The Effects of Technological Progress in Innovative Regions on the Labor Markets of Lagging Regions: A Theoretical Perspective
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Description of the Theoretical Model
- The change in total unemployment in region i at time t that is due to the labor participation or the quitting of jobs by agents living in region i at time t:
- ii
- The change in total unemployment in region i at time t that is due to the out-migration of unemployed agents to region j:
- iii
- The change in total employment in region i at time t that is due to migration by the employed workers in region j at time t:
3. Equilibrium of the Labor Market
3.1. Equilibrium of the Labor Market with No Trade in Goods
- There is no arbitrage between workers employed in the manufacturing sector and the R&D sector in each region at any time if both sectors are to operate:
- Due to the symmetry of all capital goods, in region i at time t, we have:
- Since the existing knowledge is available for everyone in the R&D sector to use, in region i at time t, we have the following condition:
- The total workers in region i at time t is
- The total employment in the sector producing manufacturing goods in region i at time t is constant. Hence,
- The competitive market in the manufacturing sector will equalize the labor wage and the marginal productivity of labor. That is,
- The price of each capital good must be equal to the marginal product of each capital good in the manufacturing sector. Therefore,
3.2. Equilibrium of the Labor Market with Trade in Goods
4. Conclusions
Funding
Conflicts of Interest
1 | There are two generations of endogenous growth models. In addition to Romer (1990), other notable first-generation works include Aghion and Howitt (1992) and Grossman and Helpman (1991b). Key second-generation works follow Jones (1995a, 1995b); Kortum (1997); Segerstrom (1998); Aghion and Howitt (1998b); For a comprehensive discussion of the spread and backwash concepts, see Gaile (1980). |
2 | A specific variety of capital goods is denoted by k, and denotes a vector of capital goods (i.e., intermediate goods) in i at time t. |
3 | That is, (k) is a sunk cost that a monopolist has to pay for when it enters the capital market. |
4 | |
5 | For a comprehensive review of the knowledge-transfer function, see Sarkar (1998). For empirical studies on the relationship between knowledge spillovers and the absorptive capacity, see Girma (2005); Girma and Görg (2005); Falvey et al. (2007); For an in-depth treatment of a knowledge production function, see Griliches (1979). |
6 | This condition is in the spirit of Burdett and Mortensen (1998). |
7 | Since technology also raises the wages for workers employed in the manufacturing sectors. |
8 | Knowledge spillovers could also prevent the outflow of unemployed agents living in the rural region, whenever . This phenomenon would increase the unemployment rate in the rural region. However, this condition should not hold empirically because most urban regions are technological leaders. |
9 | That is, the optimal solution of labor input for the manufacturing sector is more than the number of available workers in a region. |
10 | A decision to work in another region depends on the mobility cost, the outside wage, and current and future wage differentials. Historically, given that rural–urban wage differentials have been growing over time, the brain drain effect could have a significant impact on the rural labor market. |
11 | In this analysis, I have ignored the complementary effect between urban and rural goods. In the next section, I show that there is suggestive evidence that the product market competition effect dominates the complementary effect. |
12 | . Hence, if , we have . |
13 | The unemployment benefit is measured relative to the urban output price. If urban technological progress deflates the price of urban products, the unemployment benefit also decreases over time. However, the price of urban goods is protected by the preference of consumers for urban goods, and therefore, the price of urban goods and the unemployment benefit might not necessarily decline over time. |
References
- Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1992. A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60: 323–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1998a. Growth in open economies. In The Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 365–401. [Google Scholar]
- Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1998b. Testing for endogenous growth. In The Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 403–47. [Google Scholar]
- Aghion, Philippe, and Peter Howitt. 1998c. Toward endogenous growth. In The Endogenous Growth Theory. Cambridge: MIT Press, pp. 11–51. [Google Scholar]
- Agrawal, Ajay, Devesh Kapur, John McHale, and Alexander Oettl. 2011. Brain drain or brain bank? The impact of skilled emigration on poor-country innovation. Journal of Urban Economics 69: 43–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Artz, Georgeanne. 2003. Rural area brain drain: Is it a reality? Choices 18: 11–15. [Google Scholar]
- Batabyal, Amitrajeet, and Hamid Beladi. 2015. Knowledge goods, ordinary goods, and the effects of trade between leading and lagging regions. Research Policy 44: 1537–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Batabyal, Amitrajeet, and Peter Nijkamp. 2019. The magnification of a lagging region’s initial economic disadvantages on the balanced growth path. Asia-Pacific Journal of Regional Science 3: 719–30. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bloom, Nicholas, Mark Schankerman, and John Van Reenen. 2013. Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica 81: 1347–97. [Google Scholar]
- Burdett, Kenneth, and Dale Mortensen. 1998. Wage differentials, employer size, and unemployment. International Economic Review 39: 257–73. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Card, David. 2001. Immigrant inflows, native outflows, and the local labor market impacts of higher immigration. Journal of Labor Economics 19: 22–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Desmet, Klaus. 2002. A simple dynamic model of uneven development and overtaking. The Economic Journal 112: 894–918. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Desmet, Klaus, and Ignacio Ortuño Ortín. 2007. Rational underdevelopment. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 109: 1–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Falvey, Rod, Neil Foster, and David Greenaway. 2007. Relative backwardness, absorptive capacity and knowledge spillovers. Economics Letters 97: 230–23. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Gaile, Gary. 1980. The spread-backwash concept. Regional Studies 14: 15–25. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Girma, Sourafel. 2005. Absorptive capacity and productivity spillovers from FDI: A threshold regression analysis. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 67: 281–306. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Girma, Sourafel, and Holger Görg. 2005. Foreign Direct Investment, Spillovers and Absorptive Capacity: Evidence from Quantile Regressions. Bundesbank Series 1 Discussion Paper, No. 2005, 13. Available online: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2785099 (accessed on 16 May 2017).
- Glaeser, Edward. 2011. Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier. New York: The Penguin Press. [Google Scholar]
- Griliches, Zvi. 1979. Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. Bell Journal of Economics 10: 92–116. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1991a. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press. [Google Scholar]
- Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1991b. Quality ladders and product cycles. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 557–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Grossman, Gene, and Elhanan Helpman. 1996. Technology and trade. In Handbook of International Economics. Edited by Gene Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff. Amsterdam: North Holland, pp. 1279–337. [Google Scholar]
- Gumpert, M. 2016. Rational underdevelopment: Regional economic disparities under the Heckscher-Ohlin Theorem. International Review of Applied Economics 30: 89–111. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hean, Oudom, and Mark Partridge. 2022. The impact of metropolitan technology on the non-metropolitan labor market: Evidence from U.S. patents. Regional Studies 56: 476–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hean, Oudom, and Nattanicha Chairassamee. 2022. Household consumption expenditure in Thailand during the first COVID-19 lockdown. Asia-Pacific Sustainable Development Journal 28: 1–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hean, Oudom, and Nanxin Deng. Forthcoming. The effects of minimum wages over the business cycle: The Great Recession. International Journal of Manpower. [CrossRef]
- Hean, Oudom, and Nattanicha Chairassamee. Forthcoming. The effects of COVID-19 on labor force nonparticipation in the short run: Racial and ethnic disparities. Review of Social Economy. [CrossRef]
- Hirschman, Albert. 1960. The Strategy of Economic Development. New Haven: Yale University Press, vol. 40. [Google Scholar]
- Hoselitz, Bert. 1955. Generative and parasitic cities. Economic Development and Cultural Change 3: 278–94. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jaffe, Adam. 1986. Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: Evidence from firms’ patents, profits and market value. American Economics Review 76: 431–37. [Google Scholar]
- Jaffe, Adam, Manuel Trajtenberg, and Rebecca Henderson. 1993. Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 108: 577–98. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jones, Charles. 1995a. R&D-based models of economic growth. Journal of Political Economy 103: 759–84. [Google Scholar]
- Jones, Charles. 1995b. Time series tests of endogenous growth models. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 495–525. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Jones, Charles. 2005. Growth and ideas. In Handbook of Economic Growth. Edited by P. Aghion and S. Durlauf. Amsterdam: Elsevier, vol. 1, pp. 1063–111. [Google Scholar]
- Kortum, Samuel. 1997. Research, patenting, and technological change. Econometrica 64: 1389–419. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Kourtit, Karima, Bruce Newbold, Peter Nijkamp, Mark Partridge, and Oudom Hean. 2021. Geography of migration: An Introduction. In The Economic Geography of Cross-Border Migration. Edited by Karima Kourtit, Bruce Newbold, Peter Nijkamp and Mark Partridge. Footprints of Regional Science. Cham: Springer. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Lobao, Linda, Mark Partridge, Oudom Hean, Kelly Paige, Seung-Hun Chung, and Elizabeth Ruppert Bulmer. 2021. Socioeconomic Transition in the Appalachia coal Region: Some Factors of Success (English); Washington, DC: World Bank Group. Available online: https://documents.worldbank.org/en/publication/documents-reports/documentdetail/531201635134585522/socioeconomic-transition-in-the-appalachia-coal-region-some-factors-of-success (accessed on 15 July 2022).
- Myrdal, Gunnar. 1957. Rich Lands and Poor: The Road to World Prosperity. New York: Harper, vol. 16. [Google Scholar]
- Partridge, Mark, Dan Rickman, Kamar Ali, and Margaret Rose Olfert. 2008. Employment growth in the American urban hierarchy: Long live distance. The BE Journal of Macroeconomics 8: 1–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Partridge, Mark, Dan Rickman, Kamar Ali, and Margaret Rose Olfert. 2009. Agglomeration spillovers and wage and housing cost gradients across the urban hierarchy. Journal of International Economics 78: 126–40. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Roback, Jennifer. 1982. Wages, rents, and the quality of life. Journal of Political Economy 90: 1257–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Romer, Paul. 1990. Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy 98: S71–S102. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Sarkar, Jayati. 1998. Technological diffusion: Alternative theories and historical evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys 12: 131–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Segerstrom, Paul. 1998. Endogenous growth without scale effects. American Economic Review 88: 1290–310. [Google Scholar]
- Simpson, Nicole. 2022. Demographic and Economic Determinants of Migration: Push and Pull Factors Drive the Decision to Stay or Move. Bonn: IZA World of Labor. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2022 by the author. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Hean, O. The Effects of Technological Progress in Innovative Regions on the Labor Markets of Lagging Regions: A Theoretical Perspective. Economies 2022, 10, 197. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080197
Hean O. The Effects of Technological Progress in Innovative Regions on the Labor Markets of Lagging Regions: A Theoretical Perspective. Economies. 2022; 10(8):197. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080197
Chicago/Turabian StyleHean, Oudom. 2022. "The Effects of Technological Progress in Innovative Regions on the Labor Markets of Lagging Regions: A Theoretical Perspective" Economies 10, no. 8: 197. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080197
APA StyleHean, O. (2022). The Effects of Technological Progress in Innovative Regions on the Labor Markets of Lagging Regions: A Theoretical Perspective. Economies, 10(8), 197. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies10080197