From Social Information to Social Norms: Evidence from Two Experiments on Donation Behaviour
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Experimental Procedures and Design
2.1. Decision Task and Treatments: Experiment 1
“In previous sessions of this experiment, 50 participants on average gave €7 (HIGH) / €1 (LOW) to retire CO-permits”
2.2. Decision Task and Treatments: Experiment 2
2.3. Procedures
3. Hypotheses
3.1. The Effect of Social Information on Behaviour
3.2. Mechanisms by Which Social Information Affects Behaviour
4. Results
4.1. Social Information Matters
4.2. Mechanism
4.2.1. Changing Norm Perception
4.2.2. There Is No Anchoring Confound
4.2.3. Social Information Effects at the Individual Level (Experiment 2)
5. Discussion and Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A. Procedure
Appendix A.1. General Instructions
Check-in | Check-in room: |
Sign-in and generation of personal code | |
Experiment | Laboratory: |
Random seat assignment | |
General instructions read out loud (page 17) | |
Tasks implemented in z-Tree | |
• Contribution to climate change mitigation (page 18) | |
• Belief elicitation (page 20) | |
• Questionnaires on demographics and attitudes | |
Payment receipt distributed according to personal code | |
Payment | Check-in room: |
Subjects exchange payment receipt for cash |
Appendix A.1.1. Real Contribution Task
- Please insert into the blue field how much money you would like to use to retire CO2 permits and thus reduce global CO2 emissions.
- You are free to indicate every integer between 0 and 10 Euro, i.e., you may fill in whole numbers without decimal place (period or comma).
- Each Euro you are not using to purchase CO2 permits, you can take home at the end in cash.
Appendix A.1.2. Instructions Estimates
Appendix A.1.3. Instructions Experiment 2: Procedures
Appendix A.1.4. Instructions Experiment 2: Social Information
Appendix A.1.5. Instructions Experiment 2: Revision
Appendix A.1.6. Additional Tables and Results
Baseline | High | Low | Number | Pooled | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
N = 144 | N = 47 | N = 47 | N = 36 | N = 274 | |
Age (Years) | 48.79 | 44.60 | 46.53 | 50.03 | 47.85 |
Female (%) | 62.94% | 46.81% | 48.94% | 55.56% | 56.78% |
Education (Years) | 14.15 | 13.81 | 14.39 | 14.11 | 14.12 |
Monthly Net Income (€) | 1232.80 | 1404.65 | 1748.39 | 1818.97 | 1409.87 |
Assets (%) | 38.89% | 29.79% | 40.43% | 44.44% | 38.32% |
Household Size | 2.11 | 1.79 | 1.89 | 2.06 | 2.02 |
Number of Children | 0.92 | 0.85 | 0.79 | 0.88 | 0.88 |
Climate Change Attitude | 5.72 | 5.77 | 5.86 | 5.49 | 5.72 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | |
---|---|---|---|
Dependent Variable | Contributions | Contributions | Contributions |
High (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 17.47 *** | 17.34 *** | 18.27 *** |
(5.521) | (6.079) | (5.489) | |
Low (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | −1.367 | −7.014 | −2.479 |
(5.901) | (6.875) | (6.439) | |
Number (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 2.726 | 4.514 | 4.152 |
(6.924) | (7.375) | (6.720) | |
Age (Years) | 0.481 *** | 0.633 *** | 0.519 *** |
(0.118) | (0.170) | (0.156) | |
Female (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 11.34 *** | 7.438 | 7.553 * |
(4.241) | (4.846) | (4.538) | |
Education (Years) | 0.570 | 0.632 | |
(0.723) | (0.677) | ||
Monthly Net Income (€) | −0.00157 | ||
(0.00265) | |||
Household Size | 4.179 ** | 4.446 ** | |
(1.984) | (1.929) | ||
Number of Children | −0.886 | −0.776 | |
(2.547) | (2.395) | ||
Climate Change Attitude (1−7) | 6.116 *** | 6.501 *** | |
(1.699) | (1.604) | ||
Assets (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 2.200 | ||
(5.006) | |||
Constant | 0.242 | −52.73 *** | −54.70 *** |
(6.645) | (15.54) | (14.64) | |
N | 273 | 226 | 257 |
R2 | 0.098 | 0.174 | 0.171 |
Prob> F | <0.01 | <0.01 | <0.01 |
References
- Cialdini, R.B.; Reno, R.R.; Kallgren, C.A. A focus theory of normative conduct: Recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 1990, 58, 1015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- López Pérez, R. Aversion to norm-breaking: A model. Games Econ. Behav. 2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bicchieri, C.; Xiao, E. Do the right thing: But only if others do so. J. Behav. Decis. Mak. 2009, 22, 191–208. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Krupka, E.; Weber, R.A. The focusing and informational effects of norms on pro-social behaviour. J. Econ. Psychol. 2009, 30, 307–320. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Krupka, E.L.; Weber, R.A. Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary? J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2013, 11, 495–524. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Gächter, S.; Nosenzo, D.; Sefton, M. Peer effects in pro-social behaviour: Social norms or social preferences? J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2013, 11, 548–573. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Bicchieri, C. The Grammar of Society: The Nature and Dynamics of Social Norms; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 2005. [Google Scholar]
- Shang, J.; Croson, R. A field experiment in charitable contribution: The impact of social information on the voluntary provision of public goods. Econ. J. 2009, 119, 1422–1439. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Frey, B.S.; Meier, S. Social Comparisons and Pro-social Behavior: Testing “Conditional Cooperation” in a Field Experiment. Am. Econ. Rev. 2004, 94, 171–1722. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Alpizar, F.; Carlsson, F.; Johansson-Stenman, O. Anonymity, reciprocity, and conformity: Evidence from voluntary contributions to a national park in Costa Rica. J. Public Econ. 2008, 92, 1047–1060. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Allcott, H. Social norms and energy conservation. J. Public Econ. 2011, 95, 1082–1095. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Margetts, H.; John, P.; Escher, T.; Reissfelder, S. Social information and political participation on the internet: An experiment. Eur. Political Sci. Rev. 2011, 3, 321–344. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Robert, I.; Arnab, M. Is dishonesty contagious? Econ. Inq. 2013, 51, 722–734. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Beshears, J.; Choi, J.J.; Laibson, D.; Madrian, B.C.; Milkman, K.L. The effect of providing peer information on retirement savings decisions. J. Financ. 2015, 70, 1161–1201. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Coffman, L.C.; Featherstone, C.R.; Kessler, J.B. Can social information affect what job you choose and keep? Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 2017, 9, 96–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bernheim, B.D. A theory of conformity. J. Political Econ. 1994, 102, 841–877. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bénabou, R.; Tirole, J. Incentives and prosocial behaviour. Am. Econ. Rev. 2006, 96, 1652–1678. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grossman, Z. Self-signaling and social-signaling in giving. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 2015, 117, 26–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Croson, R.; Handy, F.; Shang, J. Keeping up with the Joneses: The relationship of perceived descriptive social norms, social information, and charitable giving. Nonprofit Manag. Leadersh. 2009, 19, 467–489. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Eckel, C.C.; Grossman, P.J. Rebate versus matching: does how we subsidize charitable contributions matter? J. Public Econ. 2003, 87, 681–701. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Keser, C.; Van Winden, F. Conditional cooperation and voluntary contributions to public goods. Scand. J. Econ. 2000, 102, 23–39. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fischbacher, U.; Gächter, S.; Fehr, E. Are people conditionally cooperative? Evidence from a public goods experiment. Econ. Lett. 2001, 71, 397–404. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Chaudhuri, A. Sustaining cooperation in laboratory public goods experiments: a selective survey of the literature. Exp. Econ. 2011, 14, 47–83. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Harrison, G.W.; List, J.A. Field experiments. J. Econ. Lit. 2004, 42, 1009–1055. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smith, A. Estimating the causal effect of beliefs on contributions in repeated public good games. Exp. Econ. 2013, 16, 414–425. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Costa-Gomes, M.A.; Huck, S.; Weizsäcker, G. Beliefs and actions in the trust game: Creating instrumental variables to estimate the causal effect. Games Econ. Behav. 2014, 88, 298–309. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cason, T.N.; Mui, V.L. Social influence in the sequential dictator game. J. Math. Psychol. 1998, 42, 248–265. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Diederich, J.; Goeschl, T. To mitigate or not to mitigate: The price elasticity of pro-environmental behaviour. J. Environ. Econ. Manag. 2017, 84, 209–222. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Löschel, A.; Sturm, B.; Vogt, C. The demand for climate protection—Empirical evidence from Germany. Econ. Lett. 2012, 118, 415–418. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Goldstein, N.J.; Cialdini, R.B.; Griskevicius, V. A room with a viewpoint: Using social norms to motivate environmental conservation in hotels. J. Consum. Res. 2008, 35, 472–482. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ortmann, A.; Hertwig, R. The costs of deception: Evidence from psychology. Exp. Econ. 2002, 5, 111–131. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Colson, G.; Corrigan, J.R.; Grebitus, C.; Loureiro, M.L.; Rousu, M.C. Which deceptive practices, if any, should be allowed in experimental economics research? Results from surveys of applied experimental economists and students. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 2015, 98, 610–621. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Elster, J. Social norms and economic theory. J. Econ. Perspect. 1989, 3, 99–117. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fischbacher, U. z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. Exp. Econ. 2007, 10, 171–178. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Goeschl, T.; Kettner, S.E.; Lohse, J.; Schwieren, C. What Do We Learn from Public Good Games about Voluntary Climate Action? Evidence from an Artefactual Field Experiment; AWI Working Paper Series; SSRN: Rochester, NY, USA, 2015. [Google Scholar]
- Greiner, B. The Online Recruitment System Orsee 2.0—A Guide for The Organization of Experiments in Economics; Working Paper Series; University of Cologne: Köln, Germany, 2004; Volume 10. [Google Scholar]
- Roberts, R.D. A positive model of private charity and public transfers. J. Political Econ. 1984, 92, 136–148. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Andreoni, J. Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. Econ. J. 1990, 100, 464–477. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jones, S.R. The Economics of Conformism; Blackwell: Oxford, UK, 1984. [Google Scholar]
- Croson, R.; Shang, J.Y. The impact of downward social information on contribution decisions. Exp. Econ. 2008, 11, 221–233. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ariely, D.; Loewenstein, G.; Prelec, D. “Coherent arbitrariness”: Stable demand curves without stable preferences. Q. J. Econ. 2003, 118, 73–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Diederich, J.; Goeschl, T. Willingness to pay for voluntary climate action and its determinants: Field-experimental evidence. Environ. Resour. Econ. 2013, 57, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Carpenter, J.; Connolly, C.; Myers, C.K. Altruistic behaviour in a representative dictator experiment. Exp. Econ. 2008, 11, 282–298. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baron, R.M.; Kenny, D.A. The moderator–mediator variable distinction in social psychological research: Conceptual, strategic, and statistical considerations. J. Personal. Soc. Psychol. 1986, 51, 1173–1182. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sobel, M.E. Asymptotic confidence intervals for indirect effects in structural equation models. Sociol. Methodol. 1982, 13, 290–312. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- de Oliveira, A.C.; Spraggon, J.M.; Denny, M.J. Instrumenting beliefs in threshold public goods. PLoS ONE 2016, 11, e0147043. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Croson, R.; Gneezy, U. Gender differences in preferences. J. Econ. Lit. 2009, 47, 448–474. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Croson, R.; Handy, F.; Shang, J. Gendered giving: The influence of social norms on the donation behaviour of men and women. Int. J. Nonprofit Volunt. Sect. Mark. 2010, 15, 199–213. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Barnett, A.G.; Van Der Pols, J.C.; Dobson, A.J. Regression to the mean: what it is and how to deal with it. Int. J. Epidemiol. 2004, 34, 215–220. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Yu, R.; Chen, L. The need to control for regression to the mean in social psychology studies. Front. Psychol. 2015, 5, 1574. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed] [Green Version]
- Kimbrough, E.O.; Vostroknutov, A. Norms make preferences social. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2016, 14, 608–638. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Smith, S.; Windmeijer, F.; Wright, E. Peer effects in charitable giving: Evidence from the (running) field. Econ. J. 2014, 125, 1053–1071. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nyborg, K.; Anderies, J.M.; Dannenberg, A.; Lindahl, T.; Schill, C.; Schlüter, M.; Adger, W.N.; Arrow, K.J.; Barrett, S.; Carpenter, S.; et al. Social norms as solutions. Science 2016, 354, 42–43. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Farrow, K.; Grolleau, G.; Ibanez, L. Social norms and pro-environmental behaviour: A review of the evidence. Ecol. Econ. 2017, 140, 1–13. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Allcott, H.; Rogers, T. The short-run and long-run effects of behavioural interventions: Experimental evidence from energy conservation. Am. Econ. Rev. 2014, 104, 3003–3037. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cialdini, R.B.; Demaine, L.J.; Sagarin, B.J.; Barrett, D.W.; Rhoads, K.; Winter, P.L. Managing social norms for persuasive impact. Soc. Influ. 2006, 1, 3–15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Costa, D.L.; Kahn, M.E. Energy conservation “nudges” and environmentalist ideology: Evidence from a randomized residential electricity field experiment. J. Eur. Econ. Assoc. 2013, 11, 680–702. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- List, J.A. Young, Selfish and Male: Field evidence of social preferences. Econ. J. 2004, 114, 121–149. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
1. | |
2. | Bicchieri and Xiao [3] compared a selfish norm to a norm that suggests an equal split. We compare a norm suggesting a low donation amount and a norm suggesting a high donation amount to a situation where no social information is provided. |
3. | There are other common experimental task formats in which reciprocity is a more plausible explanation as to why subjects react to social information. For instance, in standard repeated public good experiments, a significant fraction of subjects is known to react to social information; they increase their contributions upon observing high contributions made by other group members and decrease their contributions upon observing low contributions (see, e.g., Keser and Van Winden [21], Fischbacher et al. [22] or Chaudhuri [23]). This form of conditional cooperation could be interpreted as either expressing preferences for conformity or as direct reciprocity (i.e., reciprocating the observed kindness of others). In a standard public goods game, subjects benefit immediately and directly from the contributions made by other group members. Thus, there is a large scope for reciprocity to materialize. In our experimental task, in contrast, the marginal benefit of a donation to another subject is close to zero and, due to the slow reactivity of the climate system, only materializes with significant delay. This greatly limits the room for direct reciprocity compared to the standard public goods game setting. |
4. | As in Diederich and Goeschl [28] and Löschel et al. [29], their decision was implemented by retiring CO-permits via the EU Emissions Trading System. Before subjects made any decision, they were given some basic information on the exact procedures via a brief text that informed them about greenhouse gas emissions, the functioning of the offset scheme and the amount of CO that could be reduced by €1. We also explained to participants that a certificate of total emission reductions issued by the emission-trading-agency would be posted at a public notice board of the university where the study was conducted at the end of the study period, to allow them to verify the total (but not the individual) amount of money donated to carbon reductions. |
5. | This obviously does not rule out the possibility that some subjects might still misunderstand the factually correct information we provide in that way, just as some subjects in Bicchieri and Xiao [3] might wrongly believe that the session data they are shown come from a representative session. Our method, thus, clearly avoids actively misleading subjects in any way; a clear form of deception. We leave it to our readers to decide whether the scope for such misunderstanding is sufficiently small to still conform to the commonly shared norm of avoiding deception in experimental economics or rather falls into a grey area. We refer the interested reader to Ortmann and Hertwig [31] and Colson et al. [32] for a more general discussion of deception and the different views that exist within the discipline as to what such grey area might encompass. |
6. | As in the other treatments, this information is based on the actual place of residence of baseline participants. |
7. | In a few, early baseline sessions, belief elicitation was not incentivized. To increase the reliability of estimates we added an incentive mechanism in later baseline sessions, as well as all social information sessions. |
8. | The procedure, as well as a translation of the z-Tree instructions are provided in the Appendix. |
9. | Total earnings and duration for Experiment 1 encompass a second task (public goods game) that we analyse in a separate paper [35] and that took place subsequent to any decisions analysed in this paper. |
10. | Our core results continue to hold when controlling for the demographic attributes contained in Table A2. As self-reported income might not capture the wealth status of an individual, we further report participants’ assets as a binary variable indicating whether participants own a house or an apartment. With respect to reported assets, there exists no significant difference between the four treatments. |
11. | Overall, these baseline results fall into a range comparable to that observed in Diederich and Goeschl [42] and Löschel et al. [29], who looked at contributions to the same public good. As these studies vary the price of giving, there is only limited comparability to our setting. Carpenter et al. [43] used a similar elicitation method, but allowed participants to give to a charity of their own choosing. In their setting, donations reach 68 percent of the initial endowment. |
12. | One reason for a weaker effect of the LOW social information treatment, which is in line with the results we discuss in more detail below, could be that the information provided differs less from the expectations that subjects hold regarding the giving of others in BASE. |
13. | The Sobel–Goldman test is a test for the statistical significance of a mediation effect. It goes back to Sobel [45] and tests if the relationship between the independent variable and the dependent variable is affected in a significant way by the inclusion of the mediating variable. |
14. | This mirrors the results of the non-parametric analysis. Furthermore, a large F-statistic () indicates that instruments generated by random treatment assignment are not weak. |
15. | Testing for endogeneity formally via conducting a Hausman test indicates also that an endogeneity problem is not likely (). |
16. | Non-parametric tests similarly show that giving in HIGH vs. BASE differs significantly for females (Mann–Whitney test, ), but not for males (Mann–Whitney test, ). |
17. | Comparing treatment effect between sexes individually reveals at most a weak difference (male-high vs. female-high, , ; male-low vs. female-low, , ). Similarly, testing treatment differences in average beliefs separately for females and males results in significant effects when comparing high/low social information to the baseline. Hence, both males and females adapt their beliefs under social information to a similar extent. |
18. | |
19. | We are grateful to an anonymous referee for alerting us to this possibility in an earlier draft. For instance, subjects with a high initial donation are more likely to observe another subject donating less. Any change induced through the observed information will thus go in the same direction as a change resulting from a regression towards the mean. For this reason, we do not analyse the strength of change, where such concerns would be exacerbated [27]. |
20. | Tobit regressions that control for potential censoring of the outcome variable arrive at the same conclusions and are available from the authors upon request. |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
1st Stage | 2nd Stage | |||
Dependent Variable | Contributions | Contributions | Beliefs | Contributions |
High (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 13.50 ** | 2.736 | 13.78 *** | |
(6.093) | (5.824) | (3.104) | ||
Low (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | −4.164 | 6.514 | −13.67 *** | |
(5.865) | (5.891) | (3.439) | ||
Beliefs | 0.781 *** | 0.644 *** | ||
(0.129) | (0.244) | |||
Constant | 30.97 *** | 1.682 | 37.50 *** | 8.644 |
(2.889) | (4.417) | (1.643) | (9.452) | |
N | 238 | 238 | 238 | 238 |
R2 | 0.029 | 0.213 | 0.164 | 0.203 |
Prob > F / 2 | <0.01 | <0.01 | <0.01 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
1st Stage | 2nd Stage | |||
Dependent Variable | Contributions | Contributions | Beliefs | Contributions |
High (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 2.408 | −0.299 | 8.921 * | |
(7.853) | (8.170) | (4.639) | ||
Low (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | −3.042 | −7.573 | −16.18 *** | |
(8.763) | (10.30) | (5.369) | ||
Number (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 5.083 | −4.517 | ||
(11.48) | (11.00) | |||
Female (0 = No, 1 = Yes) | 6.430 | −1.961 | −2.013 | −24.37 |
(5.997) | (6.530) | (3.363) | (19.24) | |
Female*High | 26.19 ** | 35.29 *** | 9.867 | |
(11.47) | (11.29) | (6.124) | ||
Female*Low | −0.180 | −0.980 | 4.730 | |
(11.87) | (13.62) | (6.913) | ||
Female*Number | −3.805 | 16.53 | ||
(14.64) | (14.66) | |||
Beliefs | 0.212 | |||
(0.359) | ||||
Beliefs*Female | 0.923 * | |||
(0.494) | ||||
Constant | 26.79 *** | −51.40 *** | 38.68 *** | 18.81 |
(4.705) | (15.45) | (2.579) | (14.01) | |
Demographic Controls | No | Yes | ||
N | 273 | 226 | 237 | 237 |
R2 | 0.065 | 0.211 | 0.173 | 0.187 |
Prob > F | 0.011 | <0.01 | <0.01 | <0.01 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Dependent Variable | Donation Final | Donation Final | Donation Final | Donation Final |
Observed Donation of Others | 0.192 | 0.172 | 0.225 * | 0.432 |
(0.151) | (0.106) | (0.110) | (0.368) | |
Initial Donation (Demeaned) | 0.481 **** | 0.743 ** | 0.242 | |
(0.0897) | (0.318) | (0.225) | ||
Constant | 1.116 **** | 1.150 **** | 1.317 *** | 1.572 **** |
(0.296) | (0.226) | (0.425) | (0.316) | |
N | 45 | 45 | 28 | 17 |
0.04 | 0.59 | 0.23 | 0.51 | |
Prob > F | 0.21 | <0.01 | 0.03 | <0.01 |
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Change | Change | Change | Change | |
1 = Yes | 1 = Yes | 1 = Yes | 1 = Yes | |
Absolute (Observed-Initial) | 0.319 *** | 0.197 * | ||
(0.122) | (0.109) | |||
Initial Donation (Demeaned) | 0.228 ** | |||
(0.0974) | ||||
Absolute (Observed-Belief) | 0.142 | 0.0910 | ||
(0.118) | (0.121) | |||
Initial Belief (Demeaned) | 0.306 ** | |||
(0.150) | ||||
Constant | −1.029 *** | −0.735 ** | −0.544 * | −0.480 * |
(0.331) | (0.322) | (0.282) | (0.290) | |
Observations | 45 | 45 | 45 | 45 |
© 2018 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Goeschl, T.; Kettner, S.E.; Lohse, J.; Schwieren, C. From Social Information to Social Norms: Evidence from Two Experiments on Donation Behaviour. Games 2018, 9, 91. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040091
Goeschl T, Kettner SE, Lohse J, Schwieren C. From Social Information to Social Norms: Evidence from Two Experiments on Donation Behaviour. Games. 2018; 9(4):91. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040091
Chicago/Turabian StyleGoeschl, Timo, Sara Elisa Kettner, Johannes Lohse, and Christiane Schwieren. 2018. "From Social Information to Social Norms: Evidence from Two Experiments on Donation Behaviour" Games 9, no. 4: 91. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040091
APA StyleGoeschl, T., Kettner, S. E., Lohse, J., & Schwieren, C. (2018). From Social Information to Social Norms: Evidence from Two Experiments on Donation Behaviour. Games, 9(4), 91. https://doi.org/10.3390/g9040091