How Significant Are the Roles Moral Obligation and Formal Institutions Play in Participatory Irrigation Management?
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Research Hypothesis
2.1. Moral Obligation and Collective Action of Irrigation Management
2.2. Formal Institution and Collective Action of Irrigation Management
2.3. Relationship between Moral Obligation and Formal Institution
2.4. Collective Actions and Participatory Irrigation Management (PIM) Performance
3. Theoretical Analysis Framework
3.1. The Institutional Analysis and Development (IAD) Framework
3.2. Econometric Model
4. Data and Variables
4.1. Data Collection
4.2. Sample Description
4.3. Variables
5. Results and Discussion
5.1. Reliability and Validity Analysis
5.1.1. Reliability Analysis
5.1.2. Convergent Validity Analysis
5.1.3. Discriminant Validity Analysis
5.2. Overall Structural Equation Modelling (SEM) Analysis
5.2.1. Model Fit
5.2.2. Hypothesis Testing
5.3. Multi-Group Analysis
5.3.1. Reasons for Multi-Group Analysis
5.3.2. Multi-Group Test
5.4. Limitations and Implications for Future Research
6. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
Appendix A
Village Features | Value | Household Features | Value |
---|---|---|---|
Key construction project of small-scale irrigation facilities | Age of household head | ||
Involved | 13 | Age ≤ 30 | 39 |
Not involved | 37 | 30 < Age ≤ 40 | 96 |
Project of agricultural demonstration base | 40 < Age ≤ 50 | 128 | |
Involved | 11 | 50 < Age ≤ 60 | 312 |
Not involved | 39 | Age > 60 | 137 |
Village population size | Education level | ||
Size ≤ 1000 | 10 | Primary school or below | 305 |
1000 < Size ≤ 1500 | 13 | Junior high school | 335 |
1500 < Size ≤ 2000 | 11 | Senior high school or technical secondary school | 47 |
2000 < Size≤ 2500 | 9 | Junior college | 16 |
Size > 2500 | 7 | Bachelor’s degree or above | 9 |
Village cultivated land area | Household cultivated land area | ||
Area ≤ 2000 Mu | 12 | Area ≤ 5 Mu | 126 |
2000 Mu < Area ≤ 4000 Mu | 14 | 5 Mu < Area ≤ 10 Mu | 168 |
4000 Mu < Area ≤ 6000 Mu | 15 | 10 Mu < Area ≤ 15 Mu | 267 |
6000 Mu < Area ≤ 8000 Mu | 6 | 15 Mu < Area ≤ 20 Mu | 101 |
Area > 8000 Mu | 3 | Area > 20 Mu | 50 |
Village canal length | Number of family members | ||
Length ≤ 5 Km | 8 | Number ≤ 2 | 98 |
5 < Length ≤ 10 Km | 13 | 2 < Number ≤ 4 | 219 |
10 < Length ≤15 Km | 15 | 4 < Number ≤ 6 | 235 |
15 < Length ≤20 Km | 9 | 6 < Number ≤ 8 | 102 |
Length > 20 Km | 5 | Number > 8 | 58 |
Village canal type | Family members’ village cadre experience | ||
Earthen canal account for more than 50% | 27 | Exist | 83 |
Concrete-lined canal account for more than 50% | 23 | None | 629 |
References
- Yellow River Water Resources Bulletin. Available online: http://www.yrcc.gov.cn/other/hhgb/ (accessed on 10 September 2022).
- 2020 Statistic Bulletin on China Water Activities. Available online: http://www.mwr.gov.cn/sj/tjgb/slfztjgb/202202/t20220209_1561588.html (accessed on 10 September 2022).
- Yang, L.; Ren, Y.; Tang, Z.; Zhu, Y. Impact of institutional constraints on participatory irrigation management: The regulating role of moral obligation. Irrig. Drain. 2021, 70, 1287–1297. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Zang, L.; Araral, E. The impacts of land fragmentation on irrigation collective action: Empirical test of the social-ecological system framework in China. J. Rural Stud. 2020, 78, 234–244. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Poddar, R.; Qureshi, M.E.; Syme, G. Comparing irrigation management reforms in Australia and India—A special reference to participatory irrigation management. Irrig. Drain. 2011, 60, 139–150. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rao, F.; Abudikeranmu, A.; Shi, X.; Heerink, N.; Ma, X. Impact of participatory irrigation management on mulched drip irrigation technology adoption in rural Xinjiang, China. Water Resour. Econ. 2021, 33, 100170. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Lam, W.F.; Ostrom, E. Analyzing the dynamic complexity of development interventions: Lessons from an irrigation experiment in Nepal. Policy Sci. 2010, 43, 1–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yang, L.; Rezitis, A.; Zhu, Y.; Ren, Y. Investigating the effects of social trust and perceived organizational support on irrigation management performance in rural China. Water 2018, 10, 1252. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Su, Y.; Araral, E.; Wang, Y. The effects of farmland use rights trading and labor outmigration on the governance of the irrigation commons: Evidence from China. Land Use Policy 2020, 91, 104378. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nenadovic, M.; Epstein, G. The relationship of social capital and fishers’ participation in multi-level governance arrangements. Environ. Sci. Policy 2016, 61, 77–86. [Google Scholar]
- Ido, A. The effect of social capital on collective action in community forest management in Cambodia. Int. J. Commons 2019, 13, 777–803. [Google Scholar]
- Castillo, G.; Engler, A.; Wollni, M. Planned behavior and social capital: Understanding farmers’ behavior toward pressurized irrigation technologies. Agric. Water Manag. 2021, 243, 106524. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ge, W.; Sheng, G.; Zhang, H. How to solve the social norm conflict dilemma of green consumption: The moderating effect of self-affirmation. Front. Psychol. 2020, 11, 566571. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Sabucedo, J.M.; Dono, M.; Alzate, M.; Seoane, G. The importance of protesters’ morals: Moral obligation as a key variable to understand collective action. Front. Psychol. 2018, 9, 418. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- Ricks, J.I. Building participatory organizations for common pool resource management: Water user group promotion in Indonesia. World Dev. 2016, 77, 34–47. [Google Scholar]
- Ortega-Reig, M.; Sanchis-Ibor, C.; Palau-Salvador, G.; García-Mollá, M.; Avellá-Reus, L. Institutional and management implications of drip irrigation introduction in collective irrigation systems in Spain. Agric. Water Manag. 2017, 187, 164–172. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yercan, M. Management turning-over and participatory management of irrigation schemes: A case study of the Gediz River Basin in Turkey. Agric. Water Manag. 2003, 62, 205–214. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Milesi, P.; Alberici, A.I. Pluralistic morality and collective action: The role of moral foundations. Group Process. Intergroup Relat. 2018, 21, 235–256. [Google Scholar]
- Pellowe, K.E.; Leslie, H.M. The interplay between formal and informal institutions and the potential for co-management in a Mexican small-scale fishery. Mar. Policy 2020, 121, 104179. [Google Scholar]
- Ellen, O. Drink Water, but Remember the Source: Moral Discourse in a Chinese Village; University of California Press: Berkeley, CA, USA, 2010. [Google Scholar]
- Qiao, H. The position of the rule of virtue in rural governance and its realization. Truth Seek. 2018, 444, 88–97. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Wu, L.; Xie, S. The revitalization of rural culture from the perspective of cultural governance: Value coupling and system construction. J. Huazhong Agric. Univ. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2019, 139, 16–23. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Xu, Y. Moral resources, political capital and the development of social work in China: A case study of city J in Shandong province. Br. J. Soc. Work 2013, 43, 1589–1610. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Balan, D.J.; Knack, S. The correlation between human capital and morality and its effect on economic performance: Theory and evidence. J. Comp. Econ. 2012, 40, 457–475. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Vazquez, A.; Lopez-Rodriguez, L.; Gomez, A.; Brambilla, M. Verification of ingroup morality promotes willingness to participate in collective action for immigrants’ rights. Group Process. Intergroup Relat. 2020, 25, 174–192. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Agostini, M.; van Zomeren, M. Toward a comprehensive and potentially cross-cultural model of why people engage in collective action: A quantitative research synthesis of four motivations and structural constraints. Psychol. Bull. 2021, 147, 667–700. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
- van Zomeren, M. Toward a cultural psychology of collective action: Just how “core” are the core motivations for collective action? J. Pac. Rim Psychol. 2019, 13, e15. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Wu, J.; Font, X.; Liu, J. Tourists’ pro-environmental behaviors: Moral obligation or disengagement? J. Travel Res. 2021, 60, 735–748. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- North, D.C. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance; Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK, 1990. [Google Scholar]
- Steer, L.; Sen, K. Formal and informal institutions in a transition economy: The case of Vietnam. World Dev. 2010, 38, 1603–1615. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Scott, W.R. Institutions and Organizations, 4th ed.; SAGE Publications: Thousand Oaks, CA, USA, 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Fan, Y.; Tang, Z.; Park, S.C. Effects of community perceptions and institutional capacity on smallholder farmers’ responses to water scarcity: Evidence from arid northwestern China. Sustainability 2019, 11, 483. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cao, Y.; Zhang, X.; He, L. Collective action in maintaining rural infrastructures: Cadre-farmer relationship, institution rules and their interaction terms. Land Use Policy 2020, 99, 105043. [Google Scholar]
- Afroz, S.; Cramb, R.; Grunbuhel, C. Collective management of water resources in coastal Bangladesh: Formal and substantive approaches. Hum. Ecol. 2016, 44, 17–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Oehmichen, J.; Wolff, M.; Zschoche, U. Employee participation in employee stock ownership plans: Cross-level interaction effects of institutions and workgroup behavior. Hum. Resour. Manag. 2018, 57, 1023–1037. [Google Scholar]
- Williamson, C.R. Informal institutions rule: Institutional arrangements and economic performance. Public Choice 2009, 139, 371–387. [Google Scholar]
- Tang, L.; Luo, X.; Yu, W. Migrant work experience, institutional constraints and farmers’ willingness to pay for environmental governance. J. Nanjing Agric. Univ. (Soc. Sci. Ed.) 2020, 21, 121–132. (In Chinese) [Google Scholar]
- Fischer, E.; Qaim, M. Smallholder farmers and collective action: What determines the intensity of participation? J. Agric. Econ. 2014, 65, 683–702. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ge, S.; He, Q.; Sarangi, S. Reaping What You Sow: Historical Rice Farming and Contemporary Cooperative Behavior in China. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3921875 (accessed on 10 September 2021). [CrossRef]
- Wang, Y.; Zhang, M.; Kang, J. How does context affect self-governance? Examining Ostrom’s design principles in China. Int. J. Commons 2019, 13, 660–704. [Google Scholar]
- Doss, C.R.; Meinzen-Dick, R. Collective action within the household: Insights from natural resource management. World Dev. 2015, 74, 171–183. [Google Scholar]
- Turner, J.R.; Simister, S.J. Project contract management and a theory of organization. Int. J. Proj. Manag. 2001, 19, 457–464. [Google Scholar]
- Kadirbeyoglu, Z.; Özertan, G. Power in the governance of common-pool resources: A comparative analysis of irrigation management decentralization in Turkey. Environ. Policy Gov. 2015, 25, 157–171. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, X.; Otto, I.M.; Yu, L. How physical and social factors affect village-level irrigation: An institutional analysis of water governance in northern China. Agric. Water Manag. 2013, 119, 10–18. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. The institutional analysis and development framework and the commons. Cornell Law Rev. 2010, 95, 807–815. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E. Background on the institutional analysis and development framework. Policy Stud. J. 2011, 39, 7–27. [Google Scholar]
- Ostrom, E.; Gardner, R.; Walker, J. Rules, Games, and Common-Pool Resources; University of Michigan Press: Ann Arbor, MI, USA, 1994. [Google Scholar]
- Clement, F. Analysing decentralised natural resource governance: Proposition for a “politicised” institutional analysis and development framework. Policy Sci. 2010, 43, 129–156. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ostrom, E. Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. Am. Econ. Rev. 2010, 100, 641–672. [Google Scholar]
- Yu, H.H.; Edmunds, M.; Lora-Wainwright, A.; Thomas, D. Governance of the irrigation commons under integrated water resources management—A comparative study in contemporary rural China. Environ. Sci. Policy 2016, 55, 65–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Fornell, C.; Larcker, D.F. Evaluating structural equation models with unobservable variables and measurement error. J. Mark. Res. 1981, 18, 39–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hasan, M.B.; Driessen, P.; Zoomers, A.; Van Laerhoven, F. How can NGOs support collective action among the users of rural drinking water systems? A case study of Managed Aquifer Recharge (MAR) systems in Bangladesh. World Dev. 2020, 126, 104710. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Miao, S.; Heijman, W.; Zhu, X.; Qiao, D.; Lu, Q. Income groups, social capital, and collective action on small-scale irrigation facilities: A multigroup analysis based on a structural equation model. Rural. Sociol. 2018, 83, 882–911. [Google Scholar]
- Calvo-Mora, A.; Navarro-García, A.; Rey-Moreno, M.; Perianez-Cristobal, R. Excellence management practices, knowledge management and key business results in large organisations and SMEs: A multi-group analysis. Eur. Manag. J. 2016, 34, 661–673. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Variable | Definition | Mean | Std. Dev | Min | Max |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
MO1 | I feel morally obliged to participate in irrigation management: 1(totally disagree) ~ 5(totally agree) | 4.500 | 0.574 | 1 | 5 |
MO2 | I feel satisfied participating in irrigation management: 1(totally disagree) ~ 5(totally agree) | 4.216 | 0.780 | 1 | 5 |
MO3 | Whatever others may think, I will participate in irrigation management: 1(totally disagree) ~ 5(totally agree) | 4.497 | 0.569 | 1 | 5 |
MO4 | I will participate in irrigation management because I believe this is a positive measure: 1(totally disagree) ~ 5(totally agree) | 4.490 | 0.578 | 1 | 5 |
FI1 | Degree of information transparency in irrigation management: 1(very opaque) ~ 5(very transparent) | 3.476 | 0.965 | 1 | 5 |
FI2 | Clarity of rights and responsibilities of management and maintenance in irrigation management: 1(not clear) ~ 5(very clear) | 3.202 | 0.943 | 1 | 5 |
FI3 | The supervision institution can effectively constrain me to participate in irrigation management: 1(totally ineffective) ~ 5(very effective) | 3.206 | 0.878 | 1 | 5 |
FI4 | I would be punished by an institution if I didn’t participate in irrigation management: 1(totally disagree) ~5(very agree) | 3.140 | 0.845 | 1 | 5 |
CA1 | Attendance frequency of your participation in meetings related to irrigation management in the village: 1 = never; 2 = once in two to three years; 3 = once a year; 4 = two or three times a year; 5 = more than three times a year | 4.049 | 0.912 | 1 | 5 |
CA2 | Maintenance frequency of your participation in irrigation management: 1 = never; 2 = once in two to three years; 3 = once a year; 4 = two or three times a year; 5 = more than three times a year | 4.178 | 0.849 | 1 | 5 |
CA3 | The sum of the total labor value and investment level of your participation in irrigation management in the previous year: 1 = not more than 100 yuan; 2 = more than 100 yuan and not more than 200 yuan; 3 = more than 200 yuan and not more than 300 yuan; 4 = more than 300 yuan and not more than 400 yuan; 5 = more than 400 yuan | 4.247 | 0.812 | 1 | 5 |
PIMP1 | Condition of irrigation canals: 1(very poor) ~ 5(very good) | 3.742 | 0.867 | 1 | 5 |
PIMP2 | The degree of the timely maintenance of irrigation facilities: 1(untimely) ~ 5(timely) | 3.402 | 0.824 | 1 | 5 |
PIMP3 | Fairness of irrigation water allocation: 1(not fair at all) ~ 5(very fair) | 3.608 | 0.868 | 1 | 5 |
PIMP4 | The number of irrigation water use disputes in the previous year: 1 = more than six times; 2 = five or six times; 3 = three or four times; 4 = once or twice; 5 = never | 3.600 | 0.829 | 1 | 5 |
CV1 | Irrigation water is or is not in shortage: 1 = yes; 0 = no | 0.560 | 0.497 | 0 | 1 |
CV2 | The natural conditions of the village are or are not harsh: 1 = yes; 0 = no | 0.184 | 0.388 | 0 | 1 |
CV3 | The distance between the plot and the nearest canal: 1(very far) ~ 5(very close) | 4.833 | 0.592 | 1 | 5 |
CV4 | The number of farmers sharing the same irrigation canal with you: 1 = ten households or less; 2 = eleven to fifteen households; 3 = sixteen to twenty households; 4 = twenty-one to twenty-five households; 5 = more than twenty-five households | 3.416 | 1.179 | 1 | 5 |
CV5 | The degree of villagers jointly solving irrigation management problems: 1(never) ~ 5(every time) | 3.913 | 0.943 | 1 | 5 |
CV6 | The support level given to you by village organizations in irrigation: 1(not supportive) ~ 5(very supportive) | 3.414 | 0.829 | 1 | 5 |
CV7 | The shortage of the agricultural labor force in your family: 1(shortage) ~ 5(abundant) | 2.173 | 1.247 | 1 | 5 |
CV8 | The shortage of capital in your family: 1(shortage) ~ 5(abundant) | 2.591 | 1.174 | 1 | 5 |
Moral Obligation | Formal Institution | Collective Action | PIM Performance | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Reliability and convergent validity | Cronbach’s alpha | 0.877 | 0.814 | 0.908 | 0.824 |
CR | 0.928 | 0.881 | 0.944 | 0.883 | |
AVE | 0.764 | 0.652 | 0.849 | 0.655 | |
Discriminant validity | Moral obligation | 0.874 | |||
Formal institution | 0.214 | 0.807 | |||
Collective action | 0.334 | 0.290 | 0.921 | ||
PIM performance | 0.334 | 0.274 | 0.526 | 0.809 |
Path | Standardized Path Coefficient | t-Value | Inference |
---|---|---|---|
H1: Moral Obligation → Collective Action | 0.352 *** | 9.298 | Supported |
H2: Formal Institution → Collective Action | 0.250 *** | 6.274 | Supported |
H3: Formal Institution → Moral Obligation | 0.220 *** | 5.236 | Supported |
H4: Collective Action → PIM Performance | 0.600 *** | 13.912 | Supported |
CV1 → PIM Performance | −0.062 | −1.729 | Not Supported |
CV2 → PIM Performance | −0.041 | −1.131 | Not Supported |
CV3 → PIM Performance | −0.018 | −0.520 | Not Supported |
CV4 → PIM Performance | −0.056 | −1.621 | Not Supported |
CV5 → PIM Performance | −0.034 | −0.933 | Not Supported |
CV6 → PIM Performance | 0.197 *** | 5.348 | Supported |
CV7 → PIM Performance | 0.030 | 0.863 | Not Supported |
CV8 → PIM Performance | −0.016 | −0.473 | Not Supported |
Path | Direct Effect | Indirect Effect | Total Effect |
---|---|---|---|
Moral Obligation → Collective Action | 0.352 | -- | 0.352 |
Formal Institution → Collective Action | 0.250 | 0.077 | 0.327 |
Formal Institution → Moral Obligation | 0.220 | -- | 0.220 |
Collective Action → PIM Performance | 0.600 | -- | 0.600 |
Moral Obligation → PIM Performance | -- | 0.211 | 0.211 |
Formal Institution → PIM Performance | -- | 0.196 | 0.196 |
Path | Agricultural Income | ||
---|---|---|---|
Low-Income Group (n = 229) | Medium-Income Group (n = 257) | High-Income Group (n = 226) | |
H1: Moral Obligation → Collective Action | 0.347 *** | 0.265 *** | 0.448 *** |
H2: Formal Institution → Collective Action | 0.322 *** | 0.219 ** | 0.191 ** |
H3: Formal Institution → Moral Obligation | 0.209 ** | 0.208** | 0.251 *** |
H4: Collective Action → PIM Performance | 0.729 *** | 0.433 *** | 0.577 *** |
Path | Province | ||
Ningxia group (n = 240) | Shanxi group (n = 235) | Shandong group (n = 237) | |
H1: Moral Obligation → Collective Action | 0.327 *** | 0.367 *** | 0.338 *** |
H2: Formal Institution → Collective Action | 0.436 *** | 0.119 | 0.194 ** |
H3: Formal Institution → Moral Obligation | 0.348 *** | 0.236 *** | 0.066 |
H4: Collective Action → PIM Performance | 0.537 *** | 0.628 *** | 0.668 *** |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Yang, L.; Rezitis, A.; Ren, Y. How Significant Are the Roles Moral Obligation and Formal Institutions Play in Participatory Irrigation Management? Agriculture 2022, 12, 1847. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture12111847
Yang L, Rezitis A, Ren Y. How Significant Are the Roles Moral Obligation and Formal Institutions Play in Participatory Irrigation Management? Agriculture. 2022; 12(11):1847. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture12111847
Chicago/Turabian StyleYang, Liu, Anthony Rezitis, and Yang Ren. 2022. "How Significant Are the Roles Moral Obligation and Formal Institutions Play in Participatory Irrigation Management?" Agriculture 12, no. 11: 1847. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture12111847
APA StyleYang, L., Rezitis, A., & Ren, Y. (2022). How Significant Are the Roles Moral Obligation and Formal Institutions Play in Participatory Irrigation Management? Agriculture, 12(11), 1847. https://doi.org/10.3390/agriculture12111847