A Dynamic Programming Model for Operation Decision-Making in Bicycle Sharing Systems under a Sustainable Development Perspective
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Literature Review
3. Model Description
3.1. The State Transition Equation of the User Trips
- (i)
- The system scale. With the expansion of the system scale, it will be able to meet the travel needs of users. Only when the system is of a certain scale can local people appreciate the convenience of using bicycles. The system scale effect is described on the user trips as (, means the power of in stage ). Since the establishment of the station always starts in densely populated areas, with an increase in the number of stations, the population density around the new station becomes smaller, so it takes .
- (ii)
- The system service. As the user’s satisfaction determines the choice of their travel behavior, the service level from a BSS operator can directly affect the user’s satisfaction. Therefore, if a high level of service can create a convenient and comfortable experience for the user, then the user trips will increase, and vice versa (The system service effect is described on the user trips as . Based on the authors’ experiences, it is assumed that user trips will significantly rise with an increase in the service level when the service level is below a specific value, while the user trips do not apparently increase with an increase in the service level when the service level is above a specific value. Thus, we define [35]).
- (iii)
- The natural increase. With the development of the BSS and an increase in people’s environmental protection consciousness level, user trips will grow to a certain degree (The natural increase effect is described on the user trips as ).
3.2. The Incentive and Punishment Mechanism Models
3.2.1. The Incentive and Punishment Mechanism Models of the Government
- (i)
- Investment expansion station. As an investor of a BSS, the government should aim to maximize their overall interests, and to formulate reasonable and feasible investment strategies for the station expansion. With continuous expansion of the BSS scale, user trips will also be enhanced.
- (ii)
- Subsidy policies. To support the continued operation of a BSS, the government has to provide a basic operating subsidy based on the number of stations. The subsidy policy is to develop a subsidy strategy that decreases year by year. This strategy could stimulate the operator actively to explore new ways to increase revenue and reduce government spending. The expression of the basic subsidy strategy is defined as follows:To ensure the sustainability of the BSS, depreciation funds must be withdrawn to support the upgrade of bicycles. The government has to pay depreciation funds at the early stage of construction, and the expression of the depreciation subsidy is defined as follows:In Equation (3), represents the depreciation expense of bicycles. represents the government will provide all depreciation expenses during the stage of construction, and will reduce the depreciation subsidy after the construction period. Moreover, the government could adjust the subsidy ratio by deciding the value of .
- (ii)
- Reward and punishment strategy. Since service level has a significant effect on the user trips; it is recommended that the government formulate the strategy of reward and punishment for the operator’s service level. The expression of the reward and punishment strategy is defined as follows:In Equation (4), we find that the intensity of punishment is greater than reward. This method assists in constraining the operator to maintain service quality at a stable level.
3.2.2. The Incentive and Punishment Mechanism Model of the Operator
- (i)
- Incentivizing the advertising contractor to actively cooperate and protect the advertising contractor’s profit level is one of the most effective measures. Thus, the following constraint is added to ensure that the advertising contractor’s profit margin is greater than the retained profit margin which is formulated by the operator:Since advertising effectiveness is related to the effort levels of the advertising contractor, the operator should encourage them to enhance their effort levels. Therefore, the retained profit margin that is formulated by the operator is set to relate to the effort level positively, as shown below:The operator can adjust the incentive strength by adjusting the value of .
- (ii)
- Translating the user trips into carbon trading income. Since traveling with bicycles does not yield any carbon, the BSS can reduce carbon emissions from the traffic area. Therefore, the operator could put the carbon emissions into the carbon market, and translate the environmental benefits into economic benefits. In order to calculate the carbon trading income, a new formula is proposed to determine it and is shown as follows:represents the transaction ratio, and is dependent on market saturation and the acceptance of carbon trading. In addition, although it failed at successful trading, the rest of the carbon emission reduction is also beneficial to society. Therefore, the benefits of the rest (the formula is shown in Equation (18)) will be included in the social benefits.
3.3. The Profit Functions of Stakeholders
3.3.1. The Profit Function of the Advertising Contractor
3.3.2. The Profit Function of the Operator
3.3.3. The Profit Function of the Government
4. Model Formulation
4.1. The Advertising Contractor Determines the Optimal Effort Level
4.2. The Operator Determines the Advertising Revenue Allocation Proportion
4.3. The Operator Determines the Service Quantity Level
4.4. The Government Determines Optimal Decisions
- (i)
- Decision variables:
- (ii)
- State variables:
- (iii)
- State-transition function:
- (iv)
- Objective function:
5. Algorithmic Enhancements
- (i)
- Determine the initial value, the search scope, and step length of decision variables.
- (ii)
- Solve the optimal value of decision variables: fix all the values of the decision variables, except the one waiting to be solved; find the optimal value for each discrete point of this decision variable in the search range (each discrete point can determine an optimal investment decision-making time series, which is solved by depth-first search algorithm); and select the discrete point that can maximize the objective function to replace the initial/last value.
- (iii)
- Repeat Step (ii) to solve the optimal value of other decision variables, until every decision variable has found the optimal value.
- (iv)
- Repeat Steps (ii) and (iii), until the optimal value of all decision variables remains unchanged.
- (i)
- Divide into groups. The optional set of decision variables will be significantly reduced through grouping, for example, every 100 stations are divided into a group, so the station variables inserted into the calculation will from 1300 to13 groups. Thus, the rough optimal solution can be obtained quickly by the depth-first algorithm. (The grouping mechanism: group is the extent to which a possible solution set is composed of distinguishable pieces. In the calculation, first, the group is composed of coarse-grained distinguishable pieces. Then, in the next stage, the group is composed of finer distinguishable pieces. In this article, we let a refined group shrink fivefold over the group in the previous stage. In this part, we suggest that interested readers investigate the definition of “granularity” [39] to deepen understanding).
- (ii)
- Subdivide. Further subdivided within a small range near the rough optimal solution obtained in Step (i) (for example, the rough optimal solution result is 800, the small range near it is 100, so the value range in the next stage is 700–900. Then, every 100/5 stations are subdivided into a group, there are 10 groups now). The optimal solution can also be obtained quickly after refinement.
- (iii)
- Repeat the second step. Subdivide the result again until it cannot be subdivided (for example, the number of stations in the group divided by five is smaller than 1), the final optimal solution is obtained.
6. Numerical Experiments
7. Conclusions and Discussion
- (i)
- The BSS has the potential to achieve break-even, or even obtain a substantial income, when it implements suitable mechanisms and operational strategies, and the region in which it is located has a relatively high GDP.
- (ii)
- The proposed models were shown to be feasible and superior, which can provide guidance for operational decisions in a BSS or any other similar system.
- (iii)
- The best investment strategy in a BSS was to invest in stations, in the initial period of construction, as much as possible, and then reduce the investment year by year. Additionally, BSSs in economically developed areas have lower optimal operating subsidies than do economically underdeveloped areas, but the optimal intensity of rewards and punishments is higher in the former than in the latter.
Supplementary Files
Supplementary File 1Acknowledgments
Author Contributions
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Notation | Definition |
---|---|
The fixed operating subsidy for the operator | |
The unit construction cost of the bicycle station | |
The random variable | |
The cost of advertising in unit bicycle station by the advertising contractor | |
The basic operating cost of the operator | |
The operating cost of unit bicycle station | |
The carbon trading income of the operator in stage | |
The sum of subsidies by the government given to the operator in stage | |
The benefit of carbon emission reduction, energy-conserving, exhaust gas treatment, health and transport capacity substitution in stage , respectively | |
The total accumulated assets of a BSS obtained by the government | |
The cost coefficient of financial expenditure of the government | |
The sum of the investment amount to build bicycle stations from the government | |
The amount of new bicycle stations which are built during the operation period | |
The amount of the bicycle stations at the beginning of the operation period | |
The average distance of trip riding time by the public bicycle | |
The average consumption of gasoline by vehicles | |
The amount of carbon dioxide emission reduction of saving one liter of gasoline | |
The unit price of carbon trading | |
The bicycle replacement rate for bus, taxi, car and motorcycle, respectively | |
The conversion coefficient of bus, taxi, car and motorcycle converted to vehicle, respectively | |
The transaction ratio of carbon emission reduction from a BSS | |
The average price of one liter of gasoline | |
The exhaust gas of burning one liter of gasoline | |
The cost of pollution treatment of | |
The average travel times of users during one day | |
The proportion of regular exercise group relative to lack of exercise group in reducing medical expense | |
The average medical expense per person per year | |
The regression coefficient of | |
Year | |
The unit cost of buying a bus and a taxi, respectively | |
The depreciation life of a bus and a taxi, respectively | |
The average passenger capacity of bus and taxi in one trip, respectively | |
The average times of a bus departuring and a taxi carrying passengers in one day | |
The transforming volume of the bicycle to the bus and the taxi in one year, respectively | |
The average usage counter of the bicycle in a BSS in one year |
Parameter | Value | Remark | Parameter | Value | Remark |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Parameters | Coefficients | ||||
¥ 10–20 ten thousand/thousand people | Assumption | 0.9 | Expert | ||
¥1 ten thousand | Assumption | 0.75 | Expert | ||
¥300 ten thousand | Expert | 10 | Assumption | ||
¥0.75 ten thousand | Expert | 1.5% | Expert | ||
¥35,000 ten thousand | Assumption | 10% | Assumption | ||
¥250,000 ten thousand | Assumption | 2 | Expert | ||
¥30 ten thousand | [43] | 7% | Assumption | ||
¥30 ten thousand | [43] | 7% | [44] | ||
¥0.5 ten thousand/station | [43] | 1 | Expert | ||
¥10 ten thousand | [43] | 0.33 | Expert | ||
¥2.5 ten thousand/station | [43] | 1 | Expert | ||
1300 stations | [41] | 1 | Expert | ||
2411 stations | [41] | 25% | Expert | ||
3.5 km | [43] | 0.052 | [45] | ||
9 L/100 km | [43] | 0.068 | [45] | ||
2.3 km/L | Expert | 0.238 | [45] | ||
¥35/ton | [46] | 0.027 | [45] | ||
¥6/L | Assumption | 1 | Assumption | ||
11.82 km/L | Expert | 1 | Assumption | ||
¥0.25 ten thousand/ton | Expert | 0.05555556 | Assumption | ||
3/day | [41] | 0.3 | Assumption | ||
¥60 ten thousand | Assumption | 0.15 | Assumption | ||
¥15 ten thousand | Assumption | 0.4 | Expert | ||
10 years | Assumption | 284.53 | Expert | ||
10 years | Assumption | 570,426 | Expert | ||
30 people | Assumption | ||||
2 people | Assumption | ||||
10 times/day | Assumption | ||||
30 times/day | Assumption |
Appendix B
References
- DeMaio, P. Bike-sharing: History, impacts, models of provision, and future. J. Public Transp. 2009, 12, 3. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shaheen, S.; Guzman, S.; Zhang, H. Bikesharing in Europe, the Americas, and Asia: Past, present, and future. Transp. Res. Rec. J. Transp. Res. Board 2010, 2143, 159–167. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, L.; Zhang, J.; Duan, Z.Y.; Bryde, D. Sustainable bike-sharing systems: Characteristics and commonalities across cases in urban China. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 97, 124–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wikipedia. List of Bicycle-Sharing Systems. Available online: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/List of_bicycle-sharing_systems#Cities (accessed on 24 May 2017).
- Xinhua Net. Wuhan: Government Invested 300 Million Yuan in Public Sharing System but It Failed with Four Year, Why? Available online: http://news.xinhuanet.com/politics/2014-04/13/c_1110219296.htm (accessed on 25 May 2017).
- Midgley, P. Bicycle-Sharing Schemes: Enhancing Sustainable Mobility in Urban Areas; United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs: New York, NY, USA, 2011; pp. 1–12. [Google Scholar]
- Benchimol, M.; Benchimol, P.; Chappert, B.; De La Taille, A.; Laroche, F.; Meunier, F.; Robinet, L. Balancing the stations of a self service “bike hire” system. RAIRO Oper. Res. 2011, 45, 37–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Forma, I.; Raviv, T.; Tzur, M. The static repositioning problem in a bike-sharing system. In Proceedings of the 7th Triennial Symposium on Transportation Analysis (TRISTAN), Tromsø, Norway, 20–25 June 2010; Volume 6, pp. 279–282. [Google Scholar]
- Raviv, T.; Tzur, M.; Forma, I.A. Static repositioning in a bike-sharing system: Models and solution approaches. EURO J. Transp. Logist. 2013, 2, 187–229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ho, S.C.; Szeto, W.Y. Solving a static repositioning problem in bike-sharing systems using iterated tabu search. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2014, 69, 180–198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dell’Amico, M.; Hadjicostantinou, E.; Iori, M.; Novellani, S. The bike sharing rebalancing problem: Mathematical formulations and benchmark instances. Omega 2014, 45, 7–19. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Erdoğan, G.; Battarra, M.; Calvo, R.W. An exact algorithm for the static rebalancing problem arising in bicycle sharing systems. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2015, 245, 667–679. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Di Gaspero, L.; Rendl, A.; Urli, T. Balancing bike sharing systems with constraint programming. Constraints 2016, 21, 318–348. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rainer-Harbach, M.; Papazek, P.; Raidl, G.R.; Hu, B.; Kloimüllner, C. PILOT, GRASP, and VNS approaches for the static balancing of bicycle sharing systems. J. Glob. Optim. 2015, 63, 597–629. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Szeto, W.Y.; Liu, Y.; Ho, S.C. Chemical reaction optimization for solving a static bike repositioning problem. Transp. Res. Part D 2016, 47, 104–135. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ho, S.C.; Szeto, W.Y. A hybrid large neighborhood search for the static multi-vehicle bike-repositioning problem. Transp. Res. Part B 2017, 95, 340–363. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, Y.F.; Szeto, W.Y.; Long, J.C.; Shui, C.S. A multiple type bike repositioning problem. Transp. Res. Part B 2016, 90, 263–278. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kloimüllner, C.; Raidl, G.R. Full-load route planning for balancing bike sharing systems by logic-based benders decomposition. Networks 2017, 69, 270–289. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shu, J.; Chou, M.C.; Liu, Q.; Teo, C.P.; Wang, I.L. Models for effective deployment and redistribution of bicycles within public bicycle-sharing systems. Oper. Res. 2013, 61, 1346–1359. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Li, L.; Shan, M. Bidirectional incentive model for bicycle redistribution of a bicycle sharing system during rush hour. Sustainability 2016, 8, 1299. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Shaheen, S.A.; Martin, E.W.; Cohen, A.P.; Chan, N.D.; Pogodzinsk, M. Public Bikesharing in North America during a Period of Rapid Expansion: Understanding Business Models, Industry Trends & User Impacts; Mineta Transportation Institute: San Jose, CA, USA, 2014; pp. 12–29. [Google Scholar]
- Ricci, M. Bike sharing: A review of evidence on impacts and processes of implementation and operation. Res. Transp. Bus. Manag. 2015, 15, 28–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nakamura, H.; Abe, N. Evaluation of the hybrid model of public bicycle-sharing operation and private bicycle parking management. Transp. Policy. 2014, 35, 31–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhang, X. Critical success factors for public–private partnerships in infrastructure development. J. Constr. Eng. Manag. 2005, 131, 3–14. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chen, L.T. Dynamic supply chain coordination under consignment and vendor-managed inventory in retailer-centric B2B electronic markets. Ind. Mark. Manag. 2013, 42, 518–531. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pongsiri, N. Regulation and public-private partnerships. Int. J. Public Sect. Manag. 2002, 15, 487–495. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ho, T.H.; Su, X.; Wu, Y. Distributional and peer-induced fairness in supply chain contract design. Prod. Oper. Manag. 2014, 23, 161–175. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Xu, G.; Dan, B.; Zhang, X.; Liu, C. Coordinating a dual-channel supply chain with risk-averse under a two-way revenue sharing contract. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2014, 147, 171–179. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cachon, G.P.; Lariviere, M.A. Supply chain coordination with revenue-sharing contracts: Strengths and limitations. Manag. Sci. 2005, 51, 30–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Giannoccaro, I.; Pontrandolfo, P. Supply chain coordination by revenue sharing contracts. Int. J. Prod. Econ. 2004, 89, 131–139. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kouvelis, P.; Zhao, W. Supply chain contract design under financial constraints and bankruptcy costs. Manag. Sci. 2015, 62, 2341–2357. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhu, Q.; Lujia, F.; Mayyas, A.; Omar, M.A.; Al-Hammadi, Y.; Al Saleh, S. Production energy optimization using low dynamic programming, a decision support tool for sustainable manufacturing. J. Clean. Prod. 2015, 105, 178–183. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yu, S.; Gao, S. A dynamic programming model for environmental investment decision-making in coal mining. Appl. Energy 2016, 166, 273–281. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Chai, J.; Liu, J.N.; Ngai, E.W. Application of decision-making techniques in supplier selection: A systematic review of literature. Exp. Syst. Appl. 2013, 40, 3872–3885. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jonsson, P.; Eklundh, L. Seasonality extraction by function fitting to time-series of satellite sensor data. IEEE Trans. Geosci. Remote Sens. 2002, 40, 1824–1832. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kong, W.; Zhao, X.; Hu, S.; Vecchiato, G.; Babiloni, F. Electronic evaluation for video commercials by impression index. Cogn. Neurodyn. 2013, 7, 531–535. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Farris, P.; Bendle, N.; Pfeifer, P.; Reibstein, D. Marketing Metrics: The Manager’s Guide to Measuring Marketing Performance; FT Press: Upper Saddle River, NJ, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Tenbrink, T.; Winter, S. Variable granularity in route directions. Spat. Cogn. Comput. 2009, 9, 64–93. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wikipedia. Granularity. Available online: https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Granularity (accessed on 24 May 2017).
- Surging News (Shanghai). The “Survival Report” of Bike Sharing: What Is the Future Development of Hangzhou BSS? Available online: http://news.163.com/17/0331/10/CGRNTHK4000187VE.html (accessed on 24 May 2017).
- Why Could the Bicycle Sharing System in Hangzhou Succeed? A New Line of the Urban Institute. Available online: https://zhuanlan.zhihu.com/p/21716193 (accessed on 24 May 2017).
- Hangzhou Daily. 675 Million User Trips in 8 Years, How Could Hangzhou Public Bicycle to Draw Attention of the World. Available online: http://zjnews.zjol.com.cn/zjnews/hznews/201608/t20160808_1832367.shtml? open_source=weibo_search (accessed on 24 May 2017).
- Chao, X. The Research on Cost-Effectiveness of a Bicycle Sharing System. Master’s Thesis, Chang’an University, Xi’an, China, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- China Economic Net. Data Presentation: The General Survey of the GDP and Growth Rate in China, 1980–2014. Available online: http://intl.ce.cn/specials/zxxx/201501/20/t20150120_4389486.shtml (accessed on 24 May 2017).
- Tianjun, F. The Effect Analysis on Public Bicycle Traffic System. Ph.D. Thesis, Jilin University, Changchun, China, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Hangzhou Daily. Hangzhou Bicycle Sharing System Participate in the Carbon Emissions Trading for the First Time. Available online: http://hznews.hangzhou.com.cn/chengshi/content/2013-05/04/content_4721591.htm (accessed on 25 May 2017).
Nomenclature | |
---|---|
Sets | |
Set of time stages, indexed by | |
Set of the optimal number of building bicycle stations in stage | |
State Variables | |
The user trips of the BSS in stage | |
The remaining amount of bicycle stations that need the BSS to build in stage | |
Decision Variables | |
The construction cycle of a BSS | |
The retention proportionality coefficient of the depreciation subsidy formulated by the government | |
The critical value of service level evaluation index of the operator formulated by the government | |
The strength adjustment coefficient of the reward and punishment subsidy formulated by the government in stage | |
The unit subsidy proportion of operation and maintenance formulated by the government | |
The incentive strength of the effort degree of the advertising contractor formulated by the operator | |
Parameters | |
The decay coefficient of population density | |
The growth rate of the bicycle station | |
The number of the bicycle station in the BSS in stage | |
The service level evaluation index of the operator in stage | |
The influence coefficient of service level on the growth of the user trips | |
The maximum value of | |
The adjustment coefficient of service level | |
The natural growth rate of the user trips | |
The depreciation rate of the public bicycle | |
The utility coefficient of reward and punishment of the operator’s service level | |
The remained profit margin of the advertising contractor formulated by the operator, according to the effort degree of the advertising contractor | |
The remained profit margin of the advertising contractor decided by itself | |
The actual profit of the advertising contractor in stage | |
The advertising revenue of the advertising contractor in stage | |
The effort degree of the advertising contractor for operating the advertising business of the BSS in stage | |
The inherent income of advertisement in the BSS in stage | |
The coefficient of GDP growth | |
The impression index | |
The constant term of the impression index | |
The actual revenue of advertisement in the BSS in stage | |
The influence coefficient of the advertising random factor | |
The efficiency conversion coefficient of the effort degree of the advertising contractor | |
The advertising revenue distribution coefficient formulated by the operator in stage | |
The effort cost coefficient of the advertising contractor | |
The cost coefficient of the operator’s service level | |
The risk utility coefficient of the advertising contractor | |
The variance of the advertising random factor | |
The profit of the advertising contractor, the operator and the government in stage , respectively | |
The maximum amount of investment by the government in the BSS in a single stage | |
The maximum amount of investment by the government in the BSS during the entire operational period |
(10 Terms) | (10 Terms) | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
10 | 5 | 0 | 0.8 | 3.6 | 1.7 | 1.6 | 24.94829 | 22.11933 | 414-366-328-92-0-0-0-0-0-0 |
12 | 5 | 0.2 | 0.8 | 3.9 | 1.5 | 1.6 | 23.88662 | 23.97634 | 432-382-342-44-0-0-0-0-0-0 |
15 | 5 | 0.6 | 0.8 | 4.6 | 1.3 | 1.6 | 22.37334 | 26.74762 | 450-396-354-0-0-0-0-0-0-0 |
18 | 5 | 0.8 | 0.9 | 5 | 1.1 | 1.6 | 19.68258 | 29.59224 | 500-446-254-0-0-0-0-0-0-0 |
© 2017 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Li, L.; Shan, M.; Li, Y.; Liang, S. A Dynamic Programming Model for Operation Decision-Making in Bicycle Sharing Systems under a Sustainable Development Perspective. Sustainability 2017, 9, 895. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9060895
Li L, Shan M, Li Y, Liang S. A Dynamic Programming Model for Operation Decision-Making in Bicycle Sharing Systems under a Sustainable Development Perspective. Sustainability. 2017; 9(6):895. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9060895
Chicago/Turabian StyleLi, Linfeng, Miyuan Shan, Ying Li, and Sheng Liang. 2017. "A Dynamic Programming Model for Operation Decision-Making in Bicycle Sharing Systems under a Sustainable Development Perspective" Sustainability 9, no. 6: 895. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9060895
APA StyleLi, L., Shan, M., Li, Y., & Liang, S. (2017). A Dynamic Programming Model for Operation Decision-Making in Bicycle Sharing Systems under a Sustainable Development Perspective. Sustainability, 9(6), 895. https://doi.org/10.3390/su9060895