Determinants of Equilibrium Selection in Network Formation: An Experiment
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Model
- for all and and
- for all then .
3. Setup of the Experiment
3.1. Experimental Game
3.2. Multiple Equilibria
3.3. Factors Influencing the Network Formation Process
- The need for players’ farsightedness to reach the equilibrium
- The perceived riskiness of equilibria
3.4. Influences on Equilibrium Selection without Network Disruption
3.5. The Effect of Network Disruption on Equilibrium Selection
4. Hypotheses
5. Experimental Procedures
6. Results
6.1. Description of Subject and Group Variables
6.2. Equilibrium Selection across Treatments
- it has not been in any other equilibrium in the course of the game, and
- only one link is missing to reach the equilibrium and
- this link has not been suggested since reaching the quasi-equilibrium network.
6.3. The Effect of Network Disruption
The Effect of a Network Disruptor on Farsighted Behavior and Perceived Risk
7. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- Bala, V.; Goyal, S. A Noncooperative Model of Network Formation. Econometrica 2000, 68, 1181–1229. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jackson, M.O.; Wolinsky, A. A Strategic Model of Social and Economic Networks. J. Econ. Theory 1996, 71, 44–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Goeree, J.; Riedl, A.; Ule, A. In search of stars: Network formation among heterogeneous agents. Games Econ. Behav. 2009, 67, 445–466. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Callander, S.; Plott, C.R. Principles of network development and evolution: An experimental study. J. Public Econ. 2005, 89, 1469–1495. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Falk, A.; Kosfeld, M. It’s all about connections: Evidence on network formation. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2012, 11. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kosfeld, M. Economic networks in the laboratory: A survey. Rev. Netw. Econ. 2004, 3, 2. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Deck, C.; Johnson, C. Link bidding in laboratory networks. Rev. Econ. Des. 2004, 8, 359–372. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kirchsteiger, G.; Mantovani, M.; Mauleon, A.; Vannetelbosch, V. Limited farsightedness in network formation. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2016, 128, 97–120. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Morbitzer, D.; Buskens, V.; Rauhut, H.; Rosenkranz, S. Limited Farsightedness in Network Formation—An Experiment. Analyse und Kritik 2014, 36, 103–133. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carrillo, J.; Gaduh, A. The Strategic Formation of Networks: Experimental Evidence; CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP8757; CEPR: London, UK, 2012. [Google Scholar]
- Hoyer, B.; De Jaegher, K. Cooperation and the Common Enemy Effect; Discussion Paper Series; Tjalling, C., Ed.; Koopmans Research Institute: Utrecht, The Netherlands, 2012; Volume 12. [Google Scholar]
- Hoyer, B.; De Jaegher, K. Strategic Network Disruption and Defense. J. Public Econ. Theory 2016, 18, 802–830. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Dziubiński, M.; Goyal, S. Network Design and Defence. Games Econ. Behav. 2013, 79, 30–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Dziubiński, M.; Goyal, S. How do you defend a network? Theor. Econ. 2017, 12, 331–376. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Goyal, S.; Vigier, A. Attack, Defence, and Contagion in Networks. Rev. Econ. Stud. 2014, 81, 1518–1542. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Haller, H. Network Vulnerability: A Designer-Disruptor Game; Working Paper Series e07-50; Virginia Polytech Institute and State University, Department of Economics: Blacksburg, VA, USA, 2016. [Google Scholar]
- Haller, H.; Hoyer, B. Note on the Common Enemy Effect under Strategic Network Formation and Disruption; Working Papers e07-49; Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Department of Economics: Blacksburg, VA, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Mir Djawadi, B.; Endres, A.; Hoyer, B.; Recker, S. Network Formation and Disruption—An Experiment: Are Efficient Networks too Complex? SSRN Working Paper Series; Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei (FEEM): Milan, Italy, 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Ziegelmeyer, A.; Pantz, K. Collaborative Networks in Experimental Triopolies; WP Series; Friedrich-Schiller-University Jena & Max Planck Institute of Economics: Jena, Germany, 2008. [Google Scholar]
- Jackson, M.; Watts, A. The evolution of social and economic networks. J. Econ. Theory 2002, 106, 265–295. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tercieux, O.; Vannetelbosch, V. A characterization of stochastically stable networks. Int. J. Game Theory 2006, 34, 351–369. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Frederick, S. Cognitive reflection and decision making. J. Econ. Perspect. 2005, 19, 25–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fischbacher, U. z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp. Econ. 2007, 10, 171–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Greiner, B. An Online Recruitment System for Economic Experiments; MPRA: Munich, Germany, 2004. [Google Scholar]
- Keynes, J. The General Theory of Interest, Employment and Money; Macmillan: London, UK, 1936. [Google Scholar]
- Nagel, R. Unraveling in guessing games: An experimental study. Am. Econ. Rev. 1995, 85, 1313–1326. [Google Scholar]
- Holt, C.; Laury, S. Risk aversion and incentive effects. Am. Econ. Rev. 2002, 92, 1644–1655. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arad, A.; Rubinstein, A. The 11–20 Money Request Game: A Level-k Reasoning Study. Am. Econ. Rev. 2012, 102, 3561–3573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Watts, D.J.; Strogatz, S.H. Collective dynamics of ‘small-world’ networks. Nature 1998, 393, 440–442. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Eshel, I.; Samuelson, L.; Shaked, A. Altruists, egoists, and hooligans in a local interaction model. Am. Econ. Rev. 1998, 88, 157–179. [Google Scholar]
- Suri, S.; Watts, D.J. Cooperation and contagion in web-based, networked public goods experiments. PLoS ONE 2011, 6, e16836. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Rand, D.G.; Arbesman, S.; Christakis, N.A. Dynamic social networks promote cooperation in experiments with humans. Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci. USA 2011, 108, 19193–19198. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
1. | Although field research seems more natural, given the abundance of networks in the real world, it is notoriously hard to investigate network formation in the field. This is due to many possibly confounding factors such as imperfect knowledge of the existing network structure, the sheer size of most networks, agents’ motivation, as well as possible asymmetries in information, payoff or costs. In laboratory experiments, these factors can be controlled for, and other concepts relevant to network formation models can be influenced in a systematic way, such as linking costs and the value of links to players themselves and to others. |
2. | The theoretical models on network formation under the threat of disruption can be classified into two categories: centralized and decentralized models. In centralized models, such as Dziubiński and Goyal [13], Dziubiński and Goyal [14], Goyal and Vigier [15], Hoyer and De Jaegher [12] or Haller [16], a network designer forms the network, anticipating a subsequent attack. In decentralized models, such as Hoyer and De Jaegher [11] or Haller and Hoyer [17], the nodes are individual players that build the network. |
3. | See Hoyer and De Jaegher [11] for a more detailed description of the model with a strategic network disruptor. |
4. | Note that calculates the expected benefits of a player, as those may be stochastic if network disruption targets several links with equal probability. We take the expected benefits to calculate the payoffs to player i, as he/she has to decide on links before he/she knows which links will be disrupted. |
5. | In the complete network, there are 6 links to connect the 4 nodes. |
6. | We added to the values and multiplied them with 30. |
7. | Thereby, we took into account that we, of course, inherently changed the game without network disruption in such a way that it is no longer equivalent to the basic network formation model introduced by Jackson and Wolinsky [2]. This can also be seen in the possible stable networks. Whereas in the model introduced in Jackson and Wolinsky [2], only the empty network is pairwise stable, in our treatment with the adjusted payoffs, we have the same stable networks as in the case with network disruption: the empty network, the separated network and the circle network. |
8. | An end-player is any player connected by degree one. |
9. | Strictly speaking, the separated network is a set of four equilibria with isomorphic structures. |
10. | In the following analysis, we focus on the circle and the empty network, as these two equilibrium networks can be reached using the same amount of linking decisions independently of the starting network. The separated network can be reached with less linking decisions when the starting network is the line than when it is the dyads. As in the experiment, it was reached in only very few cases, we will focus our analysis on the circle and the empty network. |
11. | An improving path is a sequence of networks that can emerge when players can form or sever links based on the increase in payoff they will receive in the emerging network as compared to the current one. In such a sequence, each network differs from its predecessor by exactly one link. Whether links are added or severed is determined by the conditions of pairwise stability. |
12. | For a short discussion on the lack of analysis of cognitive abilities in standard economic theory, see Frederick [22]. |
13. | It is easy to see that when network disruption is introduced to the game, nothing changes in the robustness of the equilibria. It remains that while the empty network is robust against errors, the circle network is not. |
14. | Unlike for the case of farsightedness, we do not have a revealed measure of risk. We can control for the general risk attitude of subjects, using the Holt and Laury measure, but we do not find a revealed measure for risk in the network formation game. Therefore, we focus on the outcome of the game as our variable of interest. |
15. | The instructions used during the experiment are available upon request. |
16. | |
17. | As is done in Holt and Laury [27], we simply use the number of safe choices that subjects take to categorize them on the individual level in this table, ignoring any inconsistencies in choices. In total, we observe 10 inconsistent choices, which we take into account for the median values per group, as used in the further analysis. Subjects with inconsistent choices were treated as though there were missing data on their risk attitude for this purpose. |
18. | Conducting the analysis without including the three groups does not change the results qualitatively, however. |
19. | While the test statistic is reported, also a Fisher’s exact test is performed to correct for the fact that some of our cells included only less than five observations. The test statistic, however, remained insignificant. The same holds for every other test statistic in this paper. If there are cells with less than five observations, we always also performed a Fisher’s exact test. We will only specifically report the results if they differ between the two tests. |
20. | We consider relative frequencies here instead of absolute frequencies to control for the different number of groups we had per setting. |
21. | The result on the separated equilibrium can easily be explained. The separated equilibrium is reached by adding one link when starting from the line network and adding this link is a myopic best response. As opposed to this, it is highly unlikely to reach the separated equilibrium when starting from the dyads. |
22. | For the correlation analysis, we dropped all the ambiguous and irrational decisions. |
23. | This observation is inline with observations stated in Arad and Rubinstein [28]. |
24. | We performed a Fisher’s exact test instead of a test, as we had two cells with less than five entries. |
25. | Again, here, we also view the groups that are in quasi-equilibrium as groups that coordinate on an equilibrium network. |
26. | The separated network is reached only in a very small minority of the cases. |
Variable | Mean | Std. Dev. | Min. | Max. | N |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Male | 0.473 | 0.499 | 0 | 1 | 148 |
Age | 23.243 | 3.860 | 17 | 42 | 148 |
Student | 0.824 | 0.381 | 0 | 1 | 148 |
Dutch | 0.568 | 0.495 | 0 | 1 | 148 |
Economics | 0.331 | 0.471 | 0 | 1 | 148 |
No. of Decisions total | 11.420 | 4.408 | 2 | 22 | 148 |
No. of Decisions R1 | 5.122 | 3.388 | 0 | 14 | 148 |
No. of Decisions R2 | 6.297 | 3.193 | 1 | 14 | 148 |
No. of Decisions ND | 5.311 | 3.19 | 0 | 14 | 148 |
No. of Decisions D | 6.108 | 3.447 | 0 | 14 | 148 |
Stop R1 | 10.243 | 6.156 | 1 | 20 | 148 |
Stop R2 | 12.595 | 5.74 | 2 | 20 | 148 |
Individual | Median per Group | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Number of Steps | Frequency | Percent | Frequency | Percent |
0 | 20 | 13.51 | 0 | 0 |
1 | 33 | 22.30 | 15 | 20.27 |
2 | 34 | 22.97 | 36 | 48.65 |
3 | 23 | 15.54 | 14 | 18.92 |
4 | 15 | 10.14 | 8 | 10.81 |
5 | 10 | 6.76 | 1 | 1.35 |
6 | 13 | 8.78 | 0 | 0 |
Total | 148 | 100 | 74 | 100 |
Individual | Median per Group | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Risk Classification | Frequency | Percent | Frequency | Percent |
highly risk loving | 2 | 1.35 | 0 | 0 |
very risk loving | 0 | 0 | 0 | 0 |
risk loving | 2 | 1.35 | 0 | 0 |
risk neutral | 23 | 15.54 | 2 | 2.70 |
slightly risk averse | 20 | 13.51 | 6 | 8.11 |
risk averse | 40 | 27.03 | 35 | 47.30 |
very risk averse | 35 | 23.65 | 23 | 31.08 |
highly risk averse | 13 | 8.78 | 8 | 10.81 |
very highly risk averse | 13 | 8.78 | 0 | 0 |
Total | 148 | 100 | 74 | 100 |
Frequency | Percent | |
---|---|---|
In Equilibrium | 65 | 87.84 |
Not in Equilibrium | 9 | 12.16 |
Total | 74 | 100 |
Setting | Equilibrium | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Starting Network | Order | Frequency | Percent | |
line | ND-D | 17 | 94.44 | |
line | D-ND | 13 | 81.25 | |
dyads | ND-D | 19 | 95.00 | |
dyads | D-ND | 19 | 95.00 | |
Total | 68 | 91.89 |
Final Network | Starting Network Line | Starting Network Dyads | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Frequency | Percent | Frequency | Percent | ||
Empty | 17 | 56.67 | 19 | 50.00 | 0.0460 |
Circle | 8 | 26.67 | 19 | 50.00 | 4.5569 ** |
Separated | 5 | 16.66 | 0 | 0 | 6.3086 *** |
Total | 30 | 100 | 38 | 100.00 | *** |
Equilibrium | Frequency | Percent |
---|---|---|
Empty | 36 | 48.65 |
Circle | 27 | 36.48 |
Separated | 5 | 6.76 |
None | 6 | 8.11 |
Total | 74 | 100 |
Disruption | No Disruption | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Frequency | Percent | Frequency | Percent | Total | |
Myopic | 25 | 34.72 | 17 | 22.37 | 42 |
Farsighted | 32 | 44.44 | 39 | 51.32 | 71 |
Ambiguous | 13 | 18.06 | 20 | 26.32 | 33 |
Irrational | 2 | 2.78 | 0 | 0 | 2 |
Total | 72 | 100.00 | 76 | 100 |
Beauty | First Dec | Revealed | |
---|---|---|---|
Beauty | 1.0000 | ||
First Dec | 0.1191 | 1.0000 | |
Revealed | 0.0496 | 0.7848 *** | 1.0000 |
Circle | Separated | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Coeff. | RRR | Coeff. | RRR | |
Median of Revealed Farsighted Players Per Group | 1.909 ** | 6.743 | −2.827 | 0.059 |
(0.897) | (2.131) | |||
Disruption | −1.488 ** | 0.226 | −3.599 ** | 0.027 |
(0.702) | (1.857) | |||
Median Risk Lovingness per Group | −0.055 | 0.946 | 0.338 | 1.402 |
(0.354) | (0.981) | |||
Round 1 | −0.925 | 0.397 | 0.882 | 2.415 |
(0.639) | (1.645) | |||
Average No. of Females per Group | −0.503 | 1.654 | −1.230 | 0.292 |
(1.099) | (2.354) | |||
Average No. of Economics Students per Group | −1.717 | 0.179 | −3.508 | 0.029 |
(1.429) | (3.507) | |||
0 Players Who Know Game Theory | 0.099 | 1.104 | 1.976 | 7.214 |
(1.881) | (3.259) | |||
1 Player Who Knows Game Theory | −0.838 | 0.433 | −0.264 | 0.768 |
(1.572) | (2.384) | |||
2 Players Who Know Game Theory | 0.874 | 2.396 | 16.730 | 1.84 × 10 |
(1.389) | (1.793) | |||
3 Players Who Know Game Theory | 1.717 | 5.567 | 15.856 | 7.690 |
(1.383) | (1.793) | |||
Constant | −0.825 | - | −15.191 | - |
(2.149) | (1.793) | |||
Observations | 67 | 67 |
Disruption | No Disruption | |||
---|---|---|---|---|
Frequency | Percent | Frequency | Percent | |
In Equilibrium | 32 | 86.50 | 36 | 97.30 |
Not in Equilibrium | 5 | 13.50 | 1 | 2.70 |
Total | 37 | 100 | 37 | 100 |
No Disruption | Disruption | ||
---|---|---|---|
Circle | 17 | 10 | |
Empty | 15 | 21 | |
Total | 32 | 31 | * |
© 2018 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Hoyer, B.; Rosenkranz, S. Determinants of Equilibrium Selection in Network Formation: An Experiment. Games 2018, 9, 89. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040089
Hoyer B, Rosenkranz S. Determinants of Equilibrium Selection in Network Formation: An Experiment. Games. 2018; 9(4):89. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040089
Chicago/Turabian StyleHoyer, Britta, and Stephanie Rosenkranz. 2018. "Determinants of Equilibrium Selection in Network Formation: An Experiment" Games 9, no. 4: 89. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040089
APA StyleHoyer, B., & Rosenkranz, S. (2018). Determinants of Equilibrium Selection in Network Formation: An Experiment. Games, 9(4), 89. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040089