Next Article in Journal
Non-Performing Loans for Italian Companies: When Time Matters. An Empirical Research on Estimating Probability to Default and Loss Given Default
Next Article in Special Issue
A Comprehensive Approach for Calculating Banking Sector Risks
Previous Article in Journal
Generalized Hyperbolic Distribution and Portfolio Efficiency in Energy and Stock Markets of BRIC Countries
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

Population, Income, and Farmland Pricing in an Open Economy

Kate Tiedemann School of Business and Finance, University of South Florida, 140 7th Ave S, St. Petersburg, FL 33701, USA
*
Author to whom correspondence should be addressed.
Int. J. Financial Stud. 2020, 8(4), 67; https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8040067
Submission received: 30 September 2020 / Revised: 20 October 2020 / Accepted: 23 October 2020 / Published: 28 October 2020
(This article belongs to the Special Issue Quantitative Finance)

Abstract

:
Farmland valuation models usually incorporate local purchasing power as one of the pricing factors. A plausible rationale is that a larger population and higher income per capita imply increasing demand for agricultural products and farmland. In this paper, we study the relationship between the agricultural land prices, the regional population, and income per capita in an open economy setting in nominal and real variable terms using data from 1929 to 2018 at the state level. We show that in most areas of the United States, agricultural land prices are less affected by the state population or personal income. The valuation of agricultural land should not factor in the local purchasing power factors, with a few exceptions.
JEL Classification:
G10; R32; Q24

1. Introduction

Conventional pricing models believe that agricultural land values of an area are usually determined by a series of factors at the regional level: local purchasing power, land productivity, and land market demand and supply interactions. These factors should be distinguished with the set of microfactors that determine a single farmland asset, such as size, amenity, access to convenient traffic, etc. We study the relationship between state-level population, state income per capita, and state-level farmland price. In an economy where the liquidity of population and capital input is limited and the demand for agricultural products is restricted to local markets, farmland’s price should be positively related to the population and income per capita of the economy. The Proposition I presented in Section 2 and its proof provide the reasoning for this argument. However, in an open economy, how important are population and purchasing power related to the farmland price? Specifically, how are the farmland prices in the United States related to the population and income per capita? Our study aims to address these questions.
The meaning of answering these questions roots from the risk of using the above-mentioned argument in the farmland pricing process. It is a widely-observed practice to misuse the doctrine derived from a closed economy setting to guide farmland valuation. We attempt to clarify if the following assertion is unwarranted: the price range of a farmland lot located in a “rich” area with high population density ought to be at the higher quantile due to the greater opportunity cost and greater demand for its products. Our efforts focus on switching from a static closed economy model to a dynamic, open economy setting by introducing external farmland price and investment opportunity variables.
There is a large body of literature studying the determinants of farmland prices. The previous studies approach this topic from three perspectives: examining the impacts of individual factors, the impacts from marketplace transactions, or the impacts from macroeconomic variables.
From the individual factor effect perspective, Terry et al. (1982) is one of the earliest holistic studies on farmland value determinants. Their study shows that bordering roads, year sold, soil capability class, grain sorghum yield, and percent cropland have the greatest influence on land value. Severen et al. (2018) use a forward-looking Ricardian approach to incorporate the CCSM 3 and Hadley 3 models and conclude that land markets capitalize climate change forecasts. Malaitham et al. (2018) conclude that the distance to the main road, time to the CBD station, and the distance to the shopping mall affect farmland value in the Bangkok metropolitan area of Thailand. Uematsu et al. (2013) split the pricing of farmland by land and amenity value. They show that natural amenity increases with farmland values, and such a relationship is more significant for high-end farmland. Buck et al. (2014) highlight the value added to farmland by water and water rights accessibility. Hauer et al. (2017) document the impact of land use change on land value using the Alberta case. Boisvert et al. (1997) also confirm the important role of environmental pollution in farmland price modeling.
From the marketplace transaction perspective, Hüttel et al. (2016) analyze institutional investors’ role in farmland pricing and point out that privatization agencies conduct transactions with premia. In contrast, individual agencies perform oppositely. Lehn and Bahrs (2018) use a quantile-to-quantile plot to examine German standard farmland values. They find inconsistent relationships across the estimated quantiles, with results that show that nonagricultural factors are more significant at the high-end farmlands. Stokes and Cox (2014), alternatively, study the farmland price from a different angle. They survey the speculative behavior of agricultural outputs at the marketplace and confirm the speculative value of farm real estate. Drescher et al. (2001) suggest that agricultural production attributes and demand factors impact farmland prices. Their research is the first one we identify that provides a theoretical foundation of demand factors functioning on farmland valuation. In this paper, our incorporation of purchasing power is set up to emphasize the demand for farmland outputs.
From the macroeconomic perspective, the value of sales per acre, average farm size, and the percentage of farmland significantly affect Oregon’s farmland values, as presented by Sandrey et al. (1982). They also show that population density plays an important role in the value of farmland in Willamette Valley. Their study is the first one we identify to investigate the impact of the population on farmland transactions. Besides, our method is consistent with theirs about using the demand for agricultural products as a proxy of income per acre. Just and Miranowski (1993) conclude that inflation and real return changes are the dominating factors determining farmland prices. Weerahewa et al. (2008) address the role of urban growth. In the course of urbanization, the price of raw lands is increased significantly by developers. This process escalates the opportunity costs of maintaining the agricultural use of farmland. Kuethe et al. (2013) suggest that common trends influence farmland returns in alternative investments and general macroeconomic conditions. Based on Just and Miranowski (1993) and Weerahewa et al. (2008), we establish our model with all real terms. Bellemare and Lee (2016) confirm the impact of price volatility and income uncertainty regarding the agricultural economic policy. Nilsson and Johansson (2013) suggest that agricultural and nonagricultural factors are influential determinants of agricultural land prices. They estimate the marginal effects and indicate that nonagricultural factors are more important in regions with high agricultural land prices. Borchers et al. (2014) also conclude that farmland’s output level only partially determines its price and that nonagricultural factors impact land value. Our results are consistent with theirs after introducing the local population and state income per capita into our model. Their study inspires our investigation to go beyond the endogenous land productivity considerations, normally regarded as the dominating factor of farmland value.
However, there is a significant gap in past literature. To our knowledge, no study has contributed to building a microeconomic foundation and analyzing the effects of the macroeconomic variables. Past studies either address the influence of individual microeconomic variables, such as distance to highway, water accessibility, and environmental factors or investigate the influence of transactions and demand for agricultural products. Besides, most of the studies on farmland prices are conducted as case studies for a region as small as a county, or, at most, one state. We believe that there is a need to clarify the joint effects from both markets on land prices: the factor market and the product market.
Another significant gap exists in the determinants of farmland value. Previous studies do not distinguish between the level variables and the incremental variables. In other words, it is unclear if the population affects land prices or the change of population influences the change in the land price. The same situation applies to the investor and consumer purchasing power. While the level variables describe the impact of inventory, the incremental variables represent agricultural real estate market response to an independent variable shock impulse. The investigation of the incremental variables in this study enables us to learn if the impact from population and purchasing power are short term via impulse-response or long term via cumulative variables.
Lastly, our study proposes an open economy model instead of the conventionally used closed economy model. The major difference between these two models is that in an open economy, we do not assume local investors and consumers to be restricted to target the local farmland and its output. Recognizing the mobility of capital as well as population brings the survey of farmland price to a greater picture that considers states in the U.S. as a general factor and product market. This universal market idea avoids the robustness concern that a set of farmland value determinants in one region is less valid in a different area.
Section 2 presents the open economy farmland value model and explains the possible failure of the local population’s impact and purchasing power. The data and regressions we conduct regarding the farmland price in the 48 continental states in the U.S. are explained in detail in Section 3. In Section 4, the effect of population and income per capita on farmland price, as well as the impact on the change in population and income per capita on farmland price, is described. Finally, the conclusion in Section 5 suggests the possible future research path.

2. The Model and Method

Proposition I: If an economy has limited population mobility, and the demand to agricultural industry outputs are self-sufficient, then the farmland price of this economy is positively driven by its population and income per capita.
Proof. 
Let denote the farmland price in this closed economy. The farmland price is a function of a series of factors, stated in Equation (1):
= ( θ , λ , ξ )
where θ is the price of the agricultural products and their derivatives that are not risk hedging; λ stands for the accessibility of capital inputs; and ξ refers to the productivity of the land by the geographical nature. Holding ξ constant, i.e., regarding the land production rate as an exogenous variable that does not affect population or purchasing power, the farmland price is determined by the price level of the products from the land, the accessibility of capital input, and the land productivity developed in Equation (2).
= ( θ , λ , ξ ¯ )
Assume = ( · ) , θ = θ ( · ) , and λ = λ ( · ) are differentiable, given the Law of Demand for a closed economy,
θ ( β , κ )   β > 0 ,   θ ( β , κ ) κ > 0 ,   λ ( β , κ ) β > 0 ,   λ ( β , κ ) κ > 0 ,   and   θ > 0
where κ denotes the population; and β represents the income per capita of the economy.
Applying the Chain Rule, we arrive at
β > 0 ,   and   κ > 0
Proposition I states that a closed economy’s farmland price is positively driven by its population and income per capita in a closed economy. We revise the model and introduce external factor markets and product markets.
This study proposes Proposition II below and provides a theoretical basis to argue that higher local population and local purchasing power does not necessarily increase the local farmland price.
Proposition II: Allowing for population and capital mobility, and not requiring the demand for agricultural industry outputs to be self-sufficient, the accessibility of capital inputs on out-of-state farmland is the determinant regarding whether its population and income per capita positively drive the farmland price of a state.
Proof. 
Let γ represent the out-of-state farmland price without loss of generality. Though there are different price levels out of the state under discussion, we use γ to denote a single farmland price that the local investors and consumers target. This simplifies the model setting. Consistently, we use γ to denote the accessibility of capital inputs on out-of-state farmland.
We assume that there are two types of agricultural outputs in the state under discussion. The first type is either uniquely produced in the state, or the majority of the product is produced in the state at the overall market level so that out-of-state consumers rely on this state’s production. In either case, the state has the dominating pricing power for this product, and the product is priced at θ 1 . The other product this state produces is a general product that is also widely supplied by other out-of-state farmlands. The state is a price taker and has no influence on the output pricing. The price of this general product is θ 2 .
The farmland price of a state is the weighted average of the prices of the farmlands 1 and 2 that produce both types of products, stated in Equation (3). The weights of the prices of the farmlands producing different outputs are ω 1 and ω 2 , respectively.
= ω 1 1 ( θ 1 , λ , ξ ) + ω 2 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ )
where λ stands for the accessibility of capital inputs in the state; and ξ refers to the productivity of the land by the geographical nature. We continue to hold ξ as constant. Then the price of the farmland that produces the unique or dominating product is determined by the price level of the product, the accessibility of capital input, and the land productivity, stated in Equation (4). Note that there is no role for out-of-state farmland price because the product under discussion is not produced out of state significantly enough to affect the output price.
1 = 1 ( θ 1 , λ , ξ ¯ )
Similarly, the price of the farmland that produces the general product is determined by the price level of the product, the accessibility of capital input of both the current state ( λ ) and out-of-state ( γ ), and the land productivity, presented in Equation (5). There is an implicit role for out-of-state farmland price γ , because the capital input γ is related to γ from Equation (6).
2 = 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ )
γ = γ ( θ 2 , γ , λ , ξ ¯ γ )
Assume all functions are differentiable, given the Law of Demand, the following relationships still hold:
θ 1 ( β , κ )   β > 0 ,   θ 1 ( β , κ ) κ > 0 ,   λ ( β , κ ) β > 0 ,   λ ( β , κ ) κ > 0 ,   and   1 θ > 0
where κ denotes the population; and β represents the income per capita of the economy. This case for the unique product is similar to the close economy conclusion. However, the case for general product is different:
θ 2 ( β , κ )   β = 0 ,   θ 2 ( β , κ ) κ = 0 ,   λ ( β , κ ) β > 0 ,   λ ( β , κ ) κ > 0 ,   γ ( β , κ ) β > 0 ,   γ ( β , κ ) κ > 0
However, most importantly,
2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) γ < 0 ,   or   equivalently ,   γ 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) < 0
Taking the full derivative of the farmland price by assuming the linearity of = ( · ) ,
β = ω 1 θ 1 1 ( θ 1 , λ , ξ ¯ ) θ 1 ( β , κ ) β + ω 2 θ 2 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) θ 2 ( β , κ ) β + ω 2 γ 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) γ ( β , κ ) β
and
κ = ω 1 θ 1 1 ( θ 1 , λ , ξ ¯ ) θ 1 ( β , κ ) κ + ω 2 θ 2 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) θ 2 ( β , κ ) κ + ω 2 γ 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) γ ( β , κ ) κ
Applying the Chain Rule, we arrive at the conclusion that
β > 0 ,   if   and   only   if   ω 1 θ 1 1 ( θ 1 , λ , ξ ¯ ) θ 1 ( β , κ ) β + ω 2 θ 2 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) θ 2 ( β , κ ) β ω 2 γ ( β , κ ) β > | γ 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) |
and
κ > 0 ,   if   and   only   if ω 1 θ 1 1 ( θ 1 , λ , ξ ¯ ) θ 1 ( β , κ ) κ + ω 2 θ 2 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) θ 2 ( β , κ ) κ ω 2 γ ( β , κ ) κ > | γ 2 ( θ 2 , λ , γ , ξ ¯ ) |
If Equations (7) and (8) are violated, the regional population and income per capita do not positively affect the regional farmland value. This is due to the dilution of consumer purchasing power to regional agricultural products from out-of-state suppliers. The distraction of investor investment focuses on the out-of-state agricultural real estate property opportunities. □

3. Data and Regressions

We define farmland as land where the systematic and controlled agriculture use is conducted to produce food for humans and farm-raised animals. It includes cropland, pasture, or rangeland. We use the state-level population, income per capita, and farmland prices to investigate the empirical relationships between the demand for agricultural products, the investment capacity to farmland properties, and farmland value. The annual data is of the 48 continental states from the year 1930 to 2018. The state population data and income per capita data are cited from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA). The farmland prices are cited from the National Agricultural Statistics Service Database (NASS) of the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA). The farmland price data from 1997 to 2018 are concluded from the census data, and the data from 1930 to 1996 are from the survey data. We choose to use the agricultural land asset value measured in dollar per acre variable, including the land’s amenities. This is because the farm amenities are regarded as part of the agricultural production and operation practice. As Just and Miranowski (1993) and Weerahewa et al. (2008) suggest, we use real-term variables to conduct the regressions. The annual Consumer Price Index cited from the Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) from St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank is used to convert variables from nominal terms to real terms.
There are two reasons that we employ data for a long period of time. Firstly, the population data and the income data are surveyed or partially surveyed and interpolated on an annual basis. To maintain an accurate and meaningful dataset, we do not increase the frequency of the dataset to quarterly or higher to gain a greater number of observations. Secondly, the impact of purchasing power is not immediately transferred and reflected in the land price concurrently. To avoid drawing a spurious conclusion due to a short time window, we conduct our investigation with a long time span to allow for a gradual impact.
To facilitate the comparison and understand the influence of money supply and interest rate change, we present the population’s regressions and state income per capita on state farmland price all on nominal terms in the Appendix A. The difference between the regression coefficients is reported in Table 1.
Using the real terms in our empirical model calibration allows us to separate the monetary effect on income per capita growth from the real growth on the income per capita. Accordingly, the farmland prices are deflated by the same deflator to exclude the impact of interest rate and money supply. These effects are engaged nationwide, and therefore excluding the nominal monetary returns does not change the relative prices of the farmlands in the state and out of state.
In this study, two groups of regressions are performed on the real term variables: the level and the change. The level variables reflect the cumulative effects of population and income on land prices. The incremental variables imply the short run impulse generated by population and income and their impacts on the concurrent change of farmland price. Equation (9) describes the regression function using the level variables. Equation (10) describes the regression function using the incremental variables.
= ( c ( γ , ξ ) , β , κ )
Δ = ( c ( γ , ξ ) , Δ β , Δ κ )

4. Results from Empirical Evidence

In this section, we report the regressions described in Equations (9) and (10) conducted on the 48 continental United States, as well as the entire United States. By comparing the number of coefficients being significantly presented in Table 1, we conclude that the population incremental variables positively influence farmland price. In contrast, the income per capita level variables have weaker impacts on farmland prices. In other words, farmland values are less sensitive to a transient change of state personal income but are more responsive to the short term change of state population—Table 2 and Table 3 present the detailed comparisons.
We detect a significant number of states that violate the conditions presented in Equations (7) and (8) in Table 2 and Table 3. In fact, as Table 2 suggests, there is no significant relationship between state population and state farmland price in 27.08% of the states. Similarly, 31.25% of the states do not have a significant relationship between state income per capita and state farmland price. A few states are carrying higher farmland prices when the population and income are lower. At the national level, although the population positively influences the farmland price, the real income does not change the land price.
The short-run impact of population and income are reported in Table 3. We do not find any adverse relationship between population change, income change, and land price change. However, we detect more insignificant impacts in the short run. The violations to Equations (7) and (8) are more widely seen at the short-run level. State-level farmland prices in the United States do not follow the closed economy model proposed in Proposition I, but they follow the open economy model proposed in Proposition II.
In addition, we fail to find a deterministic pattern for states that have higher land prices with higher population and income, versus the ones that do not. The geographical distribution is scattered and does not follow a regional group character. We attribute it to the diversity of agricultural products and the heterogeneous nature of farmland property investment opportunities. While the model presented in this study categorizes the farmland outputs into two types: unique and general, the business practice introduces more complicated classifications.
We also study the subperiod identifications. Our time series samples are divided into three segments: 1930–1958, 1959–1988, and 1989–2018. These divisions should not be interpreted as structural breaks, as we do not use significant business cycles or policy changes to guide the division. This grouping method’s merit is to warrant an equal number of observations in three separate regressions so that the significance of the regression coefficients is comparable. Table 4, Table 5 and Table 6 report the regression outputs.
The results show that the change of state income per capita better explains the change of farmland price over time, whereas the results are mixed for the impact of population change. A plausible explanation is that increasing state income per capita influences the land price from two channels: higher personal income increases the demand for agricultural products and the farmland property investment opportunities. The dual effects on both the product market and the factor market enhance purchasing power’s impact on real assets and financial assets.
We present the regression results at the United States national level to serve as a benchmark of comparison with each individual state. In fact, the outputs of some of the states are comparable to smaller economies in other parts of the world. The regression at the national should be compared with other economies with caution due to the size effect.

5. Concluding Remarks

This paper studies two types of models: farmland prices and their interactions with population and income in a closed economy and an open economy. The empirical findings challenge the current state of knowledge that farmland prices are intuitively related to local purchasing power. We show that the farmland prices in many areas in the United States are not related to the population and state income per capita, which translate into purchasing power. We first provide a closed economy model and propose that a greater population and purchasing power increase farmland prices. We then expand the model to include an open economy setting. This shows that with universal products and out-of-state investment opportunities, the determinants of farmland value in a state do not necessarily include local purchasing power on the product or factor market.
Further, we conclude that the following conditions must hold to warrant a positive relationship between land price and product demand: local population, income per capita, agricultural product price, capital accessibility, and land productivity. The conditions are summarized in Equations (8) and (9). Next, we use the 48 continental states’ annual data from 1930 to 2018 and empirically measure the relationship. Excluding the impact from inflation and monetary policies, 27.08% of the states do not present a positive relationship between cumulative population and farmland price; 31.25% of the states do not show a positive relationship between cumulative income per capita and farmland price. In addition, 56.25% of the states do not demonstrate a positive relationship between annual incremental population and incremental farmland price; 72.92% of the states do not reveal a positive relationship between annual incremental personal income and incremental farmland price.
It is, therefore, risky to use the closed economy mindset when valuating the farmlands. The price range of a farmland lot located in a “rich” area with high population density does not have to be anchored at higher starting points in auctions and appraisals. On the contrary, investors might identify undervalued investment opportunities in states with lower population and personal income if the closed economy valuation practice pertains.
The next step of research might be looking at the reason for the lack of arbitrage transactions or the arbitrage financial instrument’s design. A question raised from our conclusion would be: given the fact that there are high and low farmland prices that are not warranted, arbitrage opportunities exist to bring the land prices back to their fair values. The obvious answer to this question is that there is a limited mobility of farmland property transactions due to real estate investments’ nature. However, if the existing financial instruments that securitize the lands provide such arbitrage channels, this would be of great interest to explore.

Author Contributions

H.D. contributed to the literature review, the proof of propositions, and the data collection. X.G. contributed to the data regression and results analysis, as well as drafting the working paper. All authors have read and agreed to the published version of the manuscript.

Funding

This research is funded by the University of South Florida.

Acknowledgments

We thank the editors and the anonymous reviewers for their comments. We appreciate the funding support from the University of South Florida. This research received no external funding.

Conflicts of Interest

The authors declare no conflict of interest.

Appendix A

Table A1. The impact of state level population and income per capita on nominal agriculture land price, nominal variables.
Table A1. The impact of state level population and income per capita on nominal agriculture land price, nominal variables.
Dependent variable: Nominal state land price (1930–2018)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept−31.9575−194.1679205.9384541.4082 ***15.0542−316.3592−2008.807 **118.4139−537.0088−1988.9
(123.9849)(382.1046)(126.7328)(145.6664)(38.4062)(346.8923)(926.2268)(107.1813)(362.2639)(2008.162)
State population0.00820.1092−0.6281 ***−0.0627 ***−0.01850.12262.1988 *−0.0634 **0.12980.6801
(0.0399)(0.2042)(0.1383)(0.0104)(0.0246)(0.1452)(1.2556)(0.0255)(0.1025)(0.7645)
State ipc0.0675 ***0.0660 ***0.1843 ***0.1716 ***0.0271 ***0.1817 ***0.1817 ***0.1456 ***0.0642 ***0.1178 ***
(0.0022)(0.0066)(0.0224)(0.0065)(0.0021)(0.0044)(0.0083)(0.0107)(0.0174)(0.0106)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−129.2773822.5766484.8618371.936345.5781−503.3647 ***914.62936.8334−440.3951 ***503.7348 **
(173.0678)(690.685)(524.9707)(275.2820)(305.868)(121.3129)(999.6685)(268.0863)(103.5029)(235.0662)
State population0.1562−0.1013−0.1495−0.1791−0.02170.2043 ***−0.2229−0.03340.4943 ***−0.0933 ***
(0.3034)(0.0738)(0.1239)(0.1364)(0.1035)(0.039)(0.2021)(0.0935)(0.1113)(0.0334)
State ipc0.0563 ***0.1207 ***0.1351 ***0.0350 ***0.0823 ***0.0478 ***0.2005 ***0.1353 ***0.0479 ***0.1063 ***
(0.0091)(0.0078)(0.0096)(0.0032)(0.0047)(0.0024)(0.0081)(0.007)(0.0014)(0.0043)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept1057.748 **543.5236−142.796256.2600−351.0578−1770.709 ***186.9788−323.2774 **−148.148115.4392
(429.6371)(390.3578)(360.3162)(61.0368)(242.399)(286.1235)(701.8118)(144.7737)(573.3203)(14.4536)
State population−0.3722 ***−0.14640.0783−0.11730.07942.8218 ***−0.17810.5174 **0.0068−0.0215
(0.1359)(0.0955)(0.1661)(0.0988)(0.0596)(0.4585)(0.5097)(0.2344)(0.1017)(0.0186)
State ipc0.0914 ***0.0694 ***0.0626 ***0.0208 ***0.0949 ***0.0205 ***0.0456 ***0.0796 ***0.2348 ***0.014 ***
(0.0076)(0.0053)(0.0047)(0.0012)(0.0091)(0.0011)(0.006)(0.0041)(0.0085)(0.0008)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept−101.0128 ***−112.6606421.9781−348.9924 **89.3197166.40031841.792−100.7898−1624.723 ***−8.5037
(14.3112)(104.1708)(334.3464)(153.693)(60.2009)(412.0525)(1211.302)(150.2628)(616.7172)(184.6501)
State population0.7149***0.0091−0.05990.1626 **−0.0820 **−0.0228−2.8183 *0.04472.4078**−0.0060
(0.0908)(0.0067)(0.0381)(0.0644)(0.0385)(0.0385)(1.4726)(0.069)(0.9476)(0.0551)
State ipc−0.0237 ***0.0459 ***0.1154***0.0259 ***0.0516 ***0.1141 ***0.3311 ***0.0759 ***0.0210 ***0.0862 ***
(0.0058)(0.0008)(0.0046)(0.0027)(0.0026)(0.0024)(0.0113)(0.0053)(0.0041)(0.0048)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept93.7989118.0770 *330.2106 *−77.81192.6296987.7146 ***−1119.3790 **−0.1452366.6344 **
(81.9072)(62.5509)(180.5915)(75.8189)(59.1724)(331.7925)(440.6486)(20.6961)(155.1849)
State population−0.0132−0.2460 ***−0.1133 **0.17330.0106−0.3122 ***0.5813 **−0.0247−0.0026 ***
(0.0098)(0.0828)(0.0493)(0.1903)(0.0236)(0.0903)(0.2399)(0.0663)(0.0009)
State ipc0.0422 ***0.0645 ***0.0995 ***0.0665 ***0.0439 ***0.1048 ***0.0687 ***0.0113 ***0.0616 ***
(0.0045)(0.0051)(0.0053)(0.0013)(0.0025)(0.0055)(0.0012)(0.0004)(0.0038)
This table presents the impact of state level population and income per capita on the agriculture land prices. All variables are on the nominal terms. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. The standard errors of the regression coefficients are reported in the parentheses. IPC stands for the income per capita.
Table A2. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth, nominal variables.
Table A2. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth, nominal variables.
Dependent variable: Nominal state land price change (1930–2018)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept−0.5008−1.1589−28.926478.8812 *0.219119.001717.5781−35.4052−33.7758−23.0375
(6.1040)(7.3413)(18.5633)(43.6476)(4.7919)(40.1791)(58.1165)(39.5344)(23.7822)(32.4400)
State population change0.15320.17730.4096 *−0.1694 *0.02110.3930−1.54760.16400.5732 **1.1214
(0.135)(0.1849)(0.2423)(0.1003)(0.0826)(0.9004)(2.2882)(0.1819)(0.2653)(0.9171)
State ipc change0.0632 ***0.0715 ***0.0831 ***0.1296 ***0.0253 ***0.1318 ***0.1411 **0.1168 ***0.04680.1743 ***
(0.0077)(0.0102)(0.0228)(0.0199)(0.0038)(0.0246)(0.0631)(0.0334)(0.0294)(0.0364)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−31.6803 ***0.0182−20.3011−1.7762−0.7182−19.8886 **49.4995−31.4523−3.566917.0418
(11.0109)(28.9871)(29.0133)(8.1027)(9.9167)(9.4743)(40.2996)(63.9235)(5.8094)(18.0497)
State population change1.4831 **0.06900.30130.13060.29280.6047***−0.38740.00940.9716 **−0.0852
(0.5957)(0.2095)(0.4238)(0.329)(0.2169)(0.1374)(0.5684)(0.962)(0.4227)(0.1462)
State ipc change0.0869 ***0.1217 ***0.1579 ***0.0367 ***0.0784 ***0.0711 ***0.1071 ***0.1696 ***0.0445 ***0.0816 ***
(0.0141)(0.0256)(0.0296)(0.0080)(0.0136)(0.0094)(0.0306)(0.0392)(0.0068)(0.0182)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept−1.4811−7.2140−4.7778−9.4744 **−12.77739.4937−5.3360−4.2371−2.7806−2.1700
(18.9151)(9.9484)(6.4719)(4.718)(14.1968)(6.3141)(12.1756)(17.6536)(68.1986)(2.5318)
State population change0.0361−0.02010.05450.31370.3098 **2.0829 ***0.53752.4892 *−0.2686−0.0127
(0.3583)(0.1594)(0.1677)(0.3513)(0.1517)(0.5857)(0.6768)(1.2621)(0.6385)(0.0996)
State ipc change0.0861 ***0.0873 ***0.0817 ***0.0339 ***0.0765 ***0.0122 ***0.0557 ***0.0498 ***0.2235***0.0190 ***
(0.016)(0.0122)(0.0104)(0.0053)(0.014)(0.0044)(0.0123)(0.0143)(0.0474)(0.0028)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept−3.017612.5872 *−14.81625.7437−9.27332.8832−3.6663−8.29772.0381−10.7859
(4.6348)(7.4272)(18.7963)(4.0958)(7.3816)(14.1398)(64.005)(8.5176)(8.3568)(10.3114)
State population change0.3180 ***−0.00950.08320.2491 ***0.3210 *0.0467−2.60160.5954 ***0.71000.4177 **
(0.1158)(0.0286)(0.1334)(0.089)(0.1772)(0.0924)(4.4595)(0.2138)(0.8153)(0.1634)
State ipc change0.00710.0312 ***0.1478 ***0.0189 ***0.0442 ***0.1058 ***0.3053 ***0.0476 ***0.0345 ***0.0662 ***
(0.005)(0.0057)(0.0204)(0.0037)(0.0064)(0.015)(0.0671)(0.0105)(0.0086)(0.0113)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept−11.7156 *−16.5197 **−15.20765.8177−0.0618−25.0992−5.2767−0.1905−7.296
(6.396)(7.5435)(25.4251)(5.5396)(7.719)(15.129)(8.5931)(1.5753)(17.9656)
State population change0.0618 **0.8369 ***0.10940.28490.13100.28920.34140.6303 ***0.0026
(0.0241)(0.2381)(0.3320)(0.6977)(0.1091)(0.2637)(0.2511)(0.1750)(0.0078)
State ipc change0.0338 ***0.0339 ***0.0930 ***0.0549 ***0.0334 ***0.1242 ***0.0760 ***0.0086 ***0.0599 ***
(0.0051)(0.0080)(0.0181)(0.0059)(0.005)(0.0147)(0.0128)(0.0010)(0.0079)
This table presents the impact of the change of state level population and the change of income per capita on the change of agriculture land prices. All variables are on the nominal terms. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. The standard errors of the regression coefficients are reported in the parentheses. IPC stands for the income per capita.

References

  1. Bellemare, Marc F., and Yu Na Lee. 2016. Attitudes to price risk and uncertainty: The earnest search for identification and policy relevance. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue Canadienne D’agroeconomie 64: 599–612. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  2. Boisvert, Richard N., Todd M. Schmit, and Anita Regmi. 1997. Spatial, productivity, and environmental determinants of farmland values. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79: 1657–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Borchers, Allison, Jennifer Ifft, and Todd Kuethe. 2014. Linking the price of agricultural land to use values and amenities. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 96: 1307–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Buck, Steven, Maximilian Auffhammer, and David Sunding. 2014. Land markets and the value of water: Hedonic analysis using repeat sales of farmland. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 96: 953–69. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Drescher, Klaus, Jason Henderson, and Kevin McNamara. 2001. Farmland prices determinants. Working paper. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Hauer, Grant, M. K. Luckert, Denys Yemshanov, and Jim Unterschultz. 2017. A spatial real options approach for modeling land use change: Assessing the potential for poplar energy plantations in Alberta. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue Canadienne D’agroeconomie 65: 271–92. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  7. Hüttel, Silke, Lutz Wildermann, and Carsten Croonenbroeck. 2016. How do institutional market players matter in farmland pricing? Land Use Policy 59: 154–67. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. Just, Richard E., and John A. Miranowski. 1993. Understanding farmland price changes. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75: 156–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Kuethe, Todd, Todd Hubbs, and Mitch Morehart. 2013. Farmland returns and economic conditions: A FAVAR approach. Empirical Economics 47: 129–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Lehn, Friederike, and Enno Bahrs. 2018. Quantile regression of German standard farmland values: Do the impacts of determinants vary across the conditional distribution? Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics 50: 453–77. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  11. Malaitham, Sathita, Atsushi Fukuda, Varameth Vichiensan, and Vasinee Wasuntarasook. 2018. Hedonic pricing model of assessed and market land values: A case study in Bangkok metropolitan area, Thailand. Case Studies on Transport Policy 8: 153–62. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  12. Nilsson, Pia, and Sara Johansson. 2013. Location determinants of agricultural land prices. Jahrbuch Für Regionalwissenschaft 33: 1–21. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  13. Sandrey, Ronald A., Louise M. Arthur, Ronald A. Oliveira, and W. Robert Wilson. 1982. Determinants of Oregon farmland values: A pooled cross-sectional, time series analysis. Western Journal of Agricultural Economics 7: 211–20. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. Severen, Christopher, Christopher Costello, and Olivier Deschênes. 2018. A forward-looking Ricardian approach: Do land markets capitalize climate change forecasts? Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 89: 235–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  15. Stokes, Jeffrey R., and Arthur T. Cox. 2014. The speculative value of farm real estate. Journal of Real Estate Research, American Real Estate Society 36: 169–86. [Google Scholar]
  16. Terry, David D., Wilfred H. Pine, and Orville W. Bidwell. 1982. Determinants of farmland values. Transactions of the Kansas Academy of Science 85: 152–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Uematsu, Hiroki, Aditya R. Khanal, and Ashok K. Mishra. 2013. The impact of natural amenity on farmland values: A quantile regression approach. Land Use Policy 33: 151–60. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  18. Weerahewa, Jeevika, Karl D. Meilke, Richard J. Vyn, and Zahoor Ul Haq. 2008. The determinants of farmland values in Canada. AgEcon Research CATPRN Working Paper, 1–38. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Table 1. Comparison of nominal and real term variables’ regression significance.
Table 1. Comparison of nominal and real term variables’ regression significance.
Real LevelNominal LevelReal ChangeNominal ChangeReal Change Sub-IReal Change Sub-IIReal Change Sub-III
PopulationSignificantly Positive68.75%18.75%43.75%31.25%12.50%35.42%16.67%
Significantly Negative4.17%18.75%02.08%000
Not significant27.08%62.50%56.25%66.67%87.50%64.58%83.33%
IPCSignificantly Positive58.33%97.92%27.08%95.38%016.67%31.25%
Significantly Negative10.42%2.08%006.25%2.08%0
Not significant31.25%072.92%4.17%93.75%81.25%68.75%
NationPopulationSignificantly PositiveSignificantly NegativeSignificantly PositiveNot significantSignificantly PositiveNot significantNot significant
IPCNot significantSignificantly PositiveNot significantSignificantly PositiveNot significantNot significantNot significant
This table presents the percentage of regression coefficients being positively significant, negatively significant, or not significant at 10% level, among the 49 regressions conducted on the 48 U.S. continental states, and the whole nation. IPC stands for income per capita. The real level refers to the regressions from the state population and the state income per capita on the state farmland price in real terms. The nominal level refers to the regressions from state population and state income per capita on state farmland price in nominal terms. The real change refers to the regressions from the change of state population and the change of state income per capita on the change of state farmland price in real terms. The nominal change refers to the regressions from the change of state population and the change of state income per capita on the change of state farmland price in nominal terms. The three subperiods are from 1930 to 1958, 1959 to 1988, and 1989 to 2018.
Table 2. The impact of state level population and income per capita on agriculture land price, real variables.
Table 2. The impact of state level population and income per capita on agriculture land price, real variables.
Dependent variable: Real state land price (1930–2018)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept−2702.0490 ***285.7594617.8436 ***−1119.4900 ***−7.2831−2022.1940 ***−1113.4480380.6376 *−937.2626 ***−16824.5400 ***
(612.1409)(449.0517)(146.1928)(314.2345)(34.9004)(569.2497)(1448.6580)(211.3133)(147.2625)(3490.2070)
State population1.0973 ***−0.05910.9686 ***−0.03810.1484 ***0.7116 **−1.97400.2614 ***0.4009 ***7.1554 ***
(0.2513)(0.2855)(0.0582)(0.0445)(0.0525)(0.3405)(1.7352)(0.0481)(0.0715)(1.4620)
State ipc0.00560.0669 ***−0.0874 ***0.1690 ***0.0112 **0.1771 ***0.1984 ***0.00340.0195−0.0014
(0.0145)(0.0097)(0.0110)(0.0360)(0.0052)(0.0119)(0.0150)(0.0224)(0.0127)(0.0233)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−116.7629−3079.9920 *−4580.3610 ***307.3188−4016.7170 ***−2276.2590 ***4534.3980 **−1468.5990 ***−1923.5810 ***−314.5724
(77.3259)(1580.9070)(1152.2610)(605.2129)(692.3808)(387.1118)(1836.5790)(465.6290)(370.6176)(487.2043)
State population1.3432 ***0.4922 **1.6898 ***0.08161.7563 ***1.3461 ***−1.5763 ***0.8652 **2.6528 ***−0.0084
(0.2474)(0.2352)(0.4249)(0.3747)(0.2922)(0.1775)(0.4554)(0.4159)(0.5242)(0.1155)
State ipc0.01100.0386−0.03610.0190 *−0.0091−0.0334 ***0.2865 ***0.0697 *0.0181 **0.0951 ***
(0.0087)(0.0308)(0.0391)(0.0099)(0.0143)(0.0121)(0.0212)(0.0362)(0.0078)(0.0181)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept−3011.7990 ***−4221.4660 ***747.3507−340.3919 ***−836.4540 ***−2735.3200 ***−4021.7500 ***−2395.1620 ***−2913.4510 ***13.7025
(1114.1960)(847.2459)(929.1902)(94.3383)(197.4197)(351.9770)(820.1660)(245.5641)(946.7977)(15.8406)
State population1.4691 ***1.3824***−0.25250.6284 ***0.4129 ***4.6705 ***3.5549 ***6.8677 ***0.4630 *−0.0828
(0.5262)(0.2761)(0.4893)(0.2347)(0.0817)(0.5767)(0.6921)(0.8808)(0.2597)(0.0702)
State ipc−0.0288−0.0311 *0.0659 ***0.0122 ***0.0378 ***0.0151 ***−0.0103−0.0334 *0.2120 ***0.0170 ***
(0.0329)(0.0180)(0.0142)(0.0035)(0.0131)(0.0016)(0.0093)(0.0173)(0.0254)(0.0035)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept205.9501 ***−446.1155−840.209460.7416−128.2145 **−1475.7314356.309 *−466.8615**−3107.134***−2359.023 ***
(46.912)(298.922)(725.6913)(281.4381)(53.2966)(1163.9100)(2448.174)(198.0439)(447.5603)(331.5895)
State population0.3036 ***0.0640 ***0.1227−0.08560.6481 ***0.0989−12.8862 ***0.4648 ***5.2470 ***1.0941 ***
(0.0242)(0.0234)(0.1168)(0.1527)(0.1153)(0.1235)(3.7932)(0.1485)(0.7391)(0.1502)
State ipc−0.00050.0330 ***0.0886 ***0.0315 ***−0.00800.1137 ***0.4884 ***0.0381 ***0.0032−0.0189
(0.0020)(0.0034)(0.0174)(0.007)(0.0097)(0.0094)(0.0361)(0.012)(0.0036)(0.0141)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept90.6431 *76.5364−896.6787 *−1676.0220 ***284.5692 ***−424.3346−2677.6570 ***−107.9027 ***−1075.908 **
(52.0011)(59.7196)(476.941)(259.8049)(68.2611)(1028.6140)(816.3555)(34.2693)(412.3740)
State population0.01150.9245 ***0.39005.1691 ***−0.00650.09421.3897 ***0.4202 **0.0140***
(0.0153)(0.1026)(0.2692)(0.9109)(0.0971)(0.4201)(0.4455)(0.1862)(0.0051)
State ipc0.0271 ***−0.0173 **0.04250.0346 ***0.0412 ***0.0734 **0.0668 ***0.0085 ***−0.0181
(0.0078)(0.0077)(0.0312)(0.0069)(0.0122)(0.0302)(0.0026)(0.0015)(0.0240)
This table presents the impact of state level cumulative population and deflated income per capita on deflated agriculture land prices. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. The standard errors of the regression coefficients are reported in the parentheses. IPC stands for the income per capita.
Table 3. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth, real variables.
Table 3. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth, real variables.
Dependent variable: real state land price change (1930–2018)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept16.637118.2233−43.7277 *74.6595−1.783647.505790.5426−77.6346−23.277729.0005
(12.4868)(14.6269)(25.716)(65.1233)(8.8595)(52.3264)(61.7895)(54.7747)(32.9197)(41.9524)
State population change0.43270.41921.0000 ***0.00520.18351.7473−2.46750.5177 **0.6142 **2.8225 **
(0.2813)(0.3799)(0.2674)(0.1557)(0.1332)(1.3067)(2.9664)(0.2157)(0.2914)(1.3872)
State ipc change0.00360.01450.01950.01830.0113**0.0424−0.00470.03080.01290.0211
(0.0133)(0.0170)(0.0179)(0.0257)(0.0057)(0.0295)(0.0492)(0.0312)(0.025)(0.0319)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−45.2326 **22.1559−5.61334.01023.9788−36.2801 *74.093011.9509−5.756332.7566
(17.3410)(45.6099)(45.0370)(12.1764)(16.6766)(20.0717)(54.7223)(84.8751)(9.4222)(21.6238)
State population change3.8981 ***0.33901.2636 *0.42080.9582 **1.0932 ***−0.10420.67832.4790 ***0.1219
(0.8169)(0.3747)(0.7426)(0.5101)(0.3749)(0.3073)(0.8117)(1.4513)(0.7546)(0.2152)
State ipc change0.0315 ***0.04450.04320.00800.02780.0715 ***0.04860.05120.0238 ***0.0112
(0.0119)(0.0361)(0.0323)(0.0098)(0.0192)(0.0202)(0.0405)(0.0503)(0.0090)(0.0147)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept28.048727.257722.3076−3.62145.669412.363011.1953−27.265379.68632.2874
(31.1379)(18.3130)(13.5371)(6.6520)(25.7834)(7.7579)(16.6040)(23.9545)(91.0182)(4.7565)
State population change0.43530.03710.15201.0917 **0.35392.6521 ***1.47106.6086 ***0.09610.1135
(0.5747)(0.3137)(0.3938)(0.5290)(0.2364)(0.7611)(0.9913)(1.7322)(0.9309)(0.1819)
State ipc change−0.00010.00190.00450.0120 **0.021100.00240.01710.06480.0024
(0.0221)(0.0192)(0.0190)(0.0054)(0.0194)(0.0034)(0.0124)(0.0174)(0.0583)(0.0046)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept−3.257121.4097 *29.3550−2.6887−22.8010 *42.8225 *100.82859.646110.8824−12.7518
(6.8884)(11.5065)(32.0081)(8.2515)(12.4894)(24.8012)(74.7472)(17.1539)(9.3796)(18.4800)
State population change0.3564 **0.01480.20550.4977 ***1.1484 ***0.0647−2.58340.54991.58300.8155 ***
(0.1459)(0.0496)(0.2756)(0.1772)(0.2876)(0.1846)(6.3985)(0.3542)(1.0084)(0.2656)
State ipc change0.00080.00290.03690.0185 **0.00370.02500.1312 *0.00180.00620.0254 *
(0.0034)(0.0088)(0.0280)(0.0070)(0.0074)(0.0263)(0.0780)(0.0149)(0.0060)(0.0144)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept−18.4446−26.4906 **3.933114.354−0.87821.02657.5888−1.4252−33.8773
(12.1305)(13.0610)(37.0754)(9.6371)(17.2203)(26.0650)(12.9035)(2.5059)(30.6553)
State population change0.0998 **1.4915 ***0.33432.6485 **0.25870.74420.928 **1.1914 ***0.0243 *
(0.0384)(0.3516)(0.4936)(1.2773)(0.2212)(0.4831)(0.433)(0.2834)(0.0126)
State ipc change0.0235 ***0.00300.02970.0222 **0.01140.0366 *0.0390 *0.0059 ***0.0093
(0.0077)(0.0088)(0.0252)(0.0098)(0.0083)(0.0217)(0.0200)(0.0016)(0.0113)
This table presents the impact of state level changes of population and the change of deflated income per capita on the change of deflated agriculture land prices for the full period of our study from 1930 to 2018. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. The standard errors of the regression coefficients are reported in the parentheses. IPC stands for the income per capita.
Table 4. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth (1930–1958), real variables.
Table 4. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth (1930–1958), real variables.
Dependent variable: real state land price change (1930–1958)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept10.913010.7085−0.4781−94.7155 **1.241651.7485 **29.4163 **−51.4650 **14.0848 *0.9971
(7.0947)(7.2585)(4.3251)(42.5311)(6.1680)(24.9192)(12.5322)(21.2133)(7.6507)(20.3448)
State population change−0.0519−0.15320.1867 **0.4043 ***−0.00460.0567−0.38830.5885 ***−0.09900.2094
(0.1521)(0.1911)(0.0868)(0.1184)(0.1631)(0.5387)(0.4093)(0.1528)(0.1323)(0.4638)
State ipc change−0.00280.0035−0.0044−0.00560.0051−0.0355 **−0.0036−0.00890.00050.0053
(0.0084)(0.0106)(0.0036)(0.0192)(0.0047)(0.0137)(0.0081)(0.0159)(0.0078)(0.014)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−0.340113.602912.28321.513418.2326 *23.5380 *34.30860.593110.21822.1719
(8.6082)(18.7699)(16.9561)(7.9683)(10.1023)(11.9964)(58.3622)(21.4538)(8.0331)(13.5236)
State population change0.70440.10610.4156 *0.1819−0.1260−0.0869−0.37890.8614 **−1.06120.1369
(0.5893)(0.1192)(0.2226)(0.2581)(0.2224)(0.2074)(0.7703)(0.3627)(0.6862)(0.0945)
State ipc change0.00930.02180.0134−0.0001−0.00990.0050−0.0258−0.0209−0.0152 *0.0006
(0.0064)(0.0142)(0.0114)(0.0062)(0.0149)(0.0111)(0.0640)(0.0128)(0.0087)(0.0068)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept−3.31143.83217.3341 **2.768337.0965 **2.1831−4.383210.441823.29351.9186
(12.1095)(8.7534)(6.5074)(2.7939)(14.6608)(3.5637)(9.4693)(6.9597)(36.8246)(3.0373)
State population change0.2113−0.1203−0.19470.0017−0.1911−0.05190.2971−0.11500.50950.0321
(0.2000)(0.1269)(0.1557)(0.1869)(0.2005)(0.2939)(0.5177)(0.7027)(0.3342)(0.1273)
State ipc change0.0160.0059−0.0112−0.0010−0.0122−0.0041−0.0021−0.00640.01490.0030
(0.0134)(0.0104)(0.0090)(0.0026)(0.0163)(0.0029)(0.0079)(0.0090)(0.0255)(0.0026)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept0.9329−4.71326.12512.3222−0.035921.986847.6843 *22.7950 **−3.826815.8278
(4.0896)(12.417)(20.8923)(6.6416)(9.3405)(12.9259)(24.2917)(10.6789)(5.1293)(10.747)
State population change−0.02090.04420.18290.07310.2136−0.11630.6339−0.43280.4162−0.0801
(0.4533)(0.0478)(0.1237)(0.1615)(0.2441)(0.0796)(1.9952)(0.3196)(0.4673)(0.186)
State ipc change−0.00040.00230.01550.0051−0.0010−0.0167−0.02530.0042−0.0001−0.0019
(0.0017)(0.0111)(0.0142)(0.0092)(0.0058)(0.0144)(0.0230)(0.0128)(0.0038)(0.0117)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept3.3287−6.786710.27014.8579−10.4965−1.08951.90432.0325−27.7558 **
(8.0213)(5.1429)(11.5303)(4.7727)(12.8013)(10.7216)(5.174)(2.4843)(13.4865)
State population change0.02760.18040.1603−0.31970.5187 **−0.0371−0.0138−0.12170.0184 **
(0.0460)(0.2766)(0.1784)(0.6530)(0.2340)(0.1792)(0.1368)(0.3970)(0.0067)
State ipc change0.00070.0007−0.0161−0.0138 *−0.0036−0.00510.0016−0.00140.0028
(0.0063)(0.0039)(0.0120)(0.0070)(0.0072)(0.0102)(0.0081)(0.0022)(0.0063)
This table presents the impact of state level changes of population and the change of deflated income per capita on the change of deflated agriculture land prices for the first subperiod of our study from 1930 to 1958. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. IPC stands for the income per capita.
Table 5. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth (1959–1988), real variables.
Table 5. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth (1959–1988), real variables.
Dependent variable: real state land price change (1959–1988)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept3.8516−12.04737.2705166.2563−24.791326.076595.736462.2669152.4645 *−21.6886
(37.5108)(51.5527)(22.7180)(168.4695)(27.2907)(89.4998)(66.4330)(105.9706)(74.7833)(68.1421)
State population change1.847 **2.17360.1030−0.17190.8401*1.0968−6.97870.1834−1.124715.8693 ***
(0.8572)(1.7000)(0.2544)(0.3346)(0.4618)(2.1040)(5.7888)(0.3603)(0.8567)(3.7166)
State ipc change−0.0409−0.0134−0.0123−0.1072−0.01250.1406 **−0.1087−0.0500−0.0253−0.0194
(0.0347)(0.0429)(0.0113)(0.0784)(0.0229)(0.0565)(0.0679)(0.0451)(0.0315)(0.0531)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−59.5787 **−152.9289−164.32228.1090−105.1599 ***−223.2427 ***47.558387.231117.9881−22.6783
(25.4966)(123.6446)(102.1078)(33.8875)(32.7342)(46.2670)(56.3695)(129.4707)(17.7176)(46.6684)
State population change6.4184 ***2.5829*5.8083 **0.37194.4516 ***3.7105 ***−0.22731.65692.4801*0.7326
(1.5185)(1.4757)(2.5625)(1.8904)(0.8575)(0.8412)(1.1214)(2.0944)(1.2555)(0.5942)
State ipc change−0.00490.05180.0004−0.01780.0527 *0.2363 ***0.1611 ***−0.11560.01310.0081
(0.0199)(0.1145)(0.0833)(0.0289)(0.0304)(0.0608)(0.0462)(0.0939)(0.016)(0.035)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept−50.38537.7858−2.1971−5.30745.74027.827915.2627−151.7752 **136.817812.1586
(123.8357)(61.2872)(49.3791)(8.0008)(112.5752)(13.3488)(31.8935)(55.1737)(150.0746)(12.6917)
State population change2.90221.35251.27092.2871 **0.25032.20882.847614.9514 ***0.51320.0754
(3.1709)(1.6457)(1.6265)(0.9355)(1.4368)(1.8276)(2.5432)(3.3143)(1.6509)(0.4596)
State ipc change−0.0563−0.06090.00330.0027−0.0333−0.0062−0.0433 *0.0306−0.0316−0.0181
(0.0518)(0.0459)(0.0548)(0.0064)(0.0490)(0.0045)(0.0230)(0.0276)(0.1141)(0.0122)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept−7.197044.3962 *−46.4694−55.7629 **−86.7648 ***62.073653.0136−10.16016.4548−126.35 **
(20.6420)(23.1391)(86.7274)(24.4734)(24.8459)(61.0277)(134.9453)(67.6862)(10.9585)(49.6599)
State population change0.61310.00791.32141.1754 **2.9222 ***0.4580−11.74321.29800.16223.3943 ***
(0.6468)(0.1692)(1.2965)(0.4601)(0.5915)(0.7944)(13.8104)(1.3952)(1.7164)(0.9066)
State ipc change−0.0032−0.01730.02060.0692 **0.0016−0.02090.3569 *−0.0152−0.00210.0197
(0.0087)(0.0245)(0.0877)(0.0274)(0.0177)(0.0727)(0.1797)(0.0416)(0.0063)(0.0296)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept−52.2338−69.0774 *108.77347.6016−30.239−66.873315.0486−4.1731−38.0548
(35.4734)(38.1335)(73.5617)(37.9904)(54.4506)(64.7404)(24.4617)(4.5012)(135.5701)
State population change0.14413.1917 ***−0.66765.73000.35362.68013.2028 ***1.1926 ***0.0294
(0.1123)(1.0898)(1.0133)(5.6585)(0.6496)(1.5987)(0.9910)(0.3806)(0.0541)
State ipc change0.0650 **−0.0174−0.01720.02960.04310.00460.03110.0075 *−0.0271
(0.0248)(0.0284)(0.0380)(0.0232)(0.0359)(0.0470)(0.0380)(0.0042)(0.0354)
This table presents the impact of state level changes of population and the change of deflated income per capita on the change of deflated agriculture land prices for the second subperiod of our study from 1959 to 1988. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. The standard errors of the regression coefficients are reported in the parentheses. IPC stands for the income per capita.
Table 6. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth (1989–2018), real variables.
Table 6. The impact of state level population growth and income per capita growth on agriculture land price growth (1989–2018), real variables.
Dependent variable: real state land price change (1989–2018)
StateALARAZCACOCTDEFLGAIA
Intercept21.115316.417−66.2225270.2019 *28.689339.1756165.765−168.1688−173.2011103.3631
(24.7479)(25.4839)(105.1042)(143.4991)(22.3518)(116.9729)(178.2702)(190.251)(122.9233)(132.5256)
State population change0.06450.47291.2407−0.2472−0.19154.5352−9.82490.69311.4980*1.6793
(0.6445)(0.6893)(0.8348)(0.3425)(0.2594)(4.1715)(12.6335)(0.6051)(0.7979)(7.8994)
State ipc change0.0455 *0.0492*0.06910.03070.0197 **0.03750.03530.07570.03850.0940
(0.0226)(0.0253)(0.0532)(0.0458)(0.0089)(0.069)(0.1359)(0.0752)(0.0629)(0.0855)
StateIDILINKSKYLAMAMDMEMI
Intercept−194.4253 **148.9294 *157.747715.862536.940813.0865130.0179−81.1613−36.7711 *78.2340 *
(70.8870)(74.0616)(101.6347)(35.5166)(45.9326)(18.6670)(148.3357)(262.1013)(18.9073)(40.4197)
State population change7.9759 ***−0.3605−1.3191−0.00040.79940.3949−1.43950.67026.6518 ***0.2898
(2.5577)(0.8807)(2.1216)(2.0580)(1.4820)(0.2698)(3.4078)(5.0109)(2.3840)(0.9032)
State ipc change0.1006 ***0.03580.07240.03300.01030.02910.03170.2426 *0.0376*0.0289
(0.0309)(0.0564)(0.0680)(0.0201)(0.0452)(0.0189)(0.0972)(0.1314)(0.0209)(0.0378)
StateMNMOMSMTNCNDNENHNJNM
Intercept146.1163 *51.170916.7153−41.7964−31.666−7.028424.5922−52.7747157.7643−0.7604
(75.1370)(32.6348)(16.6520)(27.7290)(64.8168)(15.2007)(58.9105)(63.2506)(219.4906)(8.6945)
State population change−1.2222−0.42800.25343.65840.544610.6291 ***0.85587.9188−2.9407−0.0052
(1.5254)(0.7643)(0.6595)(2.4797)(0.4400)(1.8167)(3.9940)(5.8473)(3.4179)(0.3251)
State ipc change0.03080.0757 **0.0502*0.0413**0.0608 *0.00490.0424−0.00860.18690.0172*
(0.0346)(0.0324)(0.0268)(0.0166)(0.0318)(0.0061)(0.0294)(0.0381)(0.1461)(0.0097)
StateNVNYOHOKORPARISCSDTN
Intercept−9.621729.3457115.1553 **12.026113.570543.721382.2543−8.557220.2768−16.8014
(25.4738)(23.1551)(50.9444)(15.6326)(37.0261)(53.6272)(192.9365)(44.0462)(41.4735)(46.8206)
State population change0.39440.0531−1.23750.36930.36360.3441−3.70340.86572.45730.9844
(0.3503)(0.1251)(1.2518)(0.4811)(0.7417)(0.6834)(15.1321)(0.73)(4.9919)(0.6081)
State ipc change0.00600.00640.0987 **0.00860.02160.06630.18380.02130.02140.0244
(0.0093)(0.0156)(0.0436)(0.0068)(0.0152)(0.0540)(0.1943)(0.0251)(0.0196)(0.0288)
StateTXUTVAVTWAWIWVWYUnited States
Intercept−72.8703 *−59.2635−99.975224.248878.7875 *24.333618.1940−0.4310121.5215
(38.5442)(50.3990)(135.8806)(21.3352)(41.7348)(62.8398)(31.1728)(5.5716)(103.8813)
State population change0.2221 **1.7721 *1.46260.0747−0.50051.24915.4797 *2.1600 ***−0.0294
(0.0927)(0.9373)(1.5358)(4.4096)(0.4159)(1.4599)(2.841)(0.7781)(0.0368)
State ipc change0.0251 **0.0334 *0.08570.02220.01530.07270.05800.0065 ***0.0323
(0.0113)(0.0195)(0.0567)(0.0192)(0.009)(0.046)(0.0487)(0.0023)(0.0193)
This table presents the impact of state level changes of population and the change of deflated income per capita on the change of deflated agriculture land prices for the third subperiod of our study from 1989 to 2018. Single, double, and triple asterisks (*, **, ***) indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% level. The standard errors of the regression coefficients are reported in the parentheses. IPC stands for the income per capita.
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Dong, H.; Guo, X. Population, Income, and Farmland Pricing in an Open Economy. Int. J. Financial Stud. 2020, 8, 67. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8040067

AMA Style

Dong H, Guo X. Population, Income, and Farmland Pricing in an Open Economy. International Journal of Financial Studies. 2020; 8(4):67. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8040067

Chicago/Turabian Style

Dong, Huijian, and Xiaomin Guo. 2020. "Population, Income, and Farmland Pricing in an Open Economy" International Journal of Financial Studies 8, no. 4: 67. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8040067

APA Style

Dong, H., & Guo, X. (2020). Population, Income, and Farmland Pricing in an Open Economy. International Journal of Financial Studies, 8(4), 67. https://doi.org/10.3390/ijfs8040067

Note that from the first issue of 2016, this journal uses article numbers instead of page numbers. See further details here.

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop