1. Introduction
According to its founding act, the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU) aims to create a harmonized and integrated economic space favourable to economic and social development with fulfilled citizens. It places particular emphasis on the balanced development of the Community area. It proposes to achieve this the optimization of the assets and potentialities of each Member State in a complementary perspective. Numerous additional protocols, additional acts and directives form the framework of WAEMU initiatives to establish an integrated zone with the key to the adoption of a Convergence, Stability, Growth and Solidarity Pact. This dynamic is supported by numerous theoretical and empirical developments in the economic literature. Indeed, cooperation and economic integration are seen as levers for promoting
1 productivity, economic growth and job creation and are likely to increase the well-being of the countries participating in them (
Viner 1950). They allow member countries to better sharpen their weapons in a regional framework to develop the capacity and confidence necessary to attack international and more demanding markets (
Rouis and Tabor 2012). Better regional integration and the development of trade that it fosters make it possible to promote peace and build peaceful regions (
Schiff and Winters 1998;
Palachek 1999). Integration is, therefore, a tool for development and progress.
However, economic integration has not always been a catalyst for development. It sometimes has and according to specific trends, reinforced the vulnerability and fragility of certain member countries or, in some cases, provoked conflicts.
Reinert and Kattel (
2013) showed that regional integration could lead to asymmetric results. For instance, regional integration combined with integration into the world economy may devastate the industrial structures in some members’ states, indicating that regional integration can lead to a lose-win/zero-sum game type of integration, rather than a win-win flying geese type.
Hugon (
2014) believes that in a situation of asymmetry in size and economic potential, the dominant country is the main beneficiary of openness and regionalization. It considers that this is the case for Brazil in Mercosur, South Africa in SADC, Côte d’Ivoire in WAEMU or Kenya at the ECA level. Regionalization can therefore promote polarization of income or development in favour of one country to the detriment of another.
As far as WAEMU is concerned, this polarization is clearly perceptible in the economic literature.
Decaluwé et al. (
2000) questioned the factors of convergence or divergence in development, resulting from the reallocation of resources and trade generated by the creation of the Union between the member countries. They showed that Côte d’Ivoire, which has the ratio of factors of production the least distant from the world mean average, is the country that benefits the most from the regional integration process. Conversely, Burkina Faso sees its situation deteriorates. The mobility of labour and industrial capital accentuates the phenomenon of divergence between the WAEMU member states. Thus, Senegal, and to a lesser extent Togo, would see their situation deteriorate in the long term compared to the baseline scenario due to the flight of industrial capital and consequently the widening of their development gap with Côte d’Ivoire.
Ndiaye (
2006), based on the per capita GNP levels of the African economies of the Franc Zone, shows that the WAEMU regional convergence process is relatively slow. Its results reveal two subsets or convergence clubs in the WAEMU; one club of countries would converge above the average and the another would converge below the average of per capita income levels. This conclusion, close to the work of
Venables (
1999), reinforces the idea of sometimes asymmetrical benefits that could result from cooperation, a customs union or integration.
Indeed, The WAEMU is the West African economic and monetary union created in 1994. This union includes eight countries: Benin, Burkina Faso, Côte d’Ivoire, Guinea-Bissau, Mali, Niger, Senegal, and Togo. These countries share the same money, West African francs (CFA francs), monetary policies, and French as an official language. The union’s objective is to promote regional economic integration and create a common market. Benin, Cote d’Ivoire, Guinea Bissau, Senegal and Togo are on the coast of West Africa, whereas Burkina Faso, Mali and Niger are landlocked countries. Besides, all the eight countries form a closed geographic area, indicating that each country shares the same border with at least one of the eight members.
Stylized facts from the WAEMU region, support the argument that some countries, namely leaders of the integration union, can monopolize the entire benefit of the cooperation. In particular, we can note that in the WAEMU region the share of exports of Cote d’Ivoire and Senegal within the union represents more than 60% of the overall exports (
BCEAO 2020). Equally, according to the last decade’s statistics, the best economic performance is about 6.72% which Cote d’Ivoire records while Guinea Bissau records the least performance at 3.85% (
BCEAO 2020). These statistics indicate a high level of disparity in economic growth among the WAEMU countries. Moreover, there is a substantial income inequality indicating that Cote d’Ivoire has the highest GDP per capita (1950
$USD) and Niger and Togo back with the lowest GDP per capita (484
$USD and 567
$USD respectively). Yet, a comparative analysis of pre-WAEMU and post-WAEMU may lead to the inefficiency of the regional integration. For instance, the mean dispersion in the economic growth within the region was 1.26 before the WAEMU union, against 0.73 after the WAEMU, indicating some improvements in the convergence process. However, the mean income per capita dispersion was about 338 before the integration and 378 after the integration, indicating a slight divergence.
From these stylized facts, this research underlines the problem of the distributional effects of regional integration externalities within the WAEMU region. Consequently, the main question that arises from this research is to know whether regional integration leads to creation or diversion effects complementarity or competition within the cooperating countries. In particular, does regional integration promote income convergence within the WAEMU countries? If so, to what magnitude regional integration moves toward income convergence?
The rationale of this research is based on the lack of empirical studies within the region that investigated the convergence effects of regional integration. Indeed, many studies confirmed the growth effects of regional integration in Africa and other developing regions like Asia (
Ejones et al. 2021;
Liu 2016;
Jalles 2012;
Vamvakidis 1998). However, to the best of our knowledge, less attention has been devoted to on how the overall benefit of the regional integration is distributed among the country WAEMU. Yet, the WAEMU regional integration is one of the oldest integration union in Africa. Thus, the motivations for investigating regional integration’s effect in terms of income convergence are at least twofold. First, as the integration is costly (for example, loss of sovereignty), it is prominent to know the net return (in terms of growth and welfare benefits) of this choice. Second, the 10th sustainable development goal posits that reducing inequalities among countries is one requirement to achieve sustainable development.
Our investigation is based on two analysis tools; on the one hand, we calculate the sigma convergence to assess the degree of convergence or divergence of the trajectories of the different economies in the regional economy, and on the other hand, we use the analytical framework of
Dendrinos and Sonis (
1988,
1990) in order to assess the complementarity-competition relations between the countries of the WAEMU region. Our analysis covers the period 1995–2015 for the sake of data availability. The paper is organized around five sections. The second section presents the methodological framework, while the third session presents the results of the estimations and their analysis. The conclusions and policy implications complete the document.
2. Methodology
The methodological approach to analyzing the complementarity or competition relations between the WAEMU countries is organized into two points. First, we will evaluate the actual convergence of the economies of this region (using the sigma-convergence), and secondly, we’ll assess the possible effects of spatial interaction existing between the countries of space with
Dendrinos and Sonis (
1988,
1990) framework. The advantage of using two different methodological approaches is that the sigma-convergence analysis only considers the single overview of income dispersion among countries, with the
Dendrinos and Sonis (
1988,
1990) frameworks’ helps to capture the various interactions between countries.
2.1. Convergence Analysis: σ Convergence
The concept of convergence is frequently used in economic analysis. Integration in both WAEMU and ECOWAS, for example, refers to the convergence of a set of macroeconomic indicators. The WAEMU Convergence, Stability, Growth and Solidarity Pact imposes precise conditions for the convergence of a number of macro-budgetary variables. Many growth models have attempted to analyze the convergence of different economies (
Baumol 1986;
Barro 1991;
Mankiw et al. 1992;
Knight et al. 1993;
Islam 1995;
Berthélémy et al. 1997;
Barro and Sala-i-Martin 1992). Convergence occurs when the difference between series or their dispersion is reduced over time. However, there are different convergence schemes and convergence measures.
Fuss (
1999) proposes an in-depth review of the literature. The economic literature essentially distinguishes between two notions of convergence: β-convergence, which focuses on the existence of a convergence mechanism, and σ-convergence, based on the evolution of the dispersion of GDP per capita of different economies over time. The β-convergence consists of testing a negative relationship between the growth rate and the initial value of GDP per capita. Widely used in the literature, this test has however, been the subject of many critics who disqualify on use (
Quah 1993a,
1993b,
1994,
1996;
Bernard and Durlauf 1991). These criticisms include the fact that it does not consider the non-stationarity of the variables, in particular the income variable. Moreover, it is blamed for its lack of clarity in the interpretation of the convergence result, the extent to which it is a victim of Galton, where a result that statistically reflects β-convergence can be associated with a constant or even increasing dispersion distribution. In the face of these criticisms, the σ-convergence is preferred (
Fuss 1999). The use of the σ-convergence in the context of this study will make it possible to assess the trends of income polarization or not in the union, the periods most affected and whether, in total, the union is an area of integration of solidarity or individuality.
For all seven WAEMU countries considered in the analysis
2, convergence will be assessed based on GDP per capita or from the sum of the square of national differences to the average value. Thus, consider the achievements of a convergence criterion
C, for year
i in the WAEMU countries
j, and
, the achievements’ average. The sigma-convergence associated with this criterion is measured by
as described in Equation (1):
Between two years or periods,
i and
I + h, there is convergence if
is greater than
. The preference given to a simple average rather than a weighted average stems from the WAEMU Treaty, which confers the same importance on all member States, regardless of their economic size. Considering
GDP per capita (
GDPtt) as a convergence criterion, Equation (1) measured by
becomes Equation (2):
To assess the significance of sigma-convergence hypothesis, the test of
Carree and Klomp (
1997) is applied. A statistic
T is derived as a function of the evolution of the dispersion between two periods (
and
). This statistic is corrected by a catch-up factor
of the estimator
(with
= 1+
) associated with the beta-convergence equation estimated in instantaneous section:
The
T statistically follows a reduced centered normal distribution under the null assumption that intra-community dispersions are constant over time against the alternative hypothesis of convergence as mentioned in (4):
In the application to the countries in our concern, the power of the test suffers from a limited number of observations, not compatible with the normal law underlying inference. With good statistics,
Carree and Klomp (
1997) applied this test to samples of our compatible size. However, out of caution, this analysis will be supplemented with a nonparametric Wilcoxon test that has the quality of being non-restrictive on assumptions of error normality. All estimations, statistical tests, and figures was done on the STATA version 15 software.
2.2. Variables and Data Sources
This study uses a sample of seven WAEMU countries (Benin, Burkina Faso, Côte d’Ivoire, Mali, Niger, Senegal, and Togo) over the period 1995–2015. The main interest variable is the gross domestic product per capita. GDP is the sum of gross value added by all resident producers in the economy plus any product taxes and minus any subsidies not included in the value of the products. It is calculated without deductions for depreciation of fabricated assets or depletion and degradation of natural resources. Thus, GDP per capita is gross domestic product divided by midyear population. Data on GDP per capita used are in constant 2015 U.S. dollars and come from the world development indicators database of the World Bank group. It should be noted that some countries in the zone have carried out rebasing and thus changed the base year for estimating their aggregate. The period 1995–2015 is still the period over which most countries concerned still keep the same basis for estimating their aggregate. We then made a choice to keep this study period to avoid scale bias.
2.3. Analysis of Spatial Interaction Effects
To assess the possible effects of spatial interaction, this paper uses the basic model of
Dendrinos and Sonis (
1988,
1990). This model has been used in several analyses of interaction between countries or regions belonging to the same central corpus (
Hewings et al. 1996;
Kamarianakis and Kaslis 2005;
Nazara et al. 2001;
Bonet 2003). This model is able to generate results for the structure of the spatial correlation between the regions of a given country. It is also possible to examine the effects of a region, country or locality on these neighbours. It has also been used to analyze vertical or hierarchical relationships between regions or localities (
Nazara et al. 2006). Regional growth theories explain the growth of a region as the result of a zero-sum or non-zero-sum game (
Magalhaes et al. 2001). In the idea of the zero-sum game, the growth of a country is necessarily to the detriment of another country, which gives an important place to the interrelationship or strategic relations between countries or regions. In the second idea of a non-zero-sum game, the growth of a region can also depend on endogenous processes of self-maintenance or self-generation of it. Dendrinos-Sonis built their model based on the zero-sum game hypothesis. However, it is important to note that the outcome of the zero-sum game is related to relative growth between countries or regions and not to absolute growth. In other words, it accepts that a country or locality in a region can record growth in absolute terms (increase in its GDP) while its relative share between product terms (GDP) at the regional level decreases.
This paper is inspired by the application of the Dendrinos-Sonis model by
Nazara et al. (
2001) and
Bonet (
2003). The basic model is as follows. Let be
the relative income (relative to that of the region) of country
i at time
t. In this paper, we use the national shares of regional GDP (per capita). If we consider n countries in the economic union, we can define the vector as follows:
The relative discrete socio-spatial dynamics can be described as follows in Equation (5):
where, the function can take any arbitrary form provided that it satisfies the property of positivity. If the first country is chosen as the currency, or reference country, then:
Using Equation (6), the process described in Equation (5) can also take the form of the following system of Equation (7):
As the numerary guaranteed that the sum of the national shares gives one, it plays an important role in the model. This implies that the growth of one country is not independent of that of another country. Thus, the Dendrinos-Sonis model perhaps perceived as a framework for analyzing a competition model in terms of share (
Nazara et al. 2001). In this model, each country competes for the largest share of regional GDP, and as mentioned earlier, absolute growth is not synonymous with relative growth.
Following
Dendrinos and Sonis (
1988), we adopt a log-linear specification of
:
where in Equation (8)
represents the position or location advantage of each country
and the coefficient
as described in Equation (9) can take the form
Equation (9) can be interpreted as national growth elasticities with . In other words, is the percentage of growth of the country relative to country 1, the numerary, following a change of 1% in the growth in the country .
By linearizing, Equation (8) becomes:
This model makes it possible to capture the state interactions in which each country tries to compete in order to increase its share in regional GDP. Each country’s performance depends on two factors: (i) its comparative advantage and (ii) the behaviour of other countries in the region. This second factor is captured through the sign and amplitude of the coefficient . A negative sign of this coefficient implies a competitive relationship between countries and ; in other words, when the share of the country’s regional GDP increases that of the country decreases relative to the numerary country and vice versa. Otherwise, a positive coefficient would indicate a relationship of complementarity between the countries and . In this case, when the country increases its share in the regional GDP, the country also increases its share always relative to the numerary country.
We estimate Equation (10) by the seemingly unrelated regression (SUR) method. Since we are dealing with a system of equations having the same explanatory variables, Equation (10) is estimated using a seemingly unrelated estimator (SUR). The SUR technique employed also makes sure that the solution achieves the maximum log of the likelihood function.
3. Results
Table 1 presents results of sigma-convergence within the WAEMU region.
Figure 1 shows the evolution of the sigma-convergence of GDP per capita over the period 1995–2015, it appears that the dispersion decreased from 1995 to 2011 before gradually worsening until 2015. Overall, the Tests of
Carree and Klomp (
1997) and Wilcoxon do not statistically reject the significance of sigma-convergence over the period 1995–2005 even if we observe a rejection of this significance by the first test for the period 1995–2000.
From
Table 1 and
Figure 1, we can conclude that the convergence of GDP per capita in the WAEMU records three phases. The first phase of convergence lasted seven years and which goes from 1995 to 2003 (start of the implementation of the treaty), then the second phase of stagnation or parallel evolution of the GDP per capita, which also lasted about seven years (2003–2010), and finally the current phase of substantial divergence which has lasted since 2010. These results, suggest a slowdown in the Spirit of Solidarity of the Union and a gradual seizure of power by unilateral or individualist tendencies.
A cross-reading of these results with community activities makes it possible to understand these dynamics. The region has common sectoral policies in several areas (agriculture, energy, environment, industry, culture, mining, transport, etc.) and directives for harmonizing several frameworks, including that of public finance, trade policy and justice. Since the adoption of these policies in the early 2000s (for their majority), their implementation remains essentially at the stage of regulatory and institutional arrangements. While this situation could be explained by the need to ensure that a good coordination framework is in place, it creates a vacuum that each country is trying to fill by multiplying national or bilateral initiatives. These could prove effective for some countries and less so for others. There is also a risk that lacking its own resources, the WAEMU, as a regional coordinating body, has aligned itself with the agenda of donors, producing and multiplying common policies without a geniune spirit of follow-up; for example, the common industrial policy adopted in 2000 did not begin to be implemented until 2011, eleven years later. Aware of this inertia, the Member States are freeing themselves from the hope created by the initiative of these common policies and are redoubling individual initiatives in the absence of a framework to encourage cooperation. There are nationally fragmented policies, the lack of an organized and structured regional value chain, the weakening of bidirectional dependencies (except in the case of hinterland countries for transport). It can also be argued that since 2013, with the project for the common policy for peace and security in the WAEMU, the Union has made the search for political coordination in favour of security a major objective. Prioritizing avoids recurring conflicts to the detriment of industrial promotion and economic development questions.
The results of the SUR estimate of the Dendrinos-Sonis model for WAEMU are presented in
Table 2. Our results show that only six (06) out of the thirty-five (35) coefficients are statistically significant, indicating a low level of integration within the WEAMU region. We found a complementary effect between Benin and Senegal and the Burkina-Faso and Mali couple. At the same time, there is evidence of competition between Togo and the coupe Benin and Côte d’Ivoire.
Niger, in terms of effect or consequences, shows no significant signs, even if these are all negative. These results reflect a shallow integration of this country with the rest of the region, weak integration against the backdrop of competitive interactions with other countries in the region. This may explain the level of backwardness of this country in the region.
Côte d’Ivoire and Senegal, the two driving countries of the region, have no ripple effect on the other countries. In other words, an increase in the shares of the region’s most dynamic economies has no ripple effect on the other economies in the region. However, it should be noted that Côte d’Ivoire and Togo on the one hand and Benin and Togo on the other side have competitive relations. The most integrated country in the zone is Burkina Faso, with positive ripple effects on Benin and Senegal. In other words, a positive GDP shock in Burkina Faso at time t has a positive ripple effect on Benin and Senegal at time t + 1.
Any GDP shock in Burkina Faso and Mali positively affects on Senegal, which testifies to the good integration relations between Senegal and these two countries. The results, however, do not suggest any transitivity; Although well integrated in Senegal, Burkina Faso and Mali have no significant integration relationship. This indicates that the windows of cooperation between countries where they exist are very bilateral and are not multifunctional. The countries of the region must develop and promote more regional commons. The results also do not show a reciprocal relationship or a bidirectional effect. No country has either positive or negative two-way interaction. While an income shock on Burkina Faso and Mali has a positive ripple effect on Senegal, the reciprocal is not verified. Symmetry in economic relations is not established, and physical or institutional infrastructures that promote reciprocity are absent.
All in all, the results confirm the low integration between the countries of the WAEMU region. Empirical evidence does not support widespread competition, even if pockets of competition are reported. However, our results reveal very limited or virtually absent complementarity links. Only the cases of interaction of Mali and Burkina Faso on Senegal constitute an oasis in a desert of lack of coherence of national policies for harmonious development in space.