission system operators usually operate as natural monopolies and are owned by the state. In addition, for new large-scale RES deployment, grid connection costs should be covered by the respective grid operator [
9].
These investments can lead the economy to a long-run balanced growth path where the debt as percentage of output remains constant, reducing (if not eliminating) the possibility of a default. We can note here that [
10] found that 62% of defaults occurred when output was below its trend.
This policy proposal protects the interests of international creditors who can avoid a default or haircut on the bonds they hold, while also allowing them to promote their (global) green and sustainable growth objectives. For the “recipient” country, productive public investments for green infrastructure are secured, and the threat of a default is avoided, which could also provide other benefits through increased credibility and reduced risk (see, for example, [
11]).
As external debt is in effect still serviced, and investments continuously realized, there are no significant lock-ins, especially for future political leaders. In other words, one could envision an annual or biennial evaluation of the scheme while allowing termination by either party without loss of the benefits already realized.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In
Section 2, we present the sectors of the economy and define the equilibrium and the associated balanced growth path and find the optimality conditions that describe the dynamic evolution of the economy.
Section 3 shows the impacts of the two main parameters. In
Section 4, we present numerical simulations, and
Section 5 provides a discussion on the main findings of the model, comments on its limitations, and proposes future research. To reduce clutter, throughout the text, we avoid presenting intermediate algebraic analysis, most of which can be found in the appendices, and the remaining analyses are available upon request.
2. The Model
2.1. The Sectors of the Economy
We consider a typical decentralized competitive general equilibrium endogenous-growth model with three sectors: the household, firms (production), and the government sector. In this model, the engine for endogenous growth is the stock of (productive) public capital, in the spirit of [
12,
13] and more similar to the work of [
14]. More precisely, the setup of the economy is a decentralized closed economy. The main differences from the work of the mentioned authors are that, in our model, the government can issue public debt domestically and internationally, invests in public infrastructure, and output is positively affected by foreign aid.
2.1.1. The Production Sector
The production sector consists of a unique competitive firm that maximizes profits. The production function is as follows:
where
denotes output,
is private capital,
is productive public capital, and
is the time period. We assume that labor is inelastic and equal to unity, the parameter
is output elasticity (
), and
is total factor productivity.
Profit maximization of the firm yields the rear wage rate
and the real interest rate
, as
2.1.2. The Household
The household sector consists of a representative infinitely lived household that optimally chooses its consumption path and saves through private capital and internal public debt. The representative household allocates consumption over time to maximize lifetime utility:
subject to its dynamic budget constraint:
where
denotes wealth,
the derivative of wealth over time,
is consumption,
is the household’s time preference (discount rate), and
is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, and
is a flat tax rate. We assume a flat tax rate since a different taxation scheme, such as progressive tax rates, may give rise to unfavorable dynamics (see [
15,
16]). The household accumulates wealth by investing in two assets, private capital
and government bonds
(sovereign internal debt). Thus, the change in wealth over time is:
The government satisfies its dynamic budget constraint through borrowing, that is, by issuing internal and external bonds. The household absorbs all new internal bond issues, and the remainder of its savings goes to private capital.
2.1.3. The Government
We do not impose a fiscal rule on the budget of the government, but rather, we let it freely borrow through the dynamic budget constraint and let the level of debt be endogenously determined in this simple economy setup. The dynamic budget constraint of the government (i.e., the debt accumulation identity) is
where
is foreign aid,
is the stock of public debt,
is the evolution of debt over time,
denotes total taxes,
denotes government public spending, and
is
where
is total debt, that is, the sum of internal debt
and external debt
.
We let the ratio of internal bonds over external bonds be exogenous:
The above notation allows us to distinguish the effects across countries with different sovereign debt profiles. In other words, we assume that the level of initial sovereign debt is fixed, but its internal-to-external ratio can differ (e.g., across countries).
For simplicity and to clearly identify the effects of foreign aid (explained below), we assume that total public spending is directed to productive public capital, such as infrastructure that enables the integration of renewable energy sources in the energy mix (e.g., electricity transmission lines):
International creditors offer the government an agreement to facilitate green and sustainable growth, and at the same time protect their interests by leading the economy to a long-run balanced growth path where the debt as a percentage of output remains constant, thus reducing the possibility of a default.
International creditors have an incentive to facilitate green and sustainable growth in line with international agreements and other climate and political agendas and to reduce the possibility that the country defaults. A default would mean that the external bonds would not be repaid, or, in the least, would be heavily discounted.
In this context, international creditors return a percentage of interest payments paid to them () in the form of direct foreign aid () to be exclusively used for investments in green public productive capital (e.g., investments to increase RES production and usage). These investments will lead the economy to a long-run balanced growth path, where the debt as a percentage of output remains constant, reducing (if not eliminating) the possibility of a default.
In our setup, foreign creditors return a percentage (
) of interest payments paid to them in the form of direct foreign aid:
Alternatively,
can be thought of as the percentage of international creditors that participate in this foreign aid agreement. Historically, it is often the case that only the official sector participates in such schemes (e.g., debt relief or payment standstills), with no participation from the private sector [
3]. In addition, as this is a non-binding voluntary mechanism, it can be stopped at any moment by either party (creditors or national government), and having a flexible return of interest payments (
) would allow an annual matching of needs and willingness to contribute.
As the above foreign aid (
) is fully directed to payments for public investments in renewable energy infrastructure, government spending for such infrastructure is
For simplicity, we assume that the depreciation rate of public capital in (13) is zero, as its inclusion would only reduce the tractability of our results without producing useful insights (see [
17] for an analysis of the long-run properties of the depreciation rate of public capital). Thus, the dynamic budget constraint of the government (8) can be written as
2.2. Equilibrium Conditions
An equilibrium allocation is defined as an allocation where the firm maximizes profits, both private factors of production earn their marginal product, the household maximizes lifetime utility subject to its intertemporal budget constraint, and the budget constraint of the government is met.
The optimality conditions of the firm are given in Equations (2) and (3). For the representative agent problem (i.e., the household), we obtain the present-value Hamiltonian as
We assume that a balanced growth path exists (proved later), that is, a balanced growth path that is a long-run equilibrium in which all endogenous variables grow at the same rate.
From the above and after some algebra, which is presented in
Appendix A, we derive the growth rate as
and the below system of equations that characterize our economy:
The existence of a unique steady state, with a corresponding unique long-run growth rate of balanced growth path, is proved in
Appendix B.
3. The Impact of External Debt on Economic Growth
From (16), one can see that the driver of economic growth is the endogenous variable . An important parameter is the ratio of internal bonds over external bonds (. Under the financial aid scheme provided to the government by international creditors, the more the government borrows from them, the more it invests in green infrastructure, which leads to more economic growth.
From (9), a decrease in refers to a relative change in the ratio of internal to external public debt, towards a higher proportion of external debt. We assume that external debt is held by international creditors, who are compensated with the same rate as internal creditors are, as in Equation (8).
Since the economy is on a balanced growth path, the level of external debt increases at the same rate as the economy grows. This means that the outflow regarding interest payments to international holders increases over time as external debt increases. From (13) and (14), it is implied that the level of aid is also increased at the same pace, and the corresponding investments in infrastructure for integrating RES, which in turn increases the relevant stock of public capital acts as a positive externality, increasing social returns and facilitating economic growth.
In other words, to prove the above analytically it is sufficient to show that (
, which is shown in
Appendix C.
In a similar manner, we analyze the impact of the rate of interest payments (
) redirected from foreign creditors to productive public capital. One expects that a higher
will increase the public capital stock of infrastructure, at a higher pace, ceteris paribus other variables. This type of public capital is considered a pure public good, that is, non-rival in its use and non-excludable. It also acts as a positive productive externality, as in [
6], that tends to increase output as it accumulates over time, thus, sustaining long-run economic growth. Therefore, increasing
should increase the rate of accumulation of public capital and increase economic growth.
To show this analytically, it is sufficient to show that (
, as shown in
Appendix D.
Regarding the speed of transition to the steady state, in the endogenous growth theory literature, [
13] showed that public spending, as a flow variable, can play a role as a positive externality leading to an equilibrium that exhibits log-run and sustained economic growth. While this novel approach had a significant impact on the literature of endogenous growth and successfully explained the tendency of economies to grow over time, this model did not exhibit transitional dynamics (for a discussion, see [
18], explaining the dynamics from initial economic conditions toward the path of balanced growth path).
This drawback was addressed through the work of [
14], where the authors regarded productive public capital (a stock variable) as the positive externality that plays the role of the engine of long-run growth. They also show how transitional dynamics arise in this setup. Our work is like that of [
14], expanding their model to also consider external and internal public debt and a foreign-aid–public-investment financing scheme. These inclusions allow us to explore a particular setup, with different dynamics, since it expands the model to more dimensions while retaining the properties of the key model.
Having shown that an increase in
lowers the long-run growth rate, while an increase in
increases it, it is also of interest to see how the speed of transition is affected by changes in these parameters. We find that, in general, whenever the steady-state long-run growth is higher, the speed of transition is slower, as one would expect given that the economy must reach a higher rate. The analytical proof is provided in
Appendix E.
Another important aspect of our analysis is to explore if the proposed institutional setup can lead the economy to a sustained debt-to-output ratio (a standstill debt ratio). We indeed find that an increase in the internal-to-external debt ratio () leads to an increase in the steady-state debt-to-output ratio. Similarly, an increase in the percentage of interest payments returned as foreign aid () causes a decrease in the steady-state debt-to-output ratio.
4. Numerical Exercises
In the previous sections, we set up the core model, derived its properties, and analytically derived the effect of the main parameters ( and ).
We now proceed to conduct a numerical simulation to demonstrate the effects of the main parameters (
and
) on growth and debt, using the typical parametric values found in the relevant literature. For this purpose, a more general version of the model is used, where we allow
to vary from 0.01 (a country relying almost entirely on external debt) to 2 (a country that relies mostly on internal debt., We fix all other parameter values as follows:
,
,
,
, τ = 0.35, and
. These values are commonly used in the literature; see for example [
19,
20].
Using these values and expressing the main variables as percentages of output, we numerically solve the system of Equations (17)–(19), along with Equations (3) and (9). The findings are summarized in
Table 1, where one can observe that the analytical results are supported. For example, we see that as the ratio of internal to external debt (
) increases, the long-run steady state growth rate (
) decreases, and the debt-to-output ratio (
) increases.
As a second exercise, we let
vary from 0.01 (almost no foreign aid) to 1 (all interest rates are returned as foreign aid) with a step of 0.1, set
, and fix all other parameter values as before. The findings are summarized in
Table 2, where we observe that the analytical results are supported. As the percentage of interest paid to international creditors that is returned in the form of foreign aid to support public investment in infrastructure (
) increases, the long-run steady-state growth rate (
) increases, and the debt-to-output ratio (
) decreases.
5. Discussion
Above, we explored how international creditors can support a developing or poor country using a scheme where debt payments are redirected to investments in green energy infrastructure to facilitate economic growth and achieve a sustained debt-to-output level.
For this purpose, we followed the endogenous growth literature and extended the standard models by including internal–external public debt and foreign aid for productive public capital. We assume that a fraction of external debt service can return to the sovereign government in the form of foreign aid under a binding agreement such that this inflow is fully directed for investing in productive public capital (a conditionality clause).
The key theoretical finding is that this economy has one unique equilibrium, or steady state, that corresponds to a unique balanced growth path. This finding is important as it means that the economy can achieve long-run growth while avoiding any poverty traps, and at the same time achieve a sustained public debt as a percentage of output level.
In this setup, we regarded two important exogenous policy parameters, the internal-to-external public debt ratio and the index of external debt servicing costs that are transformed into productive public capital, that is,
and
, respectively. Considering
, the intuition is that the government debt portfolio with a higher percentage of external public debt is associated with higher interest payments to international creditors. In a different setup, [
21] showed that this may potentially reduce the long-run economic growth.
With the model presented in this document, and considering the (quasi-)conditionality proposed, we show that a higher percentage of external public debt (lower ) or higher aid (higher ) increases public capital accumulation, resulting in a higher long-run growth rate, while the strong growth properties retain a lower level of aggregate debt to output. The trade-off that occurs is that while achieving a stronger growth perspective for the economy the transition to the steady state is slower, which is intuitive as more time is needed to reach the higher equilibria.
One can only acknowledge that such macroeconomic models are subtractive from reality. This model is a simple and stylized one, and its findings should be treated with caution. The validity of the theoretical findings should be at least partially supported by further empirical research, an exercise that can prove challenging as the proposed scheme has not (yet) been implemented in practice.
In effect, our paper is meant to serve as a policy proposal, as any scheme would need to be tailored to the specificities of a county (debt profile, green investment potentials, etc.), but also to the risk appetite, preferences, and political realities. However, the proposed structure can inform a support scheme that can be credible and effective, providing benefits for both the creditors (protection of the bonds they hold, achievement of global sustainability goals, etc.) and the recipient country (e.g., avoidance of defaults, credibility for other investments, etc.). Another consideration regards the design of the particular financial mechanism and the relevant institutional set-up. For a similar case, one can refer to [
3], which describes the basic mechanics for a temporary debt standstill due to COVID-19. Although their description is at a relatively high level, the text demonstrates how such mechanisms can become quite complicated, requiring specialized experts. For a step-by-step guide to a debt restructuring, see [
22].
Another shortcoming is that since the economy is on a balanced growth path, this implies that international creditors should continue and increase their exposure and support to the economy to retain a constant internal–external debt ratio. This observation is not intended to disregard such a financing mechanism, but rather to provoke considerations for an exit strategy following the achievement of the main goals.
Finally, for ease of modeling, we opted to refer to foreign aid. Alternatively, one could envision issuing new government bonds with long maturities for the funds received, taking ownership of the transmission system operator(s), an institutional setup where electricity grid development plans are also approved by foreign creditors, etc. In future work, we plan to extend the model and analysis considering the above.