A Review of Game Theory Applications for Seaport Cooperation and Competition
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Game Theory Approaches
2.1. Port and Container Terminal Cooperation/Competition and Co-Opetition
2.2. Port and Container Terminal Competition
2.3. Government and Container Terminal Competition
2.4. Port and Shipping Line Competition and Cooperation
2.5. Other Type of Maritime Transportation Cooperation and Competition
3. Discussion
Author Contributions
Funding
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
References
- UNCTAD. Review of Maritime Transport 2019; Publication UNCTAD/RMT/2019; United Nations Publication: New York, NY, USA; Geneva, Switzerland, 2019; p. 129. [Google Scholar]
- Why Is the Liner Shipping Industry So Important Economically? The World Shipping Council. Available online: http://www.worldshipping.org/industry-issues/environment/air-emissions/faqs-answers/a1-why-is-the-liner-shipping-industry-so-important-economically (accessed on 1 June 2019).
- Alphaliner TOP 100. Alphaliner. Available online: https://alphaliner.axsmarine.com/PublicTop100/ (accessed on 1 June 2019).
- Shipping Alliances: What Do They Do and What Does It Mean? FreightHub. Available online: https://freighthub.com/en/blog/shipping-alliances-mean/ (accessed on 1 June 2019).
- Drewry Maritime Research. Container Forecast December 2018; Drewry Financial Research Services Ltd.: London, UK, 2018; p. 87. [Google Scholar]
- Guan, C.; Yahalom, S.; Yu, J. Port congestion and economies of scale: The large container ship factor. In Proceedings of the 25th Annual Conference of the International Association of Maritime Economists, Kyoto, Japan, 27–30 June 2017. [Google Scholar]
- Anderson, C.M.; Park, Y.-A.; Chang, Y.-T.; Yang, C.-H.; Lee, T.-W.; Luo, M. A Game-Theoretic Analysis of Competition among Container Port Hubs: The Case of Busan and Shanghai 1. Marit. Policy Manag. 2008, 35, 5–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Do, T.M.H.; Park, G.-K.; Choi, K.; Kang, K.; Baik, O. Application of Game Theory and Uncertainty Theory in Port Competition between Hong Kong Port and Shenzhen Port. Int. J. E Navig. Marit. Econ. 2015, 2, 12–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Ishii, M.; Lee, P.T.-W.; Tezuka, K.; Chang, Y.-T. A Game Theoretical Analysis of Port Competition. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2013, 49, 92–106. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Luo, M.; Liu, L.; Gao, F. Post-Entry Container Port Capacity Expansion. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2012, 46, 120–138. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- De Borger, B.; Proost, S.; van Dender, K. Private Port Pricing and Public Investment in Port and Hinterland Capacity. SSRN Electron. J. 2008. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Basso, L.J.; Wan, Y.; Zhang, A. Seaport Competition and Strategic Investment in Accessibility. In Proceedings of the 16th Congreso Chileno de Ingeniería de Transport, Santiago, Chile, 21–25 October 2013. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, K.; Ng, A.K.Y.; Lam, J.S.L.; Fu, X. Cooperation or Competition? Factors and Conditions Affecting Regional Port Governance in South China. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2012, 14, 386–408. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wang, J.; Sun, S. The Game about Competition and Cooperation in Port Group. In Proceedings of the 23rd International Conference on Industrial Engineering and Engineering Management 2016, Bali, Indonesia, 4–7 December 2016; Qi, E., Shen, J., Dou, R., Eds.; Atlantis Press: Paris, France; pp. 215–219. [Google Scholar]
- Zhou, X. Competition or Cooperation: A Simulation of the Price Strategy of Ports. Int. J. Simul. Model. 2015, 14, 463–474. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cui, H.; Notteboom, T. A Game Theoretical Approach to the Effects of Port Objective Orientation and Service Differentiation on Port Authorities’ Willingness to Cooperate. Res. Transp. Bus. Manag. 2018, 26, 76–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Park, N.K.; Suh, S.C. Port Competition Study: Cooperative Game Model. J. Contemp. Manag. 2015, 4, 38–52. [Google Scholar]
- Kaselimi, E.N.; Notteboom, T.E.; de Borger, B. A Game Theoretical Approach to Competition between Multi-User Terminals: The Impact of Dedicated Terminals. Marit. Policy Manag. 2011, 38, 395–414. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nguyen, H.-O.; Chin, A.; Tongzon, J.; Bandara, M. Analysis of Strategic Pricing in the Port Sector: The Network Approach. Marit. Econ. Logist. 2015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yu, M.; Shan, J.; Ma, L. Regional Container Port Competition in a Dual Gateway-Port System. J. Syst. Sci. Syst. Eng. 2016, 25, 491–514. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Czerny, A.; Höffler, F.; Mun, S. Port Competition and Welfare Effect of Strategic Privatization. Energiewirtschaftliches Institut an der Universitaet zu Koeln (EWI). 2013. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Cui, H.; Notteboom, T. Modelling Emission Control Taxes in Port Areas and Port Privatization Levels in Port Competition and Co-Operation Sub-Games. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2017, 56, 110–128. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bae, M.J.; Chew, E.P.; Lee, L.H.; Zhang, A. Container Transshipment and Port Competition. Marit. Policy Manag. 2013, 40, 479–494. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Zhuang, W.; Luo, M.; Fu, X. A Game Theory Analysis of Port Specialization—Implications to the Chinese Port Industry. Marit. Policy Manag. 2014, 41, 268–287. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lee, H.; Boile, M.; Theofanis, S.; Choo, S. Modeling the Oligopolistic and Competitive Behavior of Carriers in Maritime Freight Transportation Networks. Procedia Soc. Behav. Sci. 2012, 54, 1080–1094. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zheng, S.; Negenborn, R.R. Centralization or Decentralization: A Comparative Analysis of Port Regulation Modes. Transp. Res. Part E Logist. Transp. Rev. 2014, 69, 21–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Ignatius, J.; Tan, T.S.; Dhamotharan, L.; Goh, M. To Cooperate or to Compete: A Game Theoretic Analysis on Ports in Malaysia and Singapore. Technol. Econ. Dev. Econ. 2018, 24, 1776–1800. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Saeed, N.; Larsen, O.I. An Application of Cooperative Game among Container Terminals of One Port. Eur. J. Oper. Res. 2010, 203, 393–403. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pujats, K.; Golias, M.M.; Mishra, S. Marine Container Terminal Cooperation: A Nash Bargaining Approach. In Proceedings of the Transportation Research Board 97th Annual Meeting, Washington, DC, USA, 7–11 January 2018. [Google Scholar]
- van Reeven. The Effect of Competition on Economic Rents in Seaports. J. Transp. Econ. Policy 2010, 44, 79–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Yip, T.L.; Liu, J.J.; Fu, X.; Feng, J. Modeling the Effects of Competition on Seaport Terminal Awarding. Transp. Policy 2014, 35, 341–349. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Wan, Y.; Zhang, A. Urban Road Congestion and Seaport Competition. J. Transp. Econ. Policy 2013, 47, 55–70. [Google Scholar]
- Song, L.; Yang, D.; Chin, A.T.H.; Zhang, G.; He, Z.; Guan, W.; Mao, B. A Game-Theoretical Approach for Modeling Competitions in a Maritime Supply Chain. Marit. Policy Manag. 2016, 43, 976–991. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Pujats, K.; Golias, M.; Mishra, S. A Mathematical Framework for Container and Liner Shipping Companies Cooperation and Competition. In Proceedings of the Material Handling, Constructions and Logistics, Bar, Montenegro, 1–2 July 2019. [Google Scholar]
- Asgari, N.; Farahani, R.Z.; Goh, M. Network Design Approach for Hub Ports-Shipping Companies Competition and Cooperation. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2013, 48, 1–18. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Tuljak-Suban, D. Competition or Cooperation in a Hub and Spoke-Shipping Network: The Case of the North Adriatic Container Terminals. Transport 2017, 33, 429–436. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Angeloudis, P.; Greco, L.; Bell, M.G.H. Strategic Maritime Container Service Design in Oligopolistic Markets. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2016, 90, 22–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Matsushima, N.; Takauchi, K. Port Privatization in an International Oligopoly. Transp. Res. Part B Methodol. 2014, 67, 382–397. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Yeo, H. Participation of Private Investors in Container Terminal Operation: Influence of Global Terminal Operators. Asian J. Shipp. Logist. 2015, 31, 363–383. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Zis, T.P.V. Prospects of Cold Ironing as an Emissions Reduction Option. Transp. Res. Part A Policy Pract. 2019, 119, 82–95. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Jia, H.; Adland, R.; Prakash, V.; Smith, T. Energy Efficiency with the Application of Virtual Arrival Policy. Transp. Res. Part D Transp. Environ. 2017, 54, 50–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Study | Technique | Methodology | Objective | Results |
---|---|---|---|---|
Wang et al., 2012 [13] | Cournot competition/ Joint profit maximization | Ports with differentiated services decide to compete or form an alliance. | Investigate the elements that have an effect on alliance formation for ports in South China with partially overlapping hinterlands. | When institutional and political factors prohibit usual business practices, the alliance will be formed only when there is a balance between increasing prices and switching some of the throughputs from high-cost ports to low-cost ones. |
Ignatius et al., 2018 [27] | Cournot competition Collusion | Transshipment ports in a proximate region decide to compete or cooperate. | Investigate whether an alliance between three leading transshipment ports situated in Malaysia (Port Klang, Port of Tanjung Pelepas) and Singapore (Port of Singapore) should be formed. | A strategic alliance between Port of Singapore and Port of Tanjung Pelepas would result in greater profit for both the current hub and spoke network. Port Klang should not engage in any cooperative strategies with any of the other ports. |
Wang and Sun, 2017 [14] | Hotelling model | Port enterprises maximize their profit at the same service level or at a different service level. | Analyze the competition and cooperation among ports based on geographical location, service level, and shipping distance. | When the service levels are the same, a cooperative strategy can significantly improve the level of the port group’s profit. |
Zhou, 2015 [15] | Hotelling model Nash equilibrium | Ports decide on setting prices under cooperation and competition conditions. | Analyze the price strategy for competition and cooperation among ports serving partially overlapping hinterland. | When the service levels are the same, the critical factor for competitive ports is location, while service levels are the critical factor for port alliance formation. |
Ciu and Notteboom, 2018 [16] | Cournot competition Bertrand competition Quantity–Price game Price–Quantity game | Two-stage game where: Port makes quantity or pricing decisions. Ports decide to cooperate or compete. | Investigate the effects of competition and cooperation on public/private Port Authorities (PA) objectives when the level of service changes with differential capacity, service price, profits, and welfare. | Under Cournot competition, an alliance will be formed only when the partial public PA will agree to transfer certain profits to the private PA. Under all other types of competitions, the highly private-oriented PA will have the highest willingness to cooperate with the private PA. |
Saeed and Larsen, 2010 [28] | Bertrand competition Bertrand–Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Terminals decide to compete or form a coalition. Terminals in coalition play cooperatively, otherwise non-cooperative Nash game | Analyze different combinations of coalitions among three container terminals situated in Karachi Port in Pakistan. | Grand coalition was found to result in the best payoff, while the terminal at a second port that did not join the coalition earned a better payoff. When discriminatory fees were considered, the overall profit of terminals in Karachi was found to be lower, while users gained most when the nondiscriminatory percentage fees were considered. |
Park and Suh et al., 2015 [17] | Bertrand competition Maximize Total Joint Profit Nash equilibrium | Terminals make pricing decisions under cooperation or competition. | Find the equilibrium price and profit between four container terminals in Busan, the Republic of Korea, in a competitive and cooperative relation. | In a situation when one container terminal will increase price, all other terminals will keep the current price, when one terminal reduces the price, all other terminals will follow. |
Pujats et al., 2018 [29] | Nash Bargaining Solution Maximize total profits Maximin profit cooperation Maximin profit increase cooperation | For the volume-based formulation, each terminal decides whether to cooperate by receiving or providing the demand. For the vessel-based formulation, each terminal decides on which vessels are served. | Evaluate and compare four different cooperation policies for sharing capacity and compare volume to vessel-based formulations. | The Nash Bargaining Solution and maximization of total profits policies outperform the maximization of minimum profit among all terminals, and maximization of minimum profit increases among all terminals when a combined uniformity of profit is shared among the cooperating terminals and size is considered. |
Study | Technique | Methodology | Objective | Results |
---|---|---|---|---|
Van Reeven, 2010 [30] | Hotelling model Cournot competition | Two-stage game where: Port authorities decide whether to integrate vertically or to separate vertically. All players simultaneously make their final choices. | Analyze the effects of service level differentiation in inter- and intraport competition, in which two ports compete for cargo transshipment. | The highest profits were achieved between vertically separated ports. Furthermore, the vertically separated Landlord Port competition results in a Nash equilibrium. A vertically integrated port organization system yields to lower profits. |
Kaselimi et al., 2011 [18] | Cournot competition Hotelling model | Two-stage game whereTerminal operators compete for quantities by taking consideration of their capacity. Terminals compete in both prices and throughput. | Examine the effects of the transition from a multiuser terminal to a fully dedicated terminal on inter- and intraport competition between the multiuser terminals. | The introduction of dedicated terminals will result in less profit to the port authorities and also to the users of multiuser terminals, while multiuser terminals were unaffected by the introduction of dedicated terminals. |
Yip et al., 2014 [31] | Cournot competition Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Ports make terminal award decisions. Terminals set port charges competing in quantity. | Examine inter- and the intraport competition on terminal concession awarding. | Terminal operators prefer to govern more terminals in the region. Port authorities with considerable market dominance prefer to introduce inter- and intraport competition. |
Zhuang et al., 2014 [24] | Stackelberg game Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: The leader port decides output volumes for both container and bulk cargo operations. The follower port decides output volumes in container and bulk cargo operations. | Investigate service differentiation for ports that manage containerized cargo and dry-bulk cargo. | Port infrastructure investments should be coordinated adequately with other port infrastructure investments and potential demand. Government intervention may be required, as it may lead to over-investment and excessive competition. Leading ports benefit from making first moves that result in greater profit and larger traffic volume. |
Ishii et al., 2013 [9] | A two-person game model with stochastic demand Nash equilibrium | Ports make pricing decisions in the time of capacity investment. | Analyze strategic port pricing in a setting of interport competition and at the time when ports make capacity investment decisions. | When both the demand elasticity and port capacity development activities are high, prices should be set low. The actual decision on setting the price made by the government was made contrary to the theory. |
Nguyen et al., 2015 [19] | Price leadership Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Ports make pricing decisions to maximize profit. Identification of network links between ports in the network and strategic interaction. | Identify the effects of strategic pricing on ports in their networks in three Australian regions, namely Queensland, South Australia and Victoria, and Western Australia. | Not all ports set prices through strategic interaction between other ports; some set prices independent of each other. Moreover, the pricing strategy of competing ports may differ from each other. |
Anderson et al., 2008 [7] | Bertrand competition | Each port makes an investment decision by increasing its capacity. | Examine port capacity investment decisions between ports of Busan, Korea, and Shanghai, China. | Investments should not be undertaken throughout East Asia. In addition, governments should be aware of any current or future competitor developments that may have a chance to gain a greater share of the market. |
Do et al., 2015 [8] | A two-person game model with uncertain demand and payoff Nash equilibrium | Ports decide to invest under consideration that demand is uncertain, or payoff is uncertain. | Examine port capacity investment decisions between ports of Hong Kong and Shenzhen. | Shenzhen was found to be the dominant port in a long-term strategy. Hong Kong should make capacity investments only when Shenzhen does. |
Luo et al., 2012 [10] | Bertrand competition Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Ports make capacity investment decisions. Ports make pricing decisions. | Examine port capacity investment decisions between ports of Hong Kong and Shenzhen, when the market demand increases and differential service levels. | Both ports would expand with the increasing market demand, although the new port with a smaller capacity will be more likely to expand owing to the lower investment costs and higher price sensitivity. |
Study | Technique | Methodology | Objective | Results |
---|---|---|---|---|
Zheng and Negenborn, 2014 [26] | Stackelberg game | Three-stage game where: Governments make capacity decisions for both private and public terminals. Governments and the private terminal operator engage in a simultaneous duopoly game. Consumers decide between the public and private terminals. | Analyze the effects of port regulation modes on optimal tariffs, capacities, and port efficiency levels for both public and private terminals. | Under the decentralization mode, the tariff, port efficiency level, port service demand, and social welfare were found to be higher. The effects of port regulation mode on port capacity and profit were inconclusive. |
Yu et al., 2016 [20] | Hotelling model Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Port governments make cargo fee decisions. Terminal operators make service quality and service price decisions. | Analyze the effects of port regulation modes on competing ports, when the government of ports makes cargo fee decisions and terminals make service quality and price decisions. | Governments prefer terminals to compete under the decentralized model. Terminals with lower service quality will gain higher profit under a centralized mode compared to the competition instance. |
Czerny et al., 2014 [21] | Hotelling model | Two-stage game where: Governments decide to privatize or not. Ports make pricing decisions. | Investigate the effects of port privatization on competition between two transshipment ports located in two different countries. | Both ports will be privatized in a setting when the transshipment market is significant. Private ports would set higher port charges, and reduction in operational costs will result in higher port charges. |
Cui and Notteboom, 2017 [22] | Cournot competition Bertrand competition Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Governments make decisions on emission control tax and whether to privatize the port. Ports make quantity/price decisions in competition or cooperation settings. | Analyze the effects of government-introduced emission tax charges on vessel and port operations in a setting of private and Landlord port competition and cooperation. | In the case of port cooperation, more rigorous environmental protection should be reinforced, compared to the port competition. In the case of port cooperation, revenue from the total emission taxes will always result in greater value than the overall damage to the environment. |
De Borger et al., 2008 [11] | Cournot type competition Bertrand competition | Two-stage game where: Governments make decisions on port capacity, hinterland capacity, and road tolls. Ports make pricing decisions. | Investigate the effects of port pricing decisions on optimal investment policies and congestion toll decisions on the hinterland network capacities between competing ports with hinterland congestion. | The capacity investment would result in reduced prices and congestion at each port, but it will increase congestion at hinterland. Hinterland investment will likely result in increased prices and congestion at the port, which at the same time will lead to reduced prices and congestion at the competing port. The introduction of congestion tolls will increase both port and capacity investments. |
Wan and Zhang, 2013 [32] | Cournot competition Cournot equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Governments make decisions on port capacity, hinterland capacity, and road tolls. Ports make pricing decisions while competing in quantity. | Investigate the effects of port pricing decisions on optimal investment policies and congestion toll (both fixed-ratio and discriminative) decisions on the hinterland network capacities between competing ports with hinterland congestion. | An increase in port hinterland road capacity or tolls may lead to increased ports profits, while at the same time, by tolling above the marginal external congestion costs, the competing port will lose profit. When the discriminative toll system is introduced, commuters will be tolled at the marginal cost, while trucks will be tolled even lower than that price. |
Study | Technique | Methodology | Objective | Results |
---|---|---|---|---|
Song et al., 2016 [33] | Bertrand competition Multinomial Logit model Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Shipping lines make a port-of-call decisions. Ports make pricing decisions. | Examine horizontal and vertical interactions between liners and ports. | When ports and liners are considered as identical players, the Nash equilibrium results in the lowest possible service charge. When ports and liners are considered as different players, liners will increase container volume and keep the service charge the same. Ports with constrained geography and limited capacity would benefit from cooperating with neighboring ports, which would allow redirecting excess demand. |
Bae et al., 2013 [23] | Bertrand competition and collusion Cournot competition | Two-stage game where: Ports make pricing decisions. Shipping lines make port-of-call decisions. | Analyze container port competition and collusion for transshipment cargo in the presence of shipping lines. | The higher-level transshipment ports that have sufficient capacity to handle excess traffic are more attractive to shipping lines. Ports with excess capacity can attract more demand by lowering prices, while the unused capacity can dissipate the congestion effect. The port collusion model will lead to a higher port price compared to the non-cooperative model. |
Pujats et al., 2019 [34] | Stackelberg game Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Shipping lines in an alliance make shipping size decisions Container terminals decide to cooperate or compete by utilizing their capacities. | Develop a mathematical framework for container terminal and liner shipping company cooperation and competition using the Stackelberg model. | The developed game theory-based model not only could assist marine container terminal operators and port authorities in identifying optimal contractual agreements, but it also could help identify optimal operational plans that support the implementation of such contractual agreements. |
Asgari et al., 2013 [35] | Stackelberg gameNash equilibrium | Two-stage game where:Shipping companies make route network design decisions.Hub ports make total handling cost decisions. | Develop route network design in a setting of port and shipping company cooperation and competition. | Short term is the easiest way to control pricing; also, change in handling charges gives control over capacity and competitive power. In the medium term, cooperation with the dominant shipping line may partially secure market share. In the long run, cooperation between ports is beneficial as port capacity may be constrained by geography and neighboring ports. |
Tulja-Suban, 2017 [36] | Stackelberg game Nash equilibrium | Two-stage game where: Shipping operators make port-of-call decisions. Spoke ports make handling charge decisions under one of the cooperation/competition scenarios. | Examine competition and cooperation between a hub and spoke ports in a shipping network. | There is no optimal strategy between the ship companies and spoke ports, port competition could lead to a reduction in the activities of the weaker port, and port cooperation between spoke ports could raise incomes and improve container transshipment services. |
Angeloudis et al., 2016 [37] | Bertrand competition Nash equilibrium | Three-stage game where: Shipping lines or alliances make fleet investment decisions. Shipping lines or alliances make service design decisions, and the route assignment problem is solved. Shipping lines or alliances make freight rate decisions on each leg. | Determine the optimum set of liner services modeled as a monopoly or duopoly. | When a duopoly was considered, shipping lines or alliances selected different service networks, thus reducing the competitive pressure. |
Study | Technique | Methodology | Objective | Results |
---|---|---|---|---|
Basso et al., 2013 [12] | Hotelling model | Three-stage game where: Governments make packability investment decisions. Ports make pricing decisions. Shippers make decisions on whether to accept the port of call and demand the product. | Investigated government strategic investment decisions on inland transportation infrastructure in the port catchment area and common hinterlands with competing ports | Increased investment in the hinterland would decrease charges at both ports, but the increased investment in a port catchment area will significantly decrease its charges compared to the rival port. |
Matsushima and Takauchi, 2014 [38] | Bertrand competition Cournot competition | Three-stage game where: Governments make decisions on whether to privatize or not. Ports make port usage fee decisions. Firms in both countries make quantity decisions. | Examine the effects of port privatizations on port usage fees, firm profits, and welfare in a setting of port and manufacturing firm competition located in two countries: home and foreign. | Under low (per unit) transportation costs either both or none of the ports are privatized, under moderate transportation costs both ports are privatized, and under high transportation costs none of the ports are privatized. |
Lee et al., 2012 [25] | A game model with Oligopolistic players Nash equilibrium | Three-stage game where: Ocean carriers make service charges and delivery route decisions. Terminal operators make port throughput and service cost decisions. Land carriers make service demand and land transportation cost decisions. | Investigate pricing and routing decisions between ocean carriers, land carriers, and terminal operators in a maritime freight transportation network. | Provided a tool to evaluate ocean carrier, terminal operator, and land carrier decision-making processes in the freight shipping market. |
© 2020 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Pujats, K.; Golias, M.; Konur, D. A Review of Game Theory Applications for Seaport Cooperation and Competition. J. Mar. Sci. Eng. 2020, 8, 100. https://doi.org/10.3390/jmse8020100
Pujats K, Golias M, Konur D. A Review of Game Theory Applications for Seaport Cooperation and Competition. Journal of Marine Science and Engineering. 2020; 8(2):100. https://doi.org/10.3390/jmse8020100
Chicago/Turabian StylePujats, Karlis, Mihalis Golias, and Dinçer Konur. 2020. "A Review of Game Theory Applications for Seaport Cooperation and Competition" Journal of Marine Science and Engineering 8, no. 2: 100. https://doi.org/10.3390/jmse8020100
APA StylePujats, K., Golias, M., & Konur, D. (2020). A Review of Game Theory Applications for Seaport Cooperation and Competition. Journal of Marine Science and Engineering, 8(2), 100. https://doi.org/10.3390/jmse8020100