Next Article in Journal
Green Investor Holdings and Corporate Green Technological Innovation
Next Article in Special Issue
Industry Heterogeneity and the Economic Consequences of Corporate ESG Performance for Good or Bad: A Firm Value Perspective
Previous Article in Journal
Factors Influencing Public Building Energy Consumption: A Case Study of Changjiang River Administration of Navigation Affairs in China
Previous Article in Special Issue
A Review of Corporate Social Responsibility Decoupling and Its Impact: Evidence from China
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China

1
School of Business Administration, Northeastern University, Shenyang 110169, China
2
School of Management, Northeastern University at Qinhuangdao, Qinhuangdao 066004, China
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Sustainability 2024, 16(10), 4290; https://doi.org/10.3390/su16104290
Submission received: 9 April 2024 / Revised: 11 May 2024 / Accepted: 16 May 2024 / Published: 19 May 2024

Abstract

:
This study examines the impact of corporate social responsibility (CSR) on labor investment efficiency utilizing a sample of China’s listed companies. The empirical results demonstrate that CSR improves labor investment efficiency, and the effect is significant in terms of both overinvestment and underinvestment. Findings from cross-sectional tests indicate that CSR has a more significant effect on labor investment efficiency in non-state-owned firms and firms with more financing constraints or higher labor adjustment costs. The conclusion is robust after utilizing a 2SLS regression, replacing indicators for labor investment efficiency and accounting for the impact of non-labor investment. In general, the results support stakeholder theory and confirm that CSR can enhance external monitoring and improve firms’ investment behavior.

1. Introduction

Corporate social responsibility (CSR) is defined as the action of companies voluntarily integrating economic, legal, and ethical concerns in their business operations and in their interaction with their stakeholders [1,2]. Good CSR performance can reduce managers’ short-sighted behaviors [3], enhance earnings quality [4], and inhibit insider trading [5]. Through CSR activities, firms build close and long-term relationships with various stakeholders and reduce risks when firms face negative shocks, which leads to improved market valuation [6]. In research on CSR, its influence on investment behavior has attracted much attention. Cook et al. (2019) [7] find that high-CSR firms have more efficient capital investment and innovation behavior. Wang et al. (2020) [8] find that environment governance information disclosure can improve Chinese firms’ investment efficiency. This effect is more significant in high-pollution industries such as heavy industry. Lee and Kim (2020) [9] also demonstrate that fulfilling environment responsibility inhibits overinvestment in South Korean companies, especially in highly competitive markets. Existing studies show that CSR activities significantly enhance investment efficiency. However, these studies concentrate mainly on capital or innovation investment, while few studies concentrate on the influence of CSR on labor investment efficiency.
Labor is an indispensable factor of productivity, and labor cost (i.e., employee salary expenditure) usually accounts for nearly two-thirds of firms’ economic value added [10]. According to a survey by the US Census Bureau, the total wages and benefits of employees in the US manufacturing industry were USD 784 billion in 2008, which is 4.7 times that of capital investment expenditure [11]. Erosa et al. (2010) [12] develop quantitative models and prove that human capital accumulation magnifies the differences in total factor productivity across countries. By increasing the marginal output of capital, a higher human capital stock will lead to more physical capital accumulation. In the era of knowledge economy, labor is an important core asset for a firm to obtain competitive advantages [13]. In recent years, scholars have focused on ways to enhance labor investment efficiency. Pinnuck and Lilli (2007) [14] propose a quantitative method of expected employee growth, which Jung et al. (2014) [11] apply to develop a measurement of labor investment efficiency. They prove that more transparent accounting information can enhance labor investment efficiency through alleviating agency problems. Ghaly et al. (2020) [15] claim that institutional investors tend to supervise the decision-making process of the management and are often related to efficient labor investment. Scholars also find that analyst following, macro-policies, and CEO traits are the influencing factors of labor investment efficiency [16,17,18]. However, the existing research is still limited, and the relationship between CSR and labor investment efficiency is not generally known.
This paper fills this gap and tries to verify the positive influence of CSR on enhancing labor investment efficiency. CSR can enhance labor investment efficiency from two aspects: reducing agency costs and easing financing constraints. In terms of the former, firms with good CSR performance usually have better corporate governance mechanisms [19] and a larger analyst following and media tracking [20], which restrains inefficient labor investment decisions by self-interested managers. In terms of the latter, good CSR performance not only increases non-financial information disclosure quantity [21] but also enhances information disclosure quality [4], therefore reducing the cost of capital [22]. Good CSR performance also assists companies to reduce risks [23] and thus reduce the risk compensation required by investors. Finally, firms showing better CSR performance also have easier access to external financial support such as government subsidies, thus reducing underinvestment in labor [24].
To test this hypothesis, 15,998 firm-year observations of Chinese listed companies are analyzed covering 2011 to 2019, and the results support the hypothesis. China is selected as the setting for the study for the following reasons. First, as the Chinese economy enters a high-quality development stage, achieving sustainable development becomes a new development goal for firms. Meeting this goal requires firms to shoulder social responsibilities and meet the demands of stakeholders. Since the publication of the Guidance on Social Responsibility of China in 2015, improvements in CSR institutional arrangements, legalization, and standardization have accelerated. The CSR performance of Chinese firms continues to improve. However, the Research Report on CSR of China (2019) points out that the development of China’s CSR is still insufficient, leaving room for progress. The imperfect CSR system limits its influence on corporate governance, which makes the connection between CSR and the development of firms uncertain. Therefore, it is worth further discussing the economic consequences of China’s CSR implementation at the current stage and whether it brings value to the development of firms. Second, in the past few decades, labor has been an important factor in China’s economic growth. In recent years, with the demographic dividend disappearing and the population aging, China’s economy is under downward pressure, and efficient labor configurations can mitigate the negative impact of the diminishing demographic dividend. Third, as China is the largest emerging economy, it is a highly representative research sample, and the research conclusion may be relevant to other emerging economies. However, existing studies on labor investment efficiency chiefly analyze firms in developed countries [16,25], so research on emerging markets is limited.
This study generates several contributions. First, the results enrich the research about the influence of CSR on firms’ investment behavior. The existing research on the connection between CSR and investment behavior concentrates on capital or innovation investment [7,8], leaving labor investment behavior relatively neglected. The results prove that CSR also significantly impacts labor investment efficiency, reflecting the important role of CSR in firms’ development. Second, labor investment is gaining increasing attention, and the factors influencing labor investment efficiency, such as analyst following [17], macro-polices [16], population structure [26], and so on, are gradually coming to light. However, the existing research is still limited. This study demonstrates that CSR contributes to enhancing labor investment efficiency and provides more evidence about the influencing factors of labor investment.
The remainder of this paper is arranged as follows. The second part provides a literature review and develops the hypothesis. The third part describes the research design. The fourth part provides the empirical results. The fifth part reports the extended analysis and robustness test. The final part presents the conclusions.

2. Literature Review and Hypothesis Development

2.1. Literature Review

In recent years, firms have gradually integrated CSR into their business activities, and research on CSR is booming. Classical economic scholars hold that managers should take profit maximization as the sole goal of the company. They believe that the fulfillment of CSR increases agency costs within the firm and will damage the interests of shareholders [27]. However, social economic scholars claim that non-shareholder stakeholders provide the environment for the firm’s survival, and managers should integrate their needs into the decision-making process [28], which lays the foundation for stakeholder theory. The subsequent corporate citizenship [29] and strategic management theories [30] illustrate the necessity for firms to fulfill their social responsibilities. Nguyen et al. (2020) argue that with the monitoring of long-term investors, managers will choose proper CSR activities and maximize shareholder value [31].
The existing literature provides a full discussion of how CSR influences firms’ financial performance [32,33]. CSR can help accumulate moral capital, which reduces the costs of unfavorable events [23,34]. Hong and Kacperczyk (2009) [20] find that analysts and media tend to track firms with good CSR performance. Firms showing good CSR performance may disclose more information [21,35] and report more transparent accounting information [4]. Therefore, CSR activities reduce the cost of capital because investors require a reduced risk premium [22]. CSR can also expand the investor base [36], promote innovation [7], and improve capital investment efficiency [8,9]. Thus, firms can fulfill their social responsibilities to meet stakeholders’ expectations, thus enhancing their reputation and public image [37]. In this way, firms can attract more customers and form unique competitive advantages [38]. For example, Bardos et al. (2020) claim that CSR enhances a firm’s product competitiveness, because CSR suggests the trustworthiness of the firm in product quality and acts as a signal for firms to differentiate themselves in a market where quality is difficult to observe [39]. In addition, a firm’s CSR performance can affect its supply chain partners, which is known as the spillover effect along supply chains [40].
Labor investment is an indispensable investment of a firm. Effective labor investment can improve productivity, income, and competitiveness [13]. Many scholars have explored the influencing factors of labor investment efficiency, among which information asymmetry is one of the main causes. Jung et al. (2014) [11] reveal that high-quality accounting information improves the information environment, thus promoting external supervision. Hence, it reduces the agency costs of managers’ self-interested behavior and alleviates the financing costs caused by adverse selection, resulting in more efficient labor investment. High stock price informativeness can also enhance labor investment efficiency, because it provides an improved information environment, which will lead to better supervision of managers [41]. Bai et al. (2023) [42] claim that diversified enterprises are faced with a more complex external environment, and their accounting information is more difficult to interpret. Higher agent costs inside diversified enterprises also make employment decisions more inefficient.
CEO characteristics also affect labor investment efficiency. The close ties between CEOs and directors might weaken corporate governance, thus exacerbating agency conflicts and leading to distortions in labor investment decisions [43]. Lai et al. (2021) [18] claim that an overconfident CEO is related to higher labor cost stickiness of a firm, which makes labor investment less efficient. In addition, CEO inside debt holdings also cause more conservative labor investment decisions [44].
From an external supervision perspective, analysts can supervise and give advice for managers’ decisions. Therefore, more analyst tracking and higher accuracy of the analysts’ predictions can enhance labor investment efficiency [17]. Internal governance can also influence labor investment efficiency. Institutional investors will pay more attention to supervising management decisions than short-term investors, which alleviates inefficient labor investment [15]. Employee-oriented treatment policies ensure the consistency of the interests between the employees and the company, thus improving labor investment efficiency [45]. Adwan (2024) also finds a positive connection between employee ownership and labor investment efficiency, because it improves the monitoring of management and reduces agency costs [46].
Finally, some studies investigate the influence of legal and external environments on labor investment efficiency. The Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine decreases the mobility of employees with proprietary information and reduces the threat of knowledge leakage, but it also makes firms take preventive recruitment measures, leading to overinvestment in labor [16]. Kong et al. (2018) [47] prove that promotion incentives put pressure on local politicians to create jobs, who may then force firms to overinvest in labor. The “Enterprise Bankruptcy Law” and “Property Law” strengthen creditor protection and increase creditors’ willingness to offer financial support, which enhances labor investment efficiency [48]. Chen et al. (2024) argue that the emission trading system reduces labor investment efficiency, because it increases the operating costs and external uncertainty [49]. Jiang et al. (2024) [26] find that as the retirement of older employees increases, firms naturally reduce labor overinvestment. The adjustment of population structure also pushes firms to optimize their employee structure, which leads to more efficient labor investment. Oil price uncertainty also asymmetrically influences firms’ labor investment decisions through affecting managers’ expectations [50].

2.2. Hypothesis Development

Information asymmetry in an imperfect market leads to inefficient labor investment, which manifests as overinvestment in labor, including over-hiring or under-firing and underinvestment caused by under-hiring or over-firing [11]. Information asymmetry makes it costly to monitor the firm’s managers, and moral hazards may arise when managers make decisions that cater to their own interests for “empire building” purposes [51], resulting in overinvestment in labor. To maintain a “quiet life”, managers may be reluctant to change the status quo [52] and refuse to fire employees to avoid problems with layoffs, resulting in under-firing [15]. In addition, Pagano and Volpin (2005) [53] find that in firms with poor performance, if the employees have enough power to influence the managers’ appointments and dismissals, managers may also ally with employees by avoiding layoffs and salary decreases, thus causing overinvestment in labor. Agency costs may also lead to labor underinvestment because if the firm’s short-term performance affects managers’ compensation, they are likely to over-fire underperforming employees or delay hiring new employees to manipulate profit, as it takes longer to improve firms’ performance through labor investment [54].
Second, information asymmetry leads external investors to increase the cost of capital as compensation, resulting in financing constraints. The classical economics school perceives labor as a variable factor of production, so they do not include additional fixed costs in labor adjustment [55]. In this view, firms pay labor expenditure out of current revenues without requirement of financing. Since labor costs are variable, financing constraints will not influence labor investment decisions, and investment opportunities are the only factor determining labor investment [11]. However, the social economic literature points out that labor cost is not completely variable, as it includes fixed cost (or at least quasi-fixed cost) [56,57]. For example, firms incur recruitment, training, and adaptation costs when recruiting new employees. It may take some enterprises a long time for new employees to adapt to the environment, increasing the cost of adaptation. This phenomenon is also known as the cost of productivity loss. Additionally, firms must usually pay compensation costs for firing employees; in most cases, layoffs do not have zero cost, and in extreme cases, layoffs may lead to lawsuits. These fixed costs are labor adjustment costs that make financing constraints a common phenomenon in labor investment [53], resulting in labor underinvestment [11].
CSR can improve the information environment and then enhance labor investment efficiency through alleviating the agency problems and easing financing constraints.
CSR can restrain inefficient labor investment by alleviating the agency problems. First, good CSR performance is generally associated with sound corporate governance mechanisms [19] because it allows stakeholders to be involved in firms’ decision-making processes. In China, by lobbying the board of directors, fostering invisible proxies, mobilizing collective action, and leveraging third parties, stakeholders can influence the appointments of managers and firms’ strategic decisions [58]. These actions can restrain managers’ power and ameliorate agency problems. Althoff (2021) [59] takes a further step and claims that CSR is indispensable for firms to achieve sustainable development, so it should be regarded as a part of good governance. Second, firms with good CSR performance attract more analysts and a greater media following [20], so such firms face stronger external supervision and constraints, which inhibits managers from making inefficient labor investment decisions for their own benefit. Third, sufficient free cash flow can prompt managers to get involved in speculation [60]. The cost of undertaking social responsibility can reduce the free cash flow inside the firm, thus restraining excessive speculation such as labor overinvestment. In summary, CSR can alleviate agency problems and inhibit managers from self-interested inefficient labor investment.
CSR can alleviate underinvestment by easing financing constraints. CSR activities increase both the quantity and quality of information disclosure, which can reduce the cost of capital investors impose as compensation for their information disadvantages [22]. From the information quantity perspective, CSR information, as non-financial information disclosure, supplements the financial information disclosed in financial reports, delivers more characteristic information to investors, and helps firms to obtain external financing [21]. As for information quality, firms showing good CSR performance tend to reduce earnings management behaviors and can provide financial information with high transparency and reliability [4]. Simultaneously, good CSR performance can send positive market signals [61,62], improve the firm’s reputation, establish a public image, and form moral capital as protective insurance to help firms reduce risks [23], thus reducing the risk compensation required by equity and bond investors [22,63]. CSR also meets the expectation of stakeholders such as the government and regulators, which can help firms get external financial support such as subsidies [24]. For example, the Chinese government provides firms that reduce their chemical oxygen demand emissions with one-off grants. Finally, better CSR performance of buyer firms suggests their trustworthiness and lower operational risks to suppliers, so the firms with better CSR performance have greater access to trade credit financing [64]. Therefore, our first hypothesis is as follows.
H1a. 
Good CSR performance can improve labor investment efficiency.
In contrast, CSR may also negatively impact labor investment efficiency because fulfilling CSR does not always reduce agency costs and may also become an agency problem itself [27], thus exacerbating inefficient labor investment. For example, Koehn and Ueng (2009) [65] believe that charitable donations are easy to implement and can bring high short-term gains, making them a likely tool for managers to divert public attention and cover up negative information. Managers will also overinvest in CSR to improve their personal reputation or win stakeholder support [66]. Apart from agency conflicts, firms may hire more workers and avoid layoffs to fulfill their responsibilities to employees [67], which leads to labor overinvestment. In addition, when the firm lacks funds, CSR activities may occupy the cash flow of labor investment and aggravate labor underinvestment. Therefore, our second hypothesis is as follows.
H1b. 
Good CSR performance can reduce labor investment efficiency.

3. Research Design

3.1. Labor Investment Efficiency Measurement

Following Jung et al. (2014) [11], we adopt abnormal net hiring as the proxy for labor investment efficiency. Specifically, as in Pinnuck and Lillis (2007) [14], we utilize net hiring (percentage change in the number of employees) as a proxy for labor investment and then regress labor investment over some fundamental economic variables of the firm. The residuals from this model are the values of abnormal net hiring. Cao and Rees (2020) [45], Ding et al. (2023) [48], Ghadhab et al. (2023) [68], and others also follow this method. The equation based on this method is as follows:
N E T _ H I R E i t = β 0 + β 1 S A L E S _ G R O W T H i t 1 + β 2 S A L E S _ G R O W T H i t + β 3 Δ R O A i t 1   + β 4 Δ R O A i t + β 5 R O A i t + β 6 R E T U R N i t 1 + β 7 S I Z E _ R i t 1 + β 8 Q U I C K i t 1   + β 9 Q U I C K i t + β 10 Δ Q U I C K i t + β 11 L E V i t 1 + β 12 L O S S B I N 1 i t 1   + β 13 L O S S B I N 2 i t 1 + β 14 L O S S B I N 3 i t 1 + β 15 L O S S B I N 4 i t 1   + β 16 L O S S B I N 5 i t 1 + β j 17 62 I N D U S T R Y + β j 63 69 Y E A R + ε i t
In Equation (1), NET_HIRE is the percentage change in the number of employees. SALES_GROWTH is the percentage growth of sales revenue. ROA is the ratio of net profit to the total assets at the beginning of the year, and ΔROA is the increment in ROA. RETURN is the total annual stock return. SIZE_R is the percentile rank of the total market value. QUICK is the ratio of current assets excluding inventory to current liabilities, and ΔQUICK is the increment of QUICK. LEV is the ratio of total debt to total assets. The LOSSBIN variables are used to measure the degree of losses in the prior year, obtained by dividing ROA into five intervals from 0 to −0.025 with a length of 0.005. That is, if ROA is in the range of −0.005 to 0, then LOSSBIN1 = 1; if ROA is in the range of −0.01 to −0.005, then LOSSBIN2 = 1, and so on. INDUSTRY and YEAR represent dummy variables for the industry and year.
To simplify the interpretation, we utilize the absolute value of the residuals as a proxy for labor investment efficiency and label it AB_NET_HIRE. A larger AB_NET_HIRE indicates a larger gap between the actual and predicted labor investment, indicating lower labor investment efficiency.

3.2. CSR Measurement

We extract the CSR from the CSR score in the Hexun database. The Hexun CSR score is a comprehensive and objective evaluation of CSR performance and is a common measure in research on CSR in China [69,70]. The Hexun CSR score consists of five dimensions (i.e., shareholder responsibility; employee responsibility; supplier, customer, and consumer responsibility; environment responsibility; and public responsibility). These dimensions are given various weights by industry to derive a comprehensive score. To increase the value of the regression coefficient, we divide the CSR score by 10 and express it as the variable CSR. Larger values of CSR indicate better CSR performance.

3.3. Model Specification

Following Jung et al. (2014) [11] and Cao and Rees (2020) [45], we conduct the empirical analysis utilizing the following regression model:
A B _ N E T _ H I R E i t = β 0 + β 1 C S R i t 1 + β 2 M T B i t 1 + β 3 S I Z E i t 1 + β 4 Q U I C K i t 1 + β 5 L E V i t 1   + β 6 D I V D U M i t 1 + β 7 S T D _ C F O i t 1 + β 8 S T D _ S A L E S i t 1 + β 9 T A N G I B L E i t 1   + β 10 L O S S i t 1 + β 11 I N S T I i t 1 + β 12 S T D _ N E T _ H I R E i t 1   + β 13 L A B O R _ I N T E N S I T Y i t 1 + β 14 A B _ I N V E S T _ O T H E R i t 1   + β j 15 60 I N D U S T R Y + β j 61 67 Y E A R + ε i t
In Equation (2), β0 is the constant term, and βk (k = 1, 2, … 14) is the regression coefficient of the equation. AB_NET_HIRE is the reverse indicator of labor investment efficiency, as Section 3.1 described. CSR is the comprehensive score of firms’ CSR performance. A significantly negative coefficient of β_1 would support H1a. However, a significantly positive coefficient of β_1 would support H1b. As in Jung et al. (2014) [11], we add 13 control variables. We add the market-to-book ratio (MTB) to measure the growth of a company. SIZE is the natural logarithm of firm’s market value. QUICK is the quick ratio. LEV is the ratio of total debt to total assets, which we use to measure the financial risk of the firm. DIVDUM is a dummy variable for dividend payment. It is equal to 1 if the firm pays dividends and 0 otherwise. STD_CFO and STD_SALES are the standard deviation of the cash flow and sales revenue in the previous five years, respectively. TANGIBLE is the ratio of tangible assets to total assets. LOSS is equal to 1 if the firm suffers loss and 0 otherwise. As in Cella (2020) [71], we use institutional investors’ shareholding (INSTI) to control the possible supervisory role of institutional investors. We include the standard deviation of the employee change rate in the previous five years (STD_NET_HIRE) to avoid the impact of employment volatility. LABOR_INTENSITY is the labor intensity of the firm, which is equal to the number of employees divided by total assets. Finally, AB_INVEST_OTHER represents capital investment efficiency. As in Biddle et al. (2009) [72], we regress capital investment expenditure over the sales growth rate ( O T H E R _ I N V E S T i t = β 0 + β 1 S A L E S _ G R O W T H i t 1 + ε i t ) to obtain the absolute value of the residual as a proxy for capital investment efficiency. INDUSTRY and YEAR represent dummy variables for the industry and year effects. We correct standard errors for firm-level clustering. All the variables in Equation (2) are defined in Table 1.

3.4. Sample and Data Sources

We utilize the CSR score of Chinese listed firms in the Hexun database and collect other data from the CSMAR database. We select firm-year observations of Chinese A-share listed firms in the Shanghai Stock Exchange and Shenzhen Stock Exchange from 2011 to 2019 as our sample. All the industries are included in our research sample except financial firms. Financial firms apply different accounting standards from other firms, so we excluded them to ensure the consistency of the indicators. In China, although not all the companies disclose their CSR reports, many firms disclose their CSR information in a dedicated section in the financial reports. The Hexun CSR score used in this article integrates the CSR information disclosed in financial reports, CSR reports, and other public information. Thus, the sample is not limited to companies that disclose their CSR reports. We remove the observations where the CSR score is missing. We also remove the observations with other missing data. Finally, the sample contains 15,998 firm-year observations. We winsorize all the continuous variables at the 1st and the 99th percentiles.
Since 2010 is the first year for which Hexun provided CSR scores and that we lag the value of CSR by one year in Equation (2), the sample begins in 2011. Our sample ends in 2019, because COVID-19 is likely to have an abnormal impact on the hiring of firms from 2020, which might distort our results. The period of COVID-19 is a special case, and we believe that it cannot serve as a reference for future general situations. In 2020–2022, because of the strict prevention and control measures against COVID-19 (e.g., home quarantine), the economy of China was impacted. The average GDP growth from 2017 to 2019 was 6.5%, and GDP growth in 2020 fell to 2.2%. At the same time, the labor investment and CSR decisions were also influenced by COVID-19, which made the relationship between CSR and labor investment efficiency in 2020–2022 (or even 2023, as the first year after reopening) not applicable to the mechanism analysis in this study. As the impact of COVID-19 continues to weaken, selecting a research period before 2020 might be more instructive for the future.

4. Empirical Results

4.1. Descriptive Statistics and Correlation Analysis

Table 2 provides the descriptive statistics of the variables in Equation (2). The mean and median of AB_NET_HIRE are 0.199 and 0.105, respectively, which are consistent with the descriptive statistics of Chinese listed companies in Kong et al. (2018) [47]. The mean and median of the independent variable CSR are 2.480 and 2.128, respectively, and the first and third quartiles are 1.494 and 2.846, respectively, which means that CSR performance varies greatly among Chinese listed firms. The results indicate that the value of CSR in the research sample has a certain cross-sectional change.
Table 3 provides the Pearson correlation coefficients for the main variables. Consistent with H1a, the correlation coefficient between CSR and AB_NET_HIRE is significantly negative at the 1% level. This indicates that better CSR performance is related to more efficient labor investment. The correlation coefficients between the control variables are not high enough to drive multicollinearity.

4.2. Baseline Results

Table 4 provides the results of Equation (2). The baseline result is in Column (1). The coefficient of CSR is significantly negative (t-statistic = −4.07), indicating that CSR activities can enhance corporate labor investment efficiency, which supports H1a rather than H1b. The results reveal that the positive impact of CSR in enhancing external supervision and transmitting market signals outweighs the negative impacts of increased agency problems, leading to more efficient labor investment.
We exclude the influence of non-observable factors on the results by applying the firm fixed effects and random effects models to perform the regression in Equation (2). We report the results in columns (2) and (3) of Table 4. The regression coefficients of CSR are significantly negative (t-statistic = −2.54, −3.35). We apply the Fama–Macbeth model (1973) [73] to exclude the cross-sectional correlation of the residuals and provide the results in column (4). The coefficient of CSR is still significantly negative (t-statistic = −1.87). The GMM model is also applied to avoid interference caused by the issues of heteroscedasticity and autocorrelation in the random error term. The result in column (5) shows that the coefficient of CSR is still significantly negative. These results further validate the conclusion.
The results of the control variables in the baseline results are consistent with previous studies (e.g., Khedmati et al., 2020 [43]). Firms with a high market-to-book ratio (MTB), high liquidity (QUICK), no dividend distribution (DIVDUM), loss (LOSS), high employment fluctuation (STD_NET_HIRE), and highly inefficient capital investment (AB_INVEST_OTHER) show a higher degree of inefficient labor investment, while larger firms (SIZE) and firms with higher leverage (LEV) and higher labor intensity (LABOR_INTENSITY) can improve labor investment efficiency.

4.3. Endogeneity

The previous analysis shows that CSR is conducive to improving labor investment efficiency. However, endogeneity, such as reverse causality and omitted variables, may be of concern. We select two instrumental variables and use 2SLS and 3SLS methods to re-estimate Equation (2).
First, the number of religious sites is selected as an instrumental variable. Culture represents shared values, beliefs, and norms [74] and determines how members in a firm interact with each other and stakeholders outside the firm [75]. Different cultural contexts result in different capacities of companies and their managers to comprehend and address CSR issues [76]. Religiousness is a part of culture and has a significant impact on business ethics. Longenecker et al. (2004) find that more religiously inclined individuals tend to exhibit better decision-making in ethical contexts and a greater orientation to CSR [77]. Ibrahim et al. (1991) [78] conduct a study of 152 self-proclaimed Christian firms and claim that nearly half of these firms emphasize employee-centered values and behaviors, and 73% of the surveyed firms emphasize loyalty and fairness. Religion can also teach people to be good and help others [79], which is essentially similar to CSR. For example, Buddhism advocates cultivation of compassion, generosity, and altruism, which is conducive to cultivating CSR concepts and will help improve CSR performance, especially through environmental protection and charitable donations [79]. Similarly, the spiritual goal in Taoist doctrine is closely related to the fulfillment of CSR, especially charity activities [80]. Therefore, local religious beliefs may affect CSR activities. However, religious sites are mainly formed in history, and their number is external to firms, so they will not directly affect labor investment efficiency.
We select the number of religious sites in the provinces in which the firms are registered as the first instrumental variable. For firms registered in a municipality directly under the central government (i.e., Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, or Chongqing), the total number of religious sites is the sum of the number of religious sites in the municipality and the number of religious sites in the province from which the municipality is divided (e.g., Chongqing was subordinate to Sichuan Province before 1997), because the religious culture of the municipality is also affected by the religious factors of the province from which it is divided due to the historical heritage and the geographical distance.
Second, following Arouri et al. (2019) [81] and others, we use the mean of CSR in the same year, industry, and province as an instrumental variable. Liu and Wu (2016) [82] argue that the peer effect exists in CSR; that is, the adoption of CSR policy by a firm in an industry will lead other firms in the same industry to strategically carry out more CSR practices. Therefore, we can infer that the industry average CSR performance will affect firms’ CSR performance. Otherwise, the industry average CSR is an exogenous factor that does not directly impact firms’ labor investment efficiency.
The 2SLS results using the number of religious sites (Religion) as an instrumental variable are provided in columns (1) and (2) in Table 5. The coefficient of Religion in column (1) is significantly positive (t-statistic = 3.09), indicating that religious belief affects the fulfillment of CSR. The coefficient of CSR in column (2) is significantly negative (t-statistic = −1.77), indicating the consistency with our baseline results. The Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic, which is above the 15% level, alleviates the concern about weak instrumental variables. Columns (3) and (4) list the results of using the average CSR (Average) as the instrumental variable with a 2SLS method. The coefficient of Average in column (3) is significantly positive (t-statistic =5.96), demonstrating the influence of industry average CSR performance on a company’s CSR performance. The coefficient of CSR in column (4) is still significant (t-statistic = −2.31). The Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic is significantly above the 15% level (F-statistic = 35.5), which alleviates the concern about weak instrumental variables. Columns (5) and (6) provide the results when using both Religion and Average as instrumental variables. The regression coefficients of Religion and Average in column (5) are significantly positive (t-statistic = 2.66, 5.85). The coefficient of CSR in column (6) is negative (t-statistic = −2.74). The Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic is 21.5, which passes the weak instrumental variable test at the 15% level. The result of the Hansen J test confirms that our results pass the overidentification test (p-value = 0.397).
Finally, according to Zenller and Theil (1962) [83], a three-stage least squares (3SLS) method is applied to re-perform the tests above, because 3SLS takes into account the correlation between the random error terms of different structural equations in the model. Our conclusion stays robust after performing the 3SLS regression. The results are omitted to save space.
These findings indicate that our conclusion remains valid after addressing endogeneity concerns.

4.4. Overinvestment and Underinvestment in Labor

We further examine the impact of CSR on labor overinvestment and underinvestment. Following Jung et al. (2014) [11], we split the full sample into overinvestment and underinvestment subsamples according to the sign of residual obtained from Equation (1). If it is positive, then the actual labor investment is above the predicted value, indicating overinvestment (OVER_INV). If it is negative, then the actual labor investment is below the predicted value, indicating underinvestment (UNDER_INV).
Column (1) of Table 6 provides the test results of Equation (2) for the overinvestment sample. The coefficient of CSR is significantly negative (t-statistic = −2.68), which proves that CSR can restrain labor overinvestment. Further, as in Jung et al. (2014) [11], we separate the labor overinvestment subsample OVER_INV into OVER_HIRE (with positive predicted net hiring) and UNDER_FIRE (with negative predicted net hiring) according to the expected level of labor investment obtained from Equation (1). The coefficient of CSR is still significant in the OVER_HIRE subsample in column (2), but the significance decreases in the UNDER_FIRE subsample in column (3), which may be because CSR, especially labor responsibility, increases the cost of firing employees, which is not conducive to timely firing decisions.
Column (4) of Table 6 provides the results of Equation (2) in the labor underinvestment sample. The coefficient of CSR is significantly negative (t-statistic = −3.33), which supports the view that CSR fulfillment can alleviate labor underinvestment. Likewise, we then divide the labor underinvestment subsample UNDER_INV into UNDER_HIRE (with positive predicted net hiring) and OVER_FIRE (with negative predicted net hiring) and then re-estimate Equation (2). Columns (5) and (6) present the results. The coefficients of CSR are significantly negative (t-statistic = −2.90, −2.55), indicating that CSR fulfillment can alleviate under-hiring and over-firing simultaneously, thus alleviating underinvestment in labor.

5. Extended Analysis and Robustness Checks

5.1. The Impact of Property Rights

The influence of CSR on labor investment efficiency may differ for state-owned enterprises (SOEs) and non-state-owned enterprises (non-SOEs). First, many Chinese firms have government ownership, such as SOEs. SOEs should undertake policy goals, such as expanding employment and providing social security and housing fund to employees [84]. Further, the government greatly influences the appointment and dismissals of SOEs’ executives [85]. To obtain better promotion opportunities, SOE managers usually voluntarily fulfill the government’s policy objectives, such as providing more employment opportunities. Therefore, the net effect of CSR on labor overinvestment may be weaker in SOEs, because these firms face greater pressure to recruit redundant employees.
Second, SOEs have a natural advantage in financing activities, relying on their own political connections. The Chinese financial system is largely subject to government intervention, forming a financing chain of “central government—state-owned commercial banks—SOEs” [86]. With the support of this financing chain, SOEs can obtain low-cost capital, with few problems with capital shortage. However, most non-SOEs have difficulty raising capital from state-owned banks. Moreover, when the macroeconomic environment starts to deteriorate, state-owned banks will prioritize loans for SOEs, leading to increased financing costs for non-SOEs [87]. Therefore, compared with SOEs, CSR is more likely to alleviate labor underinvestment of non-SOEs.
We investigate whether differences exist in the hypothesized relationship between SOEs and non-SOEs by rerunning Equation (2) with the addition of SOE (1 for SOEs and 0 otherwise) and its interaction terms with CSR. The results are provided in Table 7. The coefficient of SOE × CSR is significantly positive at the 1% level in the whole sample (column (1)), which supports the view that CSR exerts greater influence on labor investment efficiency in non-SOEs than in SOEs. When regressing the labor overinvestment and underinvestment subsamples, the coefficients of SOE × CSR are still significantly positive at the 1% level (columns (2) and (3)), which further supports our primary analysis.

5.2. The Impact of Financing Constraints

As labor costs are semi-fixed, financing constraints are a common phenomenon in labor investment [53], resulting in labor underinvestment [11]. Financially constrained companies may face labor underinvestment because they have difficulty obtaining low-cost capital. They may reduce the number of employees to save costs and improve cash flow [88]. In this case, it is more important for these firms to deliver positive signals and obtain external financing through CSR activities. As a result, the enhancement of labor investment efficiency made by CSR will be strengthened in firms with higher financing constraints. On the contrary, firms subject to low financing constraints that can easily obtain cheap capital are unlikely to experience labor underinvestment, and the influence of CSR performance on enhancing labor investment efficiency will be weakened.
We use the KZ index [89] and WW index [90] as a proxy for financing constraints. Greater KZ and WW values represent higher financing constraints. We add KZ (WW) and its interaction term with CSR, KZ × CSR (WW × CSR) to Equation (2). Columns (1) and (4) of Table 8 list the results of the moderating effect of financing constraints in the whole sample. The coefficient of KZ × CSR (WW × CSR) is significantly negative at the 1% level, consistent with our expectation that in financially constrained firms, the influence of CSR on enhancing labor investment efficiency is strengthened. Subsample regression shows that in the labor underinvestment subsample (columns (3) and (6)), the coefficient of KZ × CSR (WW × CSR) is significantly negative at the 1% level, suggesting consistency with the result of the whole sample. This demonstrates that CSR has a greater impact on underinvestment in firms facing higher financing constraints. Although the coefficient of WW × CSR is significantly negative at the 10% level when utilizing the WW index as a proxy for financing constraints (column (5)), the coefficient of KZ × CSR is not significant when we utilize the KZ index as a proxy for financing constraints (column (2)). Therefore, there is no consistent evidence to prove the influence of CSR on labor overinvestment is strengthened in firms with higher financing constraints. This may be because although financing constraints restrict firms’ layoff decisions to some extent as layoffs also have costs, which may lead to under-firing and aggravate overinvestment in labor, we believe that overinvestment in labor is more associated with agency problems and is thus less affected by financing constraints. Therefore, the influence of CSR on labor overinvestment may be less affected by financing constraints.

5.3. The Impact of Labor Adjustment Costs

Firms face fixed costs when they adjust the number of employees. Hiring creates recruitment, training, and adaptation costs, while firing employees will bring compensation costs and even lead to lawsuits. These labor adjustment costs restrict firms from proportionately adjusting labor investment in response to a change in sales [56], thus exacerbating inefficient labor investment. Labor adjustment costs may influence our hypothesized relationship. First, in firms facing higher labor adjustment costs, inefficient labor investment will cause more loss, and shareholders have a stronger willingness to supervise firms’ employment decisions [15]. Similarly, CSR enables firms to establish a positive, sustainable relationship with their stakeholders. In companies with high labor adjustment costs, these stakeholders pay more attention to their labor investment decisions to reduce the deviation from the optimal level to safeguard their own interests. Second, increased labor adjustment costs mean that companies’ financing demand for labor investment increases. In this case, CSR plays a more important role in labor adjustment decisions because good CSR performance can transmit positive signals and reduce capital cost. However, companies facing lower labor adjustment costs have less financing demand for labor investment, so CSR activities may contribute less to alleviating inefficient labor investment.
We utilize the percentage of employees with a bachelor’s degree or above (BACH) and the proportion of employees with a master’s degree or above (MAST) as proxies for labor adjustment costs. Highly educated employees are expected to take on more complicated and high-skilled work and are hard to substitute; hence, firms with a higher percentage of highly educated employees are likely to face higher cost of adjustments (e.g., hiring, firing, training, and adaptation costs) [55,56]. We rerun Equation (2) by adding BACH (MAST) and its interaction with CSR, BACH × CSR (MAST × CSR), and provide the results in Table 9. Columns (1) and (4) report the test results of the moderating effect in the whole sample. The coefficient of BACH × CSR (MAST × CSR) is significantly negative. It indicates that higher labor adjustment costs increase the influence of CSR on labor investment efficiency. Further, in the labor overinvestment (columns (2) and (5)) and underinvestment subsamples (columns (3) and (6)), the coefficient of BACH × CSR (MAST × CSR) is still significantly negative. This indicates that CSR has a greater impact on labor overinvestment and underinvestment as labor adjustment costs increase.

5.4. Alternative Proxies for Labor Investment Efficiency

We apply several substitute proxies for labor investment efficiency as a robustness test. First, following Biddle et al. (2009) [72], we retain only the sales growth on the right-hand side of Equation (1). We obtain the absolute residuals for the variable AB_NET_HIRE_1. Second, following Cella (2020) [71] and Ben-Nasr and Alshwer (2016) [41], we take the median of labor investment in the same industry and year as the predicted labor investment. AB_NET_HIRE_2 is the absolute value of the deviation between the actual and predicted labor investment level. Third, we take average labor investment in the past two, three, and four years as the predicted level, and the absolute value of the deviation between the actual value and the predicted level is the proxy for labor investment efficiency, labeled AB_NET_HIRE_3, AB_NET_HIRE_4, and AB_NET_HIRE_5, respectively. Fourth, we re-estimate Equation (1) by year and industry. The absolute value of the residuals is the proxy for labor investment efficiency, labeled AB_NET_HIRE_6. Then, we re-estimate Equation (2) and report the results in columns (1)–(6) of Table 10. Using these substitute measures for labor investment efficiency, the coefficient of CSR is still significantly negative at the 1% level.
Labor investment appears as the number and the remuneration of employees. With the improvement of mechanization and artificial intelligence, firms reduce the number of employees and require more well-paid employees. In addition, firms may have a large gap in the remuneration of different positions, which may cause a certain deviation in measuring labor investment by the fluctuation in the number of employees. We replace NET_HIRE in Equation (1) with the annual change in labor remuneration (NET_WAGE), where labor remuneration = cash paid to employees + the annual change in employee remuneration payable. Considering the influence of other factors on employee remuneration, we add more control variables in Equation (1). First, we add the lagged cash asset ratio (CASH). We also add the change in cash asset ratio (ΔCASH) of the current year and its one-year lagged variable. Second, given China’s vast territory, the economic development level of different regions varies greatly. We control for regional influences on labor remuneration by adding the log of the average wage of urban employed people in each province (WAGE_MEAN). We also add the change in the log of average wage (ΔWAGE_MEAN) in the current year and its one-year lagged variable. For these variables, the data of the average wage of urban employed people are from The China Statistical Yearbook, and the other data are from CSMAR. We employ the absolute value of the residuals of the improved model (AB_NET_WAGE) as a proxy for labor investment efficiency. Then, we re-estimate Equation (2). Column (7) of Table 10 provides the results. The coefficient of CSR is still significantly negative at the 1% level, demonstrating the validity of our conclusion after utilizing the growth in labor remuneration as a proxy for labor investment.

5.5. The Impact of Non-Labor Investment

Labor investment and non-labor investment are often complementary [91], so non-labor investment may influence our results. Following Jung et al. (2014) [11], we test the influence of non-labor investment on our hypothesized relationship. In particular, for capital, acquisition, and advertising expenditures, we divide the sample into different subsamples according to the association between a firm’s net hiring and the specific type of non-labor investment. If a company expands or reduces its labor investment and a specific type of non-labor investment simultaneously, then it shows a positive correlation, and we add the sample firm to the positive group. If a firm expands (reduces) labor investment and reduces (expands) a specific type of non-labor investment, it shows a negative correlation, and we add the sample to the negative group. If the amount of non-labor investment is missing or zero, we add it to the uncertain group. We then estimate Equation (2) for each group. If our hypothesized relationship is dominated by non-labor investment, then we expect a significant coefficient of CSR only in the positive group, which indicates that the two types of investment are complementary. As we report in Table 11, only the coefficient of CSR in the positive group of advertising expenditure (column (6)) is not significant. In other cases, the coefficients of CSR are all significantly negative. This proves that non-labor investment does not interfere with our main results.

5.6. Additional Control Variables

We add more control variables to the model. These control variables are not included in Equation (2) because the requirements of their data will result in additional sample losses. First, as regional marketization and economic development may affect the accumulation of human capital [92], we add regional marketization level (MKT) and regional GDP growth (GDP) to Equation (2) to account for the impact of the macroeconomic environment on labor investment efficiency. We use the marketization total index score as a proxy for the regional marketization level [93]. Larger values of MKT indicate higher marketization levels. We present the results after adding the two macroenvironment control variables in column (1) of Table 12. Second, considering the interference of equity structure on corporate investment, we add the largest shareholder’s shareholding (FHOLD) and the equity balance degree (SHBAL). The results are listed in column (2). Third, to account for the impact of the governance of the board of directors [43], we add the combination of CEO and board chair (BOTH), independent director proportion (INDIR), and the number of directors (DIRNUM) as control variables. If the CEO is also the board chair, then BOTH is 1, and 0 otherwise. The results are listed in column (3). Fourth, we avoid the possible impact of management incentives on labor investment efficiency by adding management shareholding (MGTSH) and management compensation (MGTWG) as control variables, where the total management compensation is the log of total management monetary compensation. The regression results are listed in column (4). Fifth, according to the research results of Jung et al. (2014) [11], we add accounting quality (AQ) to Equation (2) as a control variable, which we obtained from the modified Jones Model [94]. Column (5) provides the results. Finally, we include all the ten additional control variables simultaneously in Equation (2) and provide the results in column (6). In columns (1) to (6), the coefficients of CSR are all significantly negative at the 1% level, and our main conclusion still holds. Meanwhile, the coefficient of BOTH is significantly positive, supporting the view that appointing the CEO as the chair of the board does not improve the decisions around labor investment [36]. The coefficients of DIRNUM and MGTWG are significantly negative, indicating that larger boards and higher management compensation will alleviate inefficient labor investment. The regression coefficient of AQ supports the view that reliable accounting information significantly enhances labor investment efficiency [11].

5.7. The Impact of CSR Dimensions on Labor Investment Efficiency

We utilize a comprehensive CSR score as a proxy for CSR performance in the tests above. However, this score includes shareholder responsibility (CSR_SH); employee responsibility (CSR_LAB); supplier, customer, and consumer responsibility (CSR_SUPCUS); environment responsibility (CSR_ENV); and public responsibility (CSR_SOC). The impact of a company’s CSR in different dimensions on labor investment efficiency may vary [95]. To further explore the influence of each CSR dimension on labor investment efficiency, we add five sub-dimension variables of CSR (CSR_SH, CSR_LAB, CSR_SUPCUS, CSR_ENV, and CSR_SOC) to Equation (2). The results are listed in Table 13.
Columns (1) to (3) list the results of the influence of shareholder responsibility on labor investment efficiency. In the full sample (column (1)) and the labor underinvestment sample (column (3)), the coefficients of CSR_SH are significantly negative at the 1% level, as expected. However, in the overinvestment sample (column (2)), the coefficient of CSR_SH is not significant. We investigate the underlying cause by performing regressions for the over-hiring and under-firing subsamples (the subsamples of overinvestment). We see that the influence of shareholder responsibility on labor overinvestment is more concentrated in the over-hiring subsample (the coefficient of CSR_SH is −0.008, t-statistic = −2.38) and not significant in the under-firing subsample (the coefficient of CSR_SH is −0.002, t-statistic = −1.48). To save space, we omit these results from Table 13. To maximize shareholders’ wealth, firms should reduce redundant employees in timely manner, but China’s new labor law in 2008 restricts dismissals and requires more layoff compensation, which makes it harder for firms to fire redundant employees. Columns (4) to (6) show the test results of the influence of employee responsibility on labor investment efficiency. Similarly, the coefficients of CSR_LAB in columns (4) and (6) are significantly negative, consistent with expectations. However, in the overinvestment sample, the coefficient of CSR_LAB is not significant (column (5)). In fact, to assume employee responsibility means that firms should hire as many workers as possible, treat them with welfare higher than the legal standard, and avoid layoffs [67], which offsets the inhibiting effect of CSR on labor overinvestment. Columns (7) to (9) report the results of CSR_SUPCUS. The coefficients of CSR_SUPCUS are significantly negative at the 1% level (columns (7) and (8)), consistent with expectations, but are not significant in the labor underinvestment sample (column (9)). Supplier, customer, and consumer responsibility means that firms tend to issue more prepayments for their suppliers, provide more credit financing for their customers, and commit a longer time to guarantee product quality for their customers. These behaviors may occupy the cash flow for labor investment to a certain extent and offset the influence of CSR in alleviating labor underinvestment. Columns (10) to (12) report the results of environmental responsibility. The coefficients of CSR_ENV are significantly negative at the 1% level in all three kinds of sample, consistent with expectations. Columns (13) to (15) show the results of public responsibility. The coefficient of CSR_SOC is significant only in the underinvestment sample (column (15)), but not significant in the full or overinvestment samples (columns (13) and (14)). This result is likely because public responsibility (e.g., charitable giving) is easy to implement but will bring high short-term returns and is sometimes regarded as a “fig leaf” to divert social attention away from negative information about the firm [65]. Hence, the performance of public responsibility may actually indicate agency conflict and is not conducive to restraining overinvestment in labor.

6. Conclusions

In this study, we utilize a sample of Chinese listed companies to investigate the connection between CSR and labor investment efficiency. It is found that CSR can enhance labor investment efficiency. The relationship remains valid after implementing the 2SLS methods to address the endogeneity problem. We also perform robustness tests of using alternative proxy variables for labor investment efficiency, considering the impact of non-labor investment, and adding additional control variables. Dividing inefficient labor investment into overinvestment and underinvestment subsamples further supports our conclusion that good CSR performance can improve labor investment efficiency by inhibiting overinvestment and underinvestment simultaneously.
We also examine the moderating effect of property rights and find that compared to SOEs, the influence of CSR is more significant in non-SOEs. Second, we test the moderating effect of financing constraints and find a stronger connection between CSR and labor investment efficiency in firms facing greater financing constraints. Third, we find that higher labor adjustment costs attract more supervision from stakeholders and will strengthen the impact of CSR on labor investment efficiency. Fourth, our tests of the sub-dimensions of CSR confirm that CSR can inhibit inefficient labor investment in most cases.
This study supports the previous literature about the economic consequence of CSR. Consistent with the previous literature, CSR can improve corporate governance [19,21] and therefore reduce agency costs, which is against the view that CSR is a manifestation of agency problems [27]. In addition, CSR reduces labor underinvestment through alleviating financial constraints and supports the signaling theory [61,70] that CSR acts as a positive signal and reduces costs of capital [22,63]. The previous literature on CSR mainly focused on the firms of developed countries [19,21,22], but we select China as the research setting and provide empirical evidence from an emerging economy to complement the literature.
This study also extends the research on the influencing factors of labor investment efficiency. The previous literature on firms’ investment decision-making primarily focused on capital investment efficiency and innovation investment efficiency [7,8], but in recent years, labor investment efficiency has gradually garnered significant attention. The existing research on labor investment efficiency mainly focuses on CEO traits [18,43,44], external monitoring [15,17,45], and legal environment [16,47,48], but we emphasize CSR and its influence on labor investment efficiency and provide additional insights to the current research. Our results are consistent with the view that information asymmetry is a main cause of inefficient labor investment [11,17,41], and high-quality information disclosure and external monitoring will improve labor investment efficiency by reducing labor overinvestment and underinvestment simultaneously.
This study provides practical implications for firm managers and government regulators. The research demonstrates the significant positive impact of CSR activities on firms, which could encourage managers to actively participate in CSR activities to improve resource allocation efficiency. The results of moderating-effect tests provide differentiated instructions according to the property rights, financial constraints, and labor adjustment costs and are conducive for firms to adapt to their own conditions and select suitable paths to enhance investment efficiency. Since the development of China’s CSR overall is still insufficient, regulators should continue implementing CSR policies, improve the CSR evaluation system, and encourage more firms to undertake social responsibility.

Author Contributions

Conceptualization, Z.Y.; methodology, Z.Y. and J.Y.; formal analysis, Z.Y. and J.Y.; investigation, Z.Y.; resources, Y.Y.; data curation, J.Y.; writing—original draft preparation, Z.Y. and J.Y.; writing—review and editing, Z.Y., J.Y. and Y.Y.; visualization, Y.Y.; supervision, Z.Y.; project administration, Z.Y. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This work was supported by The National Social Science Fund of China [Grant Number: 19BGL074].

Institutional Review Board Statement

Not applicable.

Informed Consent Statement

Not applicable.

Data Availability Statement

The data used to support the findings of this study are available from the corresponding author upon request.

Acknowledgments

The authors are grateful to the anonymous reviewers and editor for their comments and suggestions on this study.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

References

  1. Jensen, M. Value Maximisation, Stakeholder Theory, and the Corporate Objective Function. Eur. Financ. Manag. 2001, 7, 297–317. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Carroll, A.B. A Three-Dimensional Conceptual Model of Corporate Performance. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1979, 4, 497. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Benabou, R.; Tirole, J. Individual and Corporate Social Responsibility. Economica 2018, 77, 1–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Kim, Y.; Park, M.S.; Wier, B. Is Earnings Quality Associated with Corporate Social Responsibility? Account. Rev. 2012, 87, 761–796. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Lu, C.; Zhao, X.; Dai, J. Corporate Social Responsibility and Insider Trading: Evidence from China. Sustainability 2018, 10, 3163. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Lins, K.V.; Servaes, H.; Tamayo, A. Social Capital, Trust, and Firm Performance: The Value of Corporate Social Responsibility during the Financial Crisis. J. Financ. 2017, 72, 1785–1824. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Cook, K.A.; Romi, A.M.; Sánchez, D.; Sánchez, J.M. The Influence of Corporate Social Responsibility on Investment Efficiency and Innovation. J. Bus. Financ. Account. 2019, 46, 494–537. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Wang, X.; Shen, X.; Yang, Y. Does Environmental Information Disclosure Make Firms’ Investments More Efficient? Evidence from Measure 2007 of Chinese A-Listed Companies. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1895. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Lee, J.; Kim, E. The Influence of Corporate Environmental Responsibility on Overinvestment Behavior: Evidence from South Korea. Sustainability 2020, 12, 1901. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Hamermesh, D.S. Labour Demand and the Source of Adjustment Costs. Econ. J. 1995, 105, 620. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  11. Jung, B.; Lee, W.-J.; Weber, D.P. Financial Reporting Quality and Labor Investment Efficiency. Contemp. Account. Res. 2014, 31, 1047–1076. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Erosa, A.; Koreshkova, T.; Restuccia, D. How Important Is Human Capital? A Quantitative Theory Assessment of World Income Inequality. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2010, 77, 1421–1449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  13. Zingales, L. In Search of New Foundations. J. Financ. 2000, 55, 1623–1653. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Pinnuck, M.; Lillis, A.M. Profits versus Losses: Does Reporting an Accounting Loss Act as a Heuristic Trigger to Exercise the Abandonment Option and Divest Employees? Account. Rev. 2007, 82, 1031–1053. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  15. Ghaly, M.; Dang, V.A.; Stathopoulos, K. Institutional Investors’ Horizons and Corporate Employment Decisions. J. Corp. Financ. 2020, 64, 101634. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Cao, Z. Does Trade Secrets Protection Affect Labor Investment Strategy? Evidence from the Inevitable Disclosure Doctrine. SSRN Electron. J. 2019. Available online: https://api.semanticscholar.org/CorpusID:219384620 (accessed on 1 October 2019). [CrossRef]
  17. Mo, K.; Lee, K.Y. (Kailey) Analyst Following, Group Affiliation, and Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from Korea. Sustainability 2019, 11, 3152. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Lai, S.; Li, X.; Chan, K.C. CEO Overconfidence and Labor Investment Efficiency. N. Am. J. Econ. Financ. 2021, 55, 101319. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  19. Ntim, C.G.; Soobaroyen, T. Corporate Governance and Performance in Socially Responsible Corporations: New Empirical Insights from a Neo-Institutional Framework. Corp. Gov. Int. Rev. 2013, 21, 468–494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Hong, H.; Kacperczyk, M. The Price of Sin: The Effects of Social Norms on Markets. J. Financ. Econ. 2009, 93, 15–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Dhaliwal, D.S.; Li, O.Z.; Tsang, A.; Yang, Y.G. Voluntary Nonfinancial Disclosure and the Cost of Equity Capital: The Initiation of Corporate Social Responsibility Reporting. Account. Rev. 2011, 86, 59–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. El Ghoul, S.; Guedhami, O.; Kwok, C.C.Y.; Mishra, D.R. Does Corporate Social Responsibility Affect the Cost of Capital? J. Bank. Financ. 2011, 35, 2388–2406. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  23. Godfrey, P.C.; Merrill, C.B.; Hansen, J.M. The Relationship between Corporate Social Responsibility and Shareholder Value: An Empirical Test of the Risk Management Hypothesis. Strateg. Manag. J. 2009, 30, 425–445. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  24. Zeng, T. Relationship between Corporate Social Responsibility and Tax Avoidance: International Evidence. Soc. Responsib. J. 2019, 15, 244–257. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Do, T.K.; Le, A.-T. Shareholder Litigation Rights and Labor Investment Efficiency. Financ. Res. Lett. 2022, 46, 102296. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. Jiang, D.; Lan, M.; Li, W.; Shen, Y. Threat or Opportunity? Unveiling the Impact of Population Aging on Corporate Labor Investment Efficiency. Pac.-Basin Financ. J. 2024, 85, 102322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Friedman, M. The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits. New York Times Magazine, 13 September 1970; 122–126. [Google Scholar]
  28. Freeman, R.E.; Reed, D.L. Stockholders and Stakeholders: A New Perspective on Corporate Governance. Calif. Manag. Rev. 1983, 25, 88–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Mattern, C.O.; Gutilla, M.J.; Bright, D.L.; Kirby, T.E.; Hinchcliff, K.W.; Devor, S.T. Maximal Lactate Steady State Declines during the Aging Process. J. Appl. Physiol. 2003, 95, 2576–2582. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. Porter, M.; Kramer, M. Strategy and Society: The Link between Competitive Advantage and Corporate Social Responsibility. Harv. Bus. Rev. 2007, 84, 78–92, 163. [Google Scholar]
  31. Nguyen, P.-A.; Kecskés, A.; Mansi, S. Does Corporate Social Responsibility Create Shareholder Value? The Importance of Long-Term Investors. J. Bank. Financ. 2020, 112, 105217. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  32. Wang, H.; Lu, W.; Ye, M.; Chau, K.W.; Zhang, X. The Curvilinear Relationship between Corporate Social Performance and Corporate Financial Performance: Evidence from the International Construction Industry. J. Clean. Prod. 2016, 137, 1313–1322. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Hirsch, S.; Petersen, T.; Koppenberg, M.; Hartmann, M. CSR and Firm Profitability: Evidence from a Meta-regression Analysis. J. Econ. Surv. 2023, 37, 993–1032. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Ferrés, D.; Marcet, F. Corporate Social Responsibility and Corporate Misconduct. J. Bank. Financ. 2021, 127, 106079. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  35. Koh, K.; Li, H.; Tong, Y.H. Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) Performance and Stakeholder Engagement: Evidence from the Quantity and Quality of CSR Disclosures. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2023, 30, 504–517. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  36. Heinkel, R.; Kraus, A.; Zechner, J. The Effect of Green Investment on Corporate Behavior. J. Financ. Quant. Anal. 2001, 36, 431–449. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Peloza, J.; Papania, L. The Missing Link between Corporate Social Responsibility and Financial Performance: Stakeholder Salience and Identification. Corp. Reput. Rev. 2008, 11, 169–181. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  38. Saeidi, S.P.; Sofian, S.; Saeidi, P.; Saeidi, S.P.; Saaeidi, S.A. How Does Corporate Social Responsibility Contribute to Firm Financial Performance? The Mediating Role of Competitive Advantage, Reputation, and Customer Satisfaction. J. Bus. Res. 2015, 68, 341–350. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Bardos, K.S.; Ertugrul, M.; Gao, L.S. Corporate Social Responsibility, Product Market Perception, and Firm Value. J. Corp. Financ. 2020, 62, 101588. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  40. Yang, Y.; Jiang, Y. The Impact of Suppliers’ CSR Controversies on Buyers’ Market Value: The Moderating Role of Social Capital. J. Purch. Supply Manag. 2024, 30, 100904. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Ben-Nasr, H.; Alshwer, A.A. Does Stock Price Informativeness Affect Labor Investment Efficiency? J. Corp. Financ. 2016, 38, 249–271. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. Bai, M.; Fu, Y.; Sun, M. Corporate Diversification and Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. Econ. Model. 2023, 127, 106482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  43. Khedmati, M.; Sualihu, M.A.; Yawson, A. CEO-Director Ties and Labor Investment Efficiency. J. Corp. Financ. 2019, 65, 101492. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  44. Mo, K.; Kim, Y.J.; Park, K.J. Chief Executive Officer inside Debt Holdings and Labor Investment Efficiency. Asia-Pac. J. Financ. Stud. 2019, 48, 476–502. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  45. Cao, Z.; Rees, W. Do Employee-Friendly Firms Invest More Efficiently? Evidence from Labor Investment Efficiency. J. Corp. Financ. 2020, 65, 101744. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  46. Adwan, S. Does Employee Ownership Improve Labor Investment Efficiency? Evidence from European Firms. Econ. Lett. 2024, 238, 111717. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  47. Kong, D.; Liu, S.; Xiang, J. Political Promotion and Labor Investment Efficiency. China Econ. Rev. 2018, 50, 273–293. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  48. Ding, H.; Liu, C.; Ni, X. Creditor Protection and Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. Financ. Res. Lett. 2023, 58, 104680. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  49. Chen, C.; Jiang, D.; Lan, M.; Li, W.; Ye, L. Does Environmental Regulation Affect Labor Investment Efficiency? Evidence from a Quasi-Natural Experiment in China. Int. Rev. Econ. Financ. 2022, 80, 82–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  50. Singh, A. Oil Price Uncertainty and Labor Investment Efficiency. Energy Econ. 2022, 116, 106407. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  51. Jensen, M.C.; Meckling, W.H. Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs and Ownership Structure. J. Financ. Econ. 1976, 3, 305–360. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  52. Bertrand, M.; Mullainathan, S. Enjoying the Quiet Life? Corporate Governance and Managerial Preferences. J. Political Econ. 2003, 111, 1043–1075. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  53. Pagno, M.; Volpin, P.F. Managers, Workers, and Corporate Control. J. Financ. 2005, 60, 841–868. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  54. Narayanan, M.P. Managerial Incentives for Short-Term Results. J. Financ. 1985, 40, 1469–1484. [Google Scholar]
  55. Dixit, A. Investment and Employment Dynamics in the Short Run and the Long Run. Oxf. Econ. Pap. 1997, 49, 1–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  56. Oi, W.Y. Labor as a Quasi-Fixed Factor. J. Political Econ. 1962, 70, 538–555. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  57. Hamermesh, D.S.; Pfann, G.A. Adjustment Costs in Factor Demand. J. Econ. Lit. 1996, 34, 1264–1292. [Google Scholar]
  58. Zhao, J.; Wang, M. Stakeholders, Informal Engagement and Corporate Governance—Based on NVC Lighting’s Case Study. Manag. World 2016, 138–149, 167. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  59. Althoff, C. Corporate Social Responsibility as an Element of Good Corporate Governance—A Chronology of Its Historical and Contemporary Development. Int. J. Econ. Account. 2021, 10, 57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Jensen, M.C. Agency Cost of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and Takeovers. Am. Econ. Rev. 1986, 76, 323–329. [Google Scholar]
  61. Spence, M. Job Market Signaling. Q. J. Econ. 1973, 87, 355–374. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  62. Conte, F.; Sardanelli, D.; Vollero, A.; Siano, A. CSR Signaling in Controversial and Noncontroversial Industries: CSR Policies, Governance Structures, and Transparency Tools. Eur. Manag. J. 2023, 41, 274–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  63. Tan, W.; Tsang, A.; Wang, W.; Zhang, W. Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) Disclosure and the Choice between Bank Debt and Public Debt. Account. Horiz. 2020, 34, 151–173. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  64. Shou, Y.; Shao, J.; Wang, W.; Lai, K. The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Trade Credit: Evidence from Chinese Small and Medium-Sized Manufacturing Enterprises. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2020, 230, 107809. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  65. Koehn, D.; Ueng, J. Is Philanthropy Being Used by Corporate Wrongdoers to Buy Good Will? J. Manag. Gov. 2009, 14, 1–16. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  66. Barnea, A.; Rubin, A. Corporate Social Responsibility as a Conflict between Shareholders. J. Bus. Ethics 2010, 97, 71–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Liu, Y.; Song, Y. A Legislative Research on the Corporate Social Responsibility for Increasing Employment. Mod. Law Sci. 2006, 28, 54–61. [Google Scholar]
  68. Ghadhab, I.; Nizar, H.; Benkraiem, R.; Lakhal, F. Cross-Listing Dynamics and Labor Investment Efficiency: International Evidence. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 2023, 88, 102678. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Wen, W.; Song, J. Executives’ Overseas Background and Corporate Social Responsibility. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2017, 30, 119–131. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  70. Wang, J.; Li, Y.; Wu, X. Corporate Social Responsibility as the Signal of Firm Future Performance: Evidence from Chinese Market. Chin. J. Manag. Sci. 2018, 26, 31–41. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  71. Cella, C. Institutional Investors and Corporate Investment. Financ. Res. Lett. 2020, 32, 101196. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  72. Biddle, G.C.; Hilary, G.; Verdi, R.S. How Does Financial Reporting Quality Relate to Investment Efficiency? J. Account. Econ. 2009, 48, 112–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Fama, E.F.; MacBeth, J.D. Risk, Return, and Equilibrium: Empirical Tests. J. Political Econ. 1973, 81, 607–636. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  74. Hartnell, C.A.; Ou, A.Y.; Kinicki, A. Organizational Culture and Organizational Effectiveness: A Meta-Analytic Investigation of the Competing Values Framework’s Theoretical Suppositions. J. Appl. Psychol. 2011, 96, 677–694. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  75. Tierney, W.G.; Schein, E.H. Organizational Culture and Leadership. Acad. Manag. Rev. 1986, 11, 677. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  76. Dobers, P.; Halme, M. Corporate Social Responsibility and Developing Countries. Corp. Soc. Responsib. Environ. Manag. 2009, 16, 237–249. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  77. Longenecker, J.G.; McKinney, J.A.; Moore, C.W. Religious Intensity, Evangelical Christianity, and Business Ethics: An Empirical Study. J. Bus. Ethics 2004, 55, 371–384. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  78. Ibrahim, N.A.; Rue, L.W.; McDougall, P.P.; Greene, G.R. Characteristics and Practices of “Christian-Based” Companies. J. Bus. Ethics 1991, 10, 123–132. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  79. Brammer, S.; Williams, G.; Zinkin, J. Religion and Attitudes to Corporate Social Responsibility in a Large Cross-Country Sample. J. Bus. Ethics 2006, 71, 229–243. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  80. Ni, C. The Influences of Top Managers’ Religious Piety on Corporate Social Responsibility—An Integrated Perspective Based on Theories of Institution and Theory of Reasoned Action. J. Shanxi Univ. Financ. Econ. 2016, 38, 92–102. [Google Scholar]
  81. Arouri, M.; Gomes, M.; Pukthuanthong, K. Corporate Social Responsibility and M&a Uncertainty. J. Corp. Financ. 2019, 56, 176–198. [Google Scholar]
  82. Liu, S.; Wu, D. Competing by Conducting Good Deeds: The Peer Effect of Corporate Social Responsibility. Financ. Res. Lett. 2016, 16, 47–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  83. Zellner, A.; Theil, H. Three-Stage Least Squares: Simultaneous Estimation of Simultaneous Equations. Econometrica 1962, 30, 54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  84. Lin, J.Y.; Cai, F.; Li, Z. Competition, Policy Burdens, and State-Owned Enterprise Reform. Am. Econ. Rev. 1998, 88, 422–427. [Google Scholar]
  85. Liao, L.; Liu, B.; Wang, H. China׳s Secondary Privatization: Perspectives from the Split-Share Structure Reform. J. Financ. Econ. 2014, 113, 500–518. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  86. Li, Y.; Yang, L. Empirical Study on Accounting Conservatism and the Inefficient Investment Action under Different Natures of Property Rights. Forecasting 2014, 33, 36–41. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  87. Tong, A.; Ma, X. Macro Environment, Nature of Property Right and Inefficient Investments. Manag. Rev. 2013, 25, 12–20. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  88. Campello, M.; Graham, J.R.; Harvey, C.R. The Real Effects of Financial Constraints: Evidence from a Financial Crisis. J. Financ. Econ. 2010, 97, 470–487. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  89. Kaplan, S.N.; Zingales, L. Do Investment-Cash Flow Sensitivities Provide Useful Measures of Financing Constraints? Q. J. Econ. 1997, 112, 169–215. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  90. Whited, T.M.; Wu, G. Financial Constraints Risk. Rev. Financ. Stud. 2006, 19, 531–559. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  91. Beard, R.T.; Ford, G.S.; Kim, H. Capital Investment and Employment in the Information Sector. Telecommun. Policy 2014, 38, 371–382. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  92. Cebula, R.J. The Impact of Economic Freedom and Personal Freedom on Net In-Migration in the U.S.: A State-Level Empirical Analysis, 2000 to 2010. J. Labor Res. 2014, 35, 88–103. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  93. Wang, X.; Fan, G.; Hu, L. Marketization Index of China’s Provinces: NERI Report 2018; Social Sciences Academic Press: Beijing, China, 2019. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
  94. Dechow, P.M.; Dichev, I.D. The Quality of Accruals and Earnings: The Role of Accrual Estimation Errors. Account. Rev. 2002, 77, 35–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  95. Galema, R.; Plantinga, A.; Scholtens, B. The Stocks at Stake: Return and Risk in Socially Responsible Investment. J. Bank. Financ. 2008, 32, 2646–2654. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. The definitions of main variables.
Table 1. The definitions of main variables.
VariableDefinition
AB_NET_HIREThe labor investment efficiency of a firm, namely the residuals of Equation (2).
CSRCSR score extracted from the Hexun database.
MTBMarket-to-book ratio.
SIZENatural logarithm of firm’s market value.
QUICKQuick ratio, which is equal to [current assets - inventory]/current liabilities.
LEVThe ratio of total debt to total assets.
DIVDUMA dummy variable, which is equal to 1 if the firm pays dividends and 0 otherwise.
STD_CFOThe standard deviation of the cash flow in the previous five years.
STD_SALESThe standard deviation of the sales revenue in the previous five years.
TANGIBLEThe ratio of tangible assets to total assets.
LOSSA dummy variable, which is equal to 1 if the firm suffers a loss and 0 otherwise.
INSTIInstitutional investors’ shareholding.
STD_NET_HIREThe standard deviation of the employee change rate in the previous five years.
LABOR_INTENSITYLabor intensity of the firm, namely the number of employees divided by total assets.
AB_INVEST_OTHERCapital investment efficiency calculated according to Biddle et al. (2009) [72].
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the main variables.
Table 2. Descriptive statistics of the main variables.
VariableNMeanMedianStandard
Deviation
Q1Q3
AB_NET_HIRE15,9980.1990.1050.3420.0480.201
CSR15,9982.4802.1281.8001.4942.846
MTB15,9984.1592.6545.7791.6694.406
SIZE15,99822.63022.5290.95821.95123.200
QUICK15,9981.0890.7241.2160.4101.256
LEV15,9980.4840.4850.2120.3210.642
DIVDUM15,9980.6531.0000.4760.0001.000
STD_CFO(/1010)15,9980.0490.0150.1000.0070.040
STD_SALES(/1010)15,9980.1790.0450.4180.0180.130
TANGIBLE15,9980.2410.1910.2110.0840.343
LOSS15,9980.1230.0000.3280.0000.000
INSTI15,9980.0450.0200.0620.0030.061
STD_NET_HIRE15,9980.6630.1572.3810.0790.350
LABOR_INTENSITY(/10−4)15,9980.0070.0050.0070.0030.010
AB_INVEST_OTHER15,9980.0400.0280.0440.0140.048
Table 3. Pearson correlation matrix.
Table 3. Pearson correlation matrix.
V1V2V3V4V5V6V7V8V9V10V11V12V13V14V15
V1:AB_NET_HIRE1
V2:CSR−0.064 ***1
V3:MTB0.150 ***−0.165 ***1
V4:SIZE−0.082 ***0.339 ***−0.057 ***1
V5:QUICK0.041 ***0.0080.025 ***0.019 **1
V6:LEV0.010−0.040 ***0.118 ***−0.019 **−0.619 ***1
V7:DIVDUM−0.125 ***0.409 ***−0.256 ***0.316 ***0.105 ***−0.191 ***1
V8:STD_CFO−0.057 ***0.213 ***−0.151 ***0.530 ***−0.168 ***0.281 ***0.115 ***1
V9:STD_SALES−0.060 ***0.197 ***−0.131 ***0.496 ***−0.151 ***0.250 ***0.105 ***0.717 ***1
V10:TANGIBLE0.017 **−0.079 ***0.051 ***−0.115 ***−0.130 ***0.046 ***−0.134 ***−0.003−0.014 *1
V11:LOSS0.076 ***−0.407 ***0.152 ***−0.189 ***−0.093 ***0.188 ***−0.455 ***−0.052 ***−0.053 ***0.099 ***1
V12:INSTI−0.0060.262 ***0.022 ***0.309 ***0.042 ***−0.050 ***0.227 ***0.050 ***0.071 ***−0.073 ***−0.144 ***1
V13:STD_NET_HIRE0.034 ***0.032 ***0.025 ***0.072 ***−0.027 ***0.047 ***−0.043 ***0.034 ***0.074 ***−0.025 ***−0.022 ***−0.0101
V14:LABOR_INTENSITY−0.052 ***−0.085 ***0.148 ***−0.230 ***−0.031 ***−0.078 ***−0.081 ***−0.213 ***−0.132 ***0.126 ***0.057 ***0.058 ***0.023 ***1
V15:AB_INVEST_OTHER0.070 ***−0.022 ***0.074 ***−0.004−0.025 ***0.032 ***−0.071 ***−0.053 ***−0.014 *0.126 ***−0.0090.023 ***0.063 ***0.028 ***1
Note: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed).
Table 4. The effect of corporate social responsibility on labor investment efficiency.
Table 4. The effect of corporate social responsibility on labor investment efficiency.
VariableBaselineFirm Fixed EffectsRandom EffectsFama–MacBethGMM
AB_NET_HIREAB_NET_HIREAB_NET_HIREAB_NET_HIREAB_NET_HIRE
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)
Intercept0.554 ***1.757 ***0.674 ***0.581 ***0.843 ***
(4.78)(6.78)(6.28)(4.04)(5.42)
CSR−0.007 ***−0.005 **−0.006 ***−0.005 *−0.005 **
(−4.07)(−2.54)(−3.35)(−1.87)(−2.00)
MTB0.008 ***0.008 ***0.008 ***0.008 ***0.008 ***
(8.92)(6.45)(9.09)(9.71)(5.20)
SIZE−0.013 ***−0.065 ***−0.017 ***−0.013 *−0.026 ***
(−2.59)(−5.81)(−3.62)(−2.24)(−3.84)
QUICK0.011 **0.019 ***0.011 **0.012 *0.005
(2.43)(2.70)(2.50)(1.87)(0.82)
LEV−0.065 ***−0.083 *−0.053 **−0.063 **−0.073 **
(−2.72)(−1.92)(−2.24)(−2.50)(−2.15)
DIVDUM−0.035 ***−0.022 **−0.038 ***−0.036 ***−0.020 **
(−4.48)(−2.30)(−4.87)(−3.78)(−2.24)
STD_CFO−0.055−0.1070.044−0.079−0.015
(−1.54)(−1.58)(1.29)(−1.72)(−0.38)
STD_SALES0.003−0.041 ***−0.0110.004−0.001
(0.38)(−2.58)(−1.56)(0.48)(−0.14)
TANGIBLE0.0390.053−0.0090.0240.053
(1.53)(1.46)(−0.44)(0.73)(1.55)
LOSS0.039 ***0.035 ***0.035 ***0.043 ***0.038 ***
(3.45)(2.82)(3.10)(4.66)(2.99)
INSTI0.0610.378 ***0.0650.0410.155 **
(1.15)(4.86)(1.27)(0.74)(2.26)
STD_NET_HIRE0.002 *−0.021 ***0.005 ***0.003 **−0.015 ***
(1.84)(−8.12)(4.22)(2.44)(−5.61)
LABOR_INTENSITY−5.860 ***−8.955 ***−6.287 ***−5.803 ***−6.473 ***
(−9.70)(−6.01)(−10.74)(−8.55)(−6.58)
AB_INVEST_OTHER0.328 ***0.170 **0.308 ***0.291 ***0.012
(4.23)(2.01)(3.99)(3.39)(0.12)
Year FEYESYESYESNOYES
Industry FEYESNONOYESYES
Adj. R20.0850.076---
N15,99815,99815,99815,99815,998
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 5. Two-stage least squares (2SLS) regression.
Table 5. Two-stage least squares (2SLS) regression.
VariableFirst StageSecond StageFirst StageSecond StageFirst StageSecond Stage
CSRAB_NET_HIRECSRAB_NET_HIRECSRAB_NET_HIRE
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Intercept−10.083 ***−0.250−10.079 ***−0.006−10.165 ***−0.070
(−14.79)(−0.48)(−14.18)(−0.02)(−14.28)(−0.28)
CSR −0.088 * −0.053 ** −0.059 ***
(−1.77) (−2.31) (−2.74)
Religion0.004 *** 0.004 ***
(3.09) (2.66)
Average 0.183 *** 0.178 ***
(5.96) (5.85)
ControlsYESYESYESYESYESYES
Year FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
N15,99815,99815,09815,09815,09815,098
Kleibergen–Paap rk LM statistic 9.4 *** 35.4 *** 40.3 ***
Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F statistic 9.5 35.5 21.5
Overidentification test (p-value) - - 0.397
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level. The number of religious sites is divided by 100 to increase the value of the regression coefficient.
Table 6. The effect of CSR on specific type of inefficient labor investment.
Table 6. The effect of CSR on specific type of inefficient labor investment.
VariableOVER_INVUNDER_INV
TOTALOVER_HIREUNDER_FIRETOTALUNDER_HIREOVER_FIRE
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Intercept1.045 ***1.939 ***0.516 **0.1050.167 **−0.065
(3.18)(3.86)(2.23)(1.63)(2.27)(−0.46)
CSR−0.015 ***−0.018 **−0.006−0.003 ***−0.003 ***−0.006 **
(−2.68)(−2.21)(−1.63)(−3.33)(−2.90)(−2.55)
MTB0.011 ***0.023 ***0.004 ***0.004 ***0.005 ***0.002 ***
(5.40)(5.78)(3.12)(8.02)(7.38)(2.87)
SIZE−0.026 *−0.059 ***−0.0120.0030.0000.009
(−1.85)(−2.74)(−1.23)(1.18)(0.13)(1.33)
QUICK0.041 ***0.036 *0.0120.005 ***0.005 **0.004
(3.03)(1.87)(1.28)(2.95)(2.33)(0.93)
LEV−0.083−0.102−0.027−0.044 ***−0.050 ***0.030
(−1.30)(−0.87)(−0.80)(−3.26)(−3.01)(1.31)
DIVDUM−0.029−0.096 ***0.000−0.030 ***−0.034 ***−0.023 ***
(−1.33)(−2.62)(0.03)(−6.88)(−6.51)(−2.99)
STD_CFO−0.070−0.0970.020−0.042 **−0.031−0.116 ***
(−0.65)(−0.68)(0.22)(−2.04)(−1.29)(−2.75)
STD_SALES−0.0010.033−0.015−0.004−0.0040.007
(−0.04)(1.00)(−0.88)(−0.86)(−0.74)(0.61)
TANGIBLE0.159 **0.251 **−0.006−0.030 **−0.025−0.044 **
(2.42)(2.56)(−0.14)(−2.39)(−1.64)(−2.25)
LOSS−0.0020.167 **0.0180.052 ***0.088 ***0.016 *
(−0.07)(2.08)(1.28)(7.24)(7.95)(1.82)
INSTI0.272 *0.128−0.061−0.067 ***−0.077 ***−0.133
(1.70)(0.63)(−0.58)(−2.76)(−2.98)(−1.39)
STD_NET_HIRE−0.004−0.006−0.0000.005 ***0.005 ***0.003
(−1.28)(−1.37)(−0.07)(4.65)(4.23)(0.98)
LABOR_INTENSITY−17.946 ***−22.150 ***−9.475 ***−0.132−0.1930.431
(−9.38)(−7.32)(−7.70)(−0.40)(−0.49)(0.75)
AB_INVEST_OTHER0.392 *0.3050.0630.250 ***0.267 ***0.112
(1.69)(1.15)(0.24)(6.49)(6.25)(1.07)
Year FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.1200.1510.0650.1560.1760.078
N54103190222010,58888581730
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 7. Cross-sectional analyses: the moderating effect of property rights.
Table 7. Cross-sectional analyses: the moderating effect of property rights.
VariableAB_NET_HIREOVER_INVUNDER_INV
(1)(2)(3)
Intercept0.561 ***1.044 ***0.107 *
(4.84)(3.17)(1.67)
CSR−0.013 ***−0.031 ***−0.006 ***
(−5.20)(−4.17)(−4.33)
SOE−0.057 ***−0.084 ***−0.043 ***
(−5.19)(−2.84)(−6.51)
SOE × CSR0.010 ***0.027 ***0.006 ***
(3.41)(3.01)(3.29)
MTB0.008 ***0.011 ***0.004 ***
(8.46)(5.20)(7.34)
SIZE−0.012 **−0.024 *0.004
(−2.40)(−1.70)(1.51)
QUICK0.011 **0.043 ***0.005 ***
(2.55)(3.15)(3.02)
LEV−0.049 **−0.063−0.032 **
(−2.01)(−0.97)(−2.36)
DIVDUM−0.035 ***−0.028−0.029 ***
(−4.43)(−1.30)(−6.83)
STD_CFO−0.049−0.073−0.037 *
(−1.37)(−0.67)(−1.81)
STD_SALES0.003−0.003−0.004
(0.36)(−0.13)(−0.80)
TANGIBLE0.042 *0.162 **−0.028 **
(1.65)(2.46)(−2.28)
LOSS0.036 ***−0.0100.052 ***
(3.26)(−0.33)(7.20)
INSTI0.0600.281 *−0.069 ***
(1.13)(1.75)(−2.79)
STD_NET_HIRE0.002−0.0040.004 ***
(1.60)(−1.27)(4.38)
LABOR_INTENSITY−5.681 ***−17.733 ***−0.015
(−9.46)(−9.32)(−0.05)
AB_INVEST_OTHER0.307 ***0.3790.234 ***
(4.01)(1.64)(6.10)
Year FEYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYES
Adj. R20.0880.1210.163
N15,998541010,588
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 8. Cross-sectional analyses: the moderating effect of financial constraints.
Table 8. Cross-sectional analyses: the moderating effect of financial constraints.
VariableAB_NET_HIREOVER_INVUNDER_INVAB_NET_HIREOVER_INVUNDER_INV
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Intercept0.570 ***1.087 ***0.136 **0.761 ***1.317 ***0.235 ***
(4.87)(3.29)(2.11)(5.85)(3.60)(3.15)
CSR−0.006 ***−0.015 **−0.003 ***−0.099 ***−0.143 *−0.058 ***
(−3.11)(−2.24)(−2.61)(−4.27)(−1.87)(−4.70)
KZ0.008−0.0050.004
(1.48)(−0.32)(1.29)
KZ × CSR−0.003 ***−0.001−0.002 ***
(−2.79)(−0.33)(−3.83)
WW 0.324 ***0.3050.131 *
(2.78)(0.77)(1.84)
WW × CSR −0.088 ***−0.123 *−0.052 ***
(−4.01)(−1.69)(−4.49)
MTB0.008 ***0.012 ***0.004 ***0.007 ***0.011 ***0.004 ***
(8.20)(5.16)(7.41)(7.32)(4.40)(6.55)
SIZE−0.014 ***−0.028 **0.002−0.008−0.0250.004
(−2.73)(−1.97)(0.68)(−1.25)(−1.31)(0.92)
QUICK0.010 **0.039 ***0.004 **0.011 **0.041 ***0.005 ***
(2.33)(2.85)(2.55)(2.40)(3.03)(3.00)
LEV−0.066 **−0.063−0.037 **−0.054 **−0.078−0.042 ***
(−2.50)(−0.91)(−2.55)(−2.13)(−1.09)(−2.98)
DIVDUM−0.035 ***−0.034−0.031 ***−0.026 ***−0.024−0.028 ***
(−4.34)(−1.48)(−7.06)(−2.60)(−0.77)(−5.19)
STD_CFO−0.054−0.063−0.041 **−0.071 **−0.102−0.054 ***
(−1.52)(−0.59)(−2.05)(−1.99)(−0.93)(−2.67)
STD_SALES0.004−0.001−0.003−0.000−0.005−0.007
(0.46)(−0.04)(−0.69)(−0.02)(−0.21)(−1.51)
TANGIBLE0.0380.157 **−0.030 **0.0360.155 **−0.032 **
(1.50)(2.39)(−2.39)(1.42)(2.36)(−2.55)
LOSS0.031 ***−0.0020.046 ***0.024 **−0.0170.044 ***
(2.73)(−0.07)(6.40)(2.13)(−0.57)(6.17)
INSTI0.0580.263−0.072 ***0.0580.266 *−0.065 ***
(1.09)(1.64)(−2.96)(1.10)(1.66)(−2.66)
STD_NET_HIRE0.002 *−0.0040.005 ***0.002 **−0.0040.005 ***
(1.90)(−1.27)(4.64)(2.04)(−1.16)(4.67)
LABOR_INTENSITY−5.962 ***−18.063 ***−0.273−5.975 ***−18.079 ***−0.157
(−9.80)(−9.36)(−0.83)(−9.88)(−9.44)(−0.47)
AB_INVEST_OTHER0.328 ***0.3570.240 ***0.342 ***0.398 *0.252 ***
(4.22)(1.55)(6.03)(4.39)(1.71)(6.47)
Year FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.0860.1200.1580.0870.1200.158
N15,998541010,58815,998541010,588
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 9. Cross-sectional analyses: the moderating effect of labor adjustment costs.
Table 9. Cross-sectional analyses: the moderating effect of labor adjustment costs.
VariableAB_NET_HIREOVER_INVUNDER_INVAB_NET_HIREOVER_INVUNDER_INV
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Intercept0.683 ***1.623 ***0.159 **0.762 ***1.793 ***0.163 **
(5.72)(4.80)(2.45)(5.55)(4.65)(2.23)
CSR−0.006 ***−0.012 **−0.003 ***−0.005 *−0.006−0.004 ***
(−3.23)(−2.06)(−2.75)(−1.95)(−0.77)(−3.13)
BACH0.101 ***0.293 ***−0.007
(2.84)(2.92)(−0.33)
BACH×CSR−0.023 **−0.054 **−0.012 **
(−2.43)(−2.12)(−2.31)
MAST 0.598 ***1.705 ***0.003
(3.06)(3.00)(0.02)
MAST × CSR −0.096 *−0.254 *−0.050 *
(−1.86)(−1.78)(−1.82)
MTB0.009 ***0.013 ***0.005 ***0.009 ***0.014 ***0.004 ***
(8.44)(5.29)(8.09)(7.97)(5.55)(7.30)
SIZE−0.013 ***−0.034 **0.004−0.016 ***−0.041 **0.004
(−2.59)(−2.36)(1.46)(−2.80)(−2.52)(1.37)
QUICK0.007 *0.034 **0.005 ***0.0040.0240.005 **
(1.77)(2.44)(2.69)(0.80)(1.46)(2.20)
LEV−0.070 ***−0.081−0.046 ***−0.091 ***−0.119−0.052 ***
(−2.96)(−1.29)(−3.52)(−3.22)(−1.55)(−3.41)
DIVDUM−0.034 ***−0.031−0.029 ***−0.032 ***−0.024−0.029 ***
(−4.02)(−1.33)(−6.20)(−3.23)(−0.93)(−5.24)
STD_CFO−0.043−0.030−0.044 **−0.045−0.026−0.052 **
(−1.18)(−0.28)(−2.10)(−1.13)(−0.23)(−2.27)
STD_SALES0.0000.000−0.0050.0030.007−0.004
(0.02)(0.02)(−0.94)(0.36)(0.26)(−0.78)
TANGIBLE0.0270.146 **−0.029 **0.0410.175 **−0.022
(1.05)(1.97)(−2.12)(1.33)(2.15)(−1.40)
LOSS0.037 ***−0.0050.052 ***0.045 ***0.0110.053 ***
(3.11)(−0.17)(6.76)(3.30)(0.32)(5.99)
INSTI0.0410.194−0.059 **0.0390.218−0.054 *
(0.76)(1.24)(−2.19)(0.64)(1.18)(−1.84)
STD_NET_HIRE0.002 *−0.0030.004 ***0.002 *−0.0030.004 ***
(1.86)(−0.85)(4.72)(1.68)(−0.76)(4.08)
LABOR_INTENSITY−6.271 ***−17.541 ***−0.778 **−7.537 ***−19.541 ***−1.486 ***
(−8.90)(−8.05)(−2.15)(−8.90)(−7.33)(−3.35)
AB_INVEST_OTHER0.263 ***0.3120.224 ***0.282 ***0.3070.234 ***
(3.43)(1.34)(5.74)(3.20)(1.16)(5.22)
Year and Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.0840.1140.1580.0890.1240.157
N13,7844782900210,51836676851
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 10. Alternative proxies for labor investment efficiency.
Table 10. Alternative proxies for labor investment efficiency.
VariableAB_NET
_HIRE_1
AB_NET
_HIRE2
AB_NET
_HIRE3
AB_NET
_HIRE4
AB_NET
_HIRE5
AB_NET
_HIRE6
AB_NET
_WAGE
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)
Intercept1.614 ***0.710 ***0.4760.900 *1.194 **0.551 ***0.396 ***
(10.28)(4.45)(0.98)(1.67)(2.51)(4.66)(4.59)
CSR−0.009 ***−0.010 ***−0.032 ***−0.030 ***−0.023 ***−0.007 ***−0.005 ***
(−4.40)(−4.38)(−4.16)(−3.64)(−3.38)(−3.79)(−3.65)
ControlsYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Year FEYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.5340.0490.2240.3780.5300.0700.088
N15,99815,99813,56212,38011,37215,99815,608
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 11. The effect of non-labor investment on the association between CSR and labor investment efficiency.
Table 11. The effect of non-labor investment on the association between CSR and labor investment efficiency.
VariableCapital ExpendituresAcquisitions ExpendituresAdvertising Expenses
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
PositiveNegativePositiveNegativeUncertainPositiveNegativeUncertain
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)
Intercept0.682 ***0.377 **0.836 ***0.731 ***0.544 ***0.857 ***0.1820.582 ***
(4.45)(2.31)(4.12)(3.10)(3.28)(3.96)(0.94)(3.15)
CSR−0.008 ***−0.007 ***−0.009 ***−0.008 **−0.004 *−0.003−0.008 **−0.009 ***
(−3.35)(−2.80)(−2.94)(−2.12)(−1.70)(−0.94)(−2.49)(−3.53)
Controls YESYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Year FEYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.0890.0850.1030.0850.0910.0890.0550.102
N84257573532938776792467645946728
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 12. The results when adding additional controls to the baseline model.
Table 12. The results when adding additional controls to the baseline model.
VariableAB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
AB_NET
_HIRE
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)
Intercept0.568 ***0.606 ***0.564 ***0.518 ***0.414 ***0.392 **
(4.88)(4.96)(4.74)(4.20)(3.15)(2.54)
CSR−0.007 ***−0.007 ***−0.007 ***−0.007 ***−0.008 ***−0.006 ***
(−4.05)(−3.82)(−3.82)(−3.80)(−4.21)(−3.31)
MKT−0.002 −0.002
(−0.84) (−1.04)
GDP−0.022 −0.053
(−0.37) (−0.82)
FHOLD −0.032 −0.047
(−1.02) (−1.33)
SHBAL −0.001 0.001
(−0.15) (0.11)
BOTH 0.013 * 0.017 *
(1.73) (1.77)
INDIR −0.072 −0.022
(−1.30) (−0.33)
DIRNUM −0.008 *** −0.008 ***
(−4.36) (−3.68)
MGTSH −0.017 −0.007
(−0.82) (−0.21)
MGTWG −0.000 * −0.000 **
(−1.83) (−2.56)
AQ 0.036 ***0.039 ***
(4.21)(4.28)
Other ControlsYESYESYESYESYESYES
Year FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry FEYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.0850.0850.0870.0850.0870.091
N15,99815,99815,89915,98213,19812,570
Notes: ***, **, and * indicate significance at the 0.01, 0.05, and 0.1 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Table 13. The effect of CSR dimensions on labor investment efficiency.
Table 13. The effect of CSR dimensions on labor investment efficiency.
VariableAB_NET
_HIRE
OVER
_INV
UNDER
_INV
AB_NET
_HIRE
OVER
_INV
UNDER
_INV
AB_NET
_HIRE
OVER
_INV
UNDER
_INV
AB_NET
_HIRE
OVER
_INV
UNDER
_INV
AB_NET
_HIRE
OVER
_INV
UNDER
_INV
(1)(2)(3)(4)(5)(6)(7)(8)(9)(10)(11)(12)(13)(14)(15)
CSR_SH
−0.020 ***−0.026−0.012 ***
(−2.88)(−1.24)(−2.84)
CSR_LAB −0.017 **−0.034−0.012 ***
(−2.18)(−1.34)(−2.80)
CSR_SUPCUS −0.017 ***−0.055 ***−0.003
(−3.22)(−2.97)(−1.16)
CSR_ENV −0.019 ***−0.054 ***−0.005 **
(−3.92)(−3.41)(−2.10)
CSR_SOC −0.0100.004−0.010 **
(−1.28)(0.18)(−2.08)
Control VariablesYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Year Fixed EffectYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Industry Fixed EffectYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYESYES
Adj. R20.0850.1190.1560.0850.1190.1560.0850.1200.1550.0850.1210.1560.0850.1190.156
N15,998541010,58815,998541010,58815,998541010,58815,998541010,58815,998541010,588
Notes: *** and ** indicate significance at the 0.01and 0.05 levels, respectively (two-tailed). Standard errors are clustered at the firm level.
Disclaimer/Publisher’s Note: The statements, opinions and data contained in all publications are solely those of the individual author(s) and contributor(s) and not of MDPI and/or the editor(s). MDPI and/or the editor(s) disclaim responsibility for any injury to people or property resulting from any ideas, methods, instructions or products referred to in the content.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Yuan, Z.; Yu, J.; Yin, Y. The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. Sustainability 2024, 16, 4290. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16104290

AMA Style

Yuan Z, Yu J, Yin Y. The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. Sustainability. 2024; 16(10):4290. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16104290

Chicago/Turabian Style

Yuan, Zhizhu, Junze Yu, and Yue Yin. 2024. "The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China" Sustainability 16, no. 10: 4290. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16104290

APA Style

Yuan, Z., Yu, J., & Yin, Y. (2024). The Impact of Corporate Social Responsibility on Labor Investment Efficiency: Evidence from China. Sustainability, 16(10), 4290. https://doi.org/10.3390/su16104290

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop