4.1. Countries with Expenditure Rules
Canada (1998–2005) has temporarily used an expenditure rule in its debt repayment plan. Although there was a ‘balanced budget or better’ policy, it was not enacted into federal law. In Georgia, an expenditure rule was temporarily introduced between 2014 and 2018. In Hungary, a rule limiting the variation of public expenditure was temporarily introduced in 2010–2011. In Iceland, an expenditure rule was temporarily introduced between 2004 and 2008, but it was politically abandoned afterward. In Japan, expenditure rules were temporarily introduced between 2006 and 2008, 2010 and 2012, and 2015 and 2018; but the economic situation did not make them sustainable. Between 2006 and 2008, a temporary expenditure rule was implemented in Kosovo; however, it was not followed and, as of 2009, it was only formally applicable to municipalities. In Romania, an expenditure rule (both in terms of the variation and absolute level) was temporarily introduced between 2010 and 2012, and in Serbia, such a rule was introduced between 2016 and 2018; however, they were very short-lived. In Thailand (2018–), the expenditure rule defines the minimal amount of capital expenditure. In the United Kingdom (2014–2019), a ceiling was temporarily imposed on a subset of welfare spending; but due to this limited scope, it cannot be considered a fiscal rule. In Azerbaijan, an expenditure rule has only existed since 2019, in Costa Rica since 2020, and in Uruguay since 2021. Therefore, we will not consider these countries in the database of our empirical results in the current section.
Some countries have national rules both in terms of the variation and absolute level of public expenditure. For example, in Denmark (2007–), in 2007–2008, in addition to a target on public consumption as a percentage of the cyclically adjusted GDP, a target was set for real growth in public consumption. Between 2009 and 2014, the target was to reduce the share of public consumption in the cyclically adjusted GDP to 26.5% in 2015. Additionally, in 2012, a new fiscal rule suggested that the increase in real public spending could not surpass the potential GDP growth. The Budget Act, which went into effect in 2014, also established legally mandated caps on expenditures for the central government, local governments, and regions, covering a continuous four-year period. Since 2014, Latvia (2012–)’s Fiscal Discipline Law has determined that public spending, excluding the GDP deflator (inflation), cannot rise more quickly than the average potential GDP growth. An expenditure ceiling is also fixed in the Medium Term Budget Framework Law for the next three years as an operational tool for the preparing the Budget Law. A political commitment to a ceiling on the expenditure-to-GDP ratio was temporarily applied in Bulgaria between 2006 and 2009. Since 2012, Bulgaria (2012–) has also combined the two types of expenditure rules. The expenditure-to-GDP ratio should not exceed 40%, whereas the annual expenditure growth should not exceed the potential GDP growth. As members of the European Union, Denmark, Latvia, and Bulgaria must also verify the constraint of the Six Pack limiting public expenditure variation since 2012.
Outside the EU, Armenia has also a national fiscal rule both in terms of the variation and absolute level of public expenditure. Indeed, in 2018, Armenia (2018–) introduced expenditure ceilings to manage the public debt. If the government debt is more than 40% of the GDP, then recurrent spending cannot be higher than the revenue. Furthermore, if the public debt surpasses 50% of the GDP, the government must set a ceiling on the potential increase in recurrent expenditures.
Some European countries have national rules in terms of an absolute level of public expenditure. However, as members of the European Union, since 2012, they must also verify the constraint of the Six Pack in terms of the variation of public expenditure. In Finland (2003–), for the four years that the government is in office, the rule establishes annual spending caps. Real limits are imposed on primary non-cyclical spending (about 75% of all central government spending). In Greece (2011–), spending ceilings exist for line ministries. In Luxembourg (2014–), since July 2014, the multi-annual financial programming law includes for each fiscal year a maximum amount of expenditure for the central government. In the Netherlands (1994–), real expenditure ceilings are set for both total (roughly 90% of general government spending) and sectoral spending for each year of the government’s four-year office term. The scope of the coverage was altered in 2007, 2009, and 2010. In Sweden (1997–), nominal expenditure ceilings are set for three years for the central government and pension system, with an annual addition to the outer year; interest expenses are not included.
Some countries have national rules in terms of the variation of public expenditure. In Andorra (2014–), the general government’s growth of current primary spending (wages and salaries, goods and services, and current transfers) must remain below the nominal GDP growth if it is positive, or must be zero otherwise. In Argentina (2000–2008; 2018–2019), the primary expenditure should not grow faster than the nominal GDP or, at most, should remain constant during periods of negative nominal GDP growth. However, the rule was never observed, and it was suspended in because of the financial crisis between 2009 and 2017. Since 2018, primary current expenditure cannot grow more than inflation; but the rule was suspended in 2020 and 2021 with the COVID crisis. In Australia (2009–), in case of a budget deficit, once the economy recovered to grow above trend, the annual real growth rate of public expenditure must not exceed 2%, until reaching budget surpluses of at least 1% of the GDP. In Colombia (2000–), a fiscal rule limited the central government’s current expenditure growth, but it was suspended in 2020 because of the pandemic. In Grenada (2015–), the central government’s and covered parastatal entities’ real primary spending growth is limited to 2% annually. In Israel (2005–), the central government’s real spending was limited to 1.7% in 2007. Afterward, the rule was relaxed to allow a real growth of public expenditure of 3% in 2009 or 2.6% in 2011. In 2014, the method of calculation of the real public expenditure growth rate was complicated, taking into account the level of the public debt.
In Mexico (2014–), structural current spending, defined as the current primary expenditure, which includes capital transfers to state and local governments but does not include spending subject to automatic regulations (such as pensions, subsidies for electricity, and sub-national revenue-sharing), is limited by a cap. The latter, initially set at 2%, depends on the potential output growth (average of past and projected growth rates). In Mongolia (2013–), the expenditure growth cannot be above the non-mineral GDP growth. In Paraguay (2015–), primary spending real growth is capped at 4% annually. In Peru (2000–), a ceiling was put on the real growth of the current expenditure: 2% (2000–2002), 3% (2003–2008), or 4% after 2009. Since 2013, new expenditure ceilings were introduced on the general government’s real (non-interest and current) spending. The ceiling was established by referencing a moving average of annual real GDP growth centered between −15 and +5. In these two last countries, the rules were suspended because of the COVID-19 health crisis.
Some countries have both national and supranational rules limiting the variation of public expenditure, as they are members of the European Union. In Belgium (1993–1998), between 1993 and 1998, the central government’s real growth in primary expenditures should be below or equal to 0%. Following a successful budgetary consolidation in a period of relatively high economic growth, once the rule was perceived as having fulfilled its purpose, it was abandoned in 1998. In Denmark (1994–2006), between 1994 and 2001, real public consumption growth was capped at 0.5% of the GDP; it was capped at 1% between 2002 and 2006. In Croatia (2012–), in 2012, the temporary rule stipulated that general government spending must be reduced by 1% of the GDP annually until, at the very least, a nominal primary balance of zero was reached. Since 2014, real growth in public spending cannot surpass potential GDP growth; this national regulation is comparable to the European Six Pack benchmark. In France (1998–), the stricter provision applies between the target for the increase in real public expenditure and the target for nominal expenditure growth, excluding interest payments and pensions. In Germany (1982–2009), expenditures could not grow faster on average than revenue (1% annually on average until 2008) for central and regional governments. This rule was replaced in 2009 by the ‘debt brake’, limiting structural deficits to 0.35% of the GDP for the federal government.
In Lithuania (2008–), if the general government budgets saw an average deficit over the previous five years, the annual growth of budget appropriations could not exceed half of the average growth rate of budget revenue during that time. This rule was revised in 2015 as follows. If the general government budgets have, on average, shown a deficit over the previous five years, the annual growth rate in percentage of total spending of the state budget, social insurance fund, and health insurance may not exceed half (0.5 times) the average multiannual growth rate of the potential GDP. In Luxembourg (1990–2013), public expenditure growth should remain compatible with quantified medium-term economic growth prospects. New measures were enacted in 2014 (see above). In Poland (2011–), the global increase in central government real discretionary spending and in all newly enacted spending could not exceed 1%. Since 2015, the trajectory of government spending has been determined by long-term GDP growth (or, in the event that the deficit or debt exceed predetermined thresholds, below trend GDP growth). National expenditure rules were put on hold during the pandemic and then changed in 2020. In Spain (2011–), nominal expenditure growth for central and local governments shall not surpass the growth of the nominal medium-term GDP; interest and non-discretional spending on unemployment benefits are excluded from the calculation.
Since 2012, as members of the European Economic and Monetary Union, Austria, Cyprus, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Malta, Portugal, Romania, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, and the United Kingdom (until 2020) are concerned by the supranational fiscal rule of the Six Pack, limiting the variation of public expenditure. When subtracting revenue discretionary increases and excluding unemployment benefits, the annual growth of primary expenditure should not surpass the nominal GDP growth over the long run. This benchmark only applies when a nation is not in an excessive deficit procedure, and it is used to determine whether a nation has made sufficient progress toward the medium-term goal of a structural budget that is in balance.
Finally, some countries have fiscal rules constraining the absolute level of public expenditure. In Botswana (2003–), the government has set expenditure limits since 2006, capping government spending at 40% of the GDP, and introducing the goal to reduce government spending to 30% of GDP by the end of the 2015–2016 fiscal year. In Brazil (2000–), the cap on personnel expenses is 50% of the net current revenue for the federal government; for states and municipalities, it is 60%. The 2016 rule amendment places restrictions on the federal government’s real primary spending and indicates that nominal spending may increase starting in 2016 following inflation. In Ecuador (2010–), even though both are ill-defined, the permanent expenditures cannot exceed the permanent revenue. The rule was revised in 2020; the Ministry of Finance is responsible for defining annual nominal limits for the increase in eligible primary expenditures for the central government. In Namibia (2010–), the cap on government spending was set at 30% of the GDP before being revised to less than 33% of GDP in response to the COVID-19 crisis.
In Russia (2013–), there is an oil-price-based fiscal rule. The rule sets a ceiling on expenditures using oil revenue at the ‘base’ oil price. The rule was revised in 2017 to integrate a tougher definition of unstable revenues, and it was temporarily suspended because of the COVID-19 crisis. In Singapore (1991–), according to the expenditure rule, the annual budget for spending may include up to 50% of net investment income from the Monetary Authority of Singapore, the Government of Singapore Investment Corporation, and Temasek. The rule was changed in 2008 to take ‘expected long-term net real investment returns’ into consideration as a benchmark. In Tanzania (2015–), the Oil and Gas Revenue Management Act requires the government to maintain current spending at a constant percentage of the GDP, and it sets a ceiling on government spending at 40% of the GDP. In the United States (1990–2002 and 2011–), between 1990 and 2002, annual appropriations limits were put on discretionary spending. However, the rule was abandoned when the economic boom suggested that an increasing amount of spending was occurring outside of the ceiling through an emergency spending category. Since 2011, discretionary spending caps have been adopted and are associated with additional spending cuts (‘sequester’). In Vietnam (2016–), development investment should account for 25% (28% since the revision in 2021) of the total expenditure, and recurrent expenditure should be under 64% (62% in 2021) of the total expenditure.
4.2. Expenditure Rules and Fiscal Discipline
Our database comes from OECD and IMF statistics. Our goal is to compare the situation of countries having various expenditure rules with the average situation in OECD countries for a given year.
Cordes et al. (
2015) and
Ayuso-i-Casals (
2012) underline that according to econometric studies, countries with expenditure rules typically have higher primary balances; they seem effective at controlling politically motivated spending pressures. According to empirical observations extracted from our database, are expenditure rules efficient at ensuring fiscal discipline? Mainly, regarding the goal of our paper, what is the relative efficiency of fiscal rules in terms of the variation or level of public expenditure to ensure this fiscal discipline?
According to our database, budget surpluses are higher (or budget deficits are weaker) by about 2.5 percentage points of the GDP in countries with an expenditure rule in comparison with average OECD values; but the R
2 values are very weak. Additionally, this relationship can be biased, as countries that have a strong commitment to fiscal discipline and restrictive expenditure rules may be more likely to have a weaker budget deficit. However,
Figure 1 shows that a rule in terms of level of public expenditure reduces the budget deficit more than a rule in terms of variation. Furthermore, having both rules would still be more efficient, as the budget deficit would then be weaker (or the budget surplus higher), and the relation would be more significant.
Regarding fiscal discipline, we can also study if there is an empirical link between fiscal rules and the public debt-to-GDP ratio. Indeed, the extent to which governments are compelled to meet their expenditure targets by fiscal surveillance and the financial markets may be influenced by this ratio. Then, an expenditure rule seems to imply a smaller increase (or a stronger reduction) in the public debt-to-GDP ratio in comparison with its average increase (reduction) in OECD countries (see
Figure 2). Indeed, an expenditure rule can improve fiscal discipline: the public debt decreases on average by 3.9 percentage points of the GDP more than in average OECD countries. Additionally, the public debt would be slightly more reduced with a rule in terms of the level (and the relation is more significant) than with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure (see
Figure 2).
Therefore, an expenditure rule, in particular in terms of the level of public expenditure, could improve fiscal discipline. Empirically, the relationship between the share of public expenditure in GDP and the fiscal balance (or the variation of the public debt) is very weak. Nevertheless, according to analytical results in
Section 3, we can study whether the public expenditure-to-GDP ratio could influence the most appropriate fiscal rule.
Then, in conformity with the results in
Section 3, we find that in countries with a weak public expenditure-to-GDP ratio, a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure would better improve fiscal discipline. Indeed, such a rule would allow the budget deficit to be reduced (or the budget surplus to increase) by 2.63 percentage points of GDP more than in other OECD countries, whereas differences with other OECD countries are not significant (the R
2 is too weak) with a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure (see
Appendix B). For example, in 2019, the average budget deficit was 3.18% of the GDP in OECD countries, whereas budget surpluses were 0.12% of the GDP in Estonia, 0.48% in Ireland, 0.49% in Lithuania, 1% in Mongolia, and 5% of the GDP in Grenada. In the same way, a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure could allow the public debt to decrease (or to increase by a weaker amount) by 4.77 percentage points of the GDP more than in other OECD countries. On the contrary, with a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure, the public debt could only decrease by 2.63 percentage points of the GDP more than in other OECD countries, whereas the decrease was not really significant when both types of expenditure rules were present (see
Appendix B). For example, in 2019, in OECD countries, public debts decreased on average by 0.27 percentage points of the GDP, whereas the public debts decreased by 1.18 percentage points of the GDP in Colombia, 6.01 in Ireland, and 9.70 in Mongolia.
Also in conformity with the results in
Section 3, in countries with a high share of public expenditure in GDP, a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure would better improve fiscal discipline. Indeed, such a rule would allow the budget deficit to be reduced (or the budget surplus to increase) by 5.66 percentage points of the GDP more than in other OECD countries, whereas it was only reduced by 2.81 when both rules were present and by 1.41 percentage points of the GDP more than in other OECD countries with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure (see
Appendix B). For example, in 2011, the average budget deficit was 6.86% of the GDP in OECD countries, whereas it was only 0.36% in Sweden and 1.02% of the GDP in Finland (rule for the level). In the same way, a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure could allow the public debt to decrease (or to increase by a weaker amount) by 5.82 percentage points of the GDP more than in other OECD countries. On the contrary, the public debt could only decrease by 4.69 points with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure, and by 4.07 percentage points of the GDP more than in other OECD countries when both types of expenditure rules were present (see
Appendix B). For example, in 2019, in OECD countries, public debts decreased on average by 0.27 percentage points of the GDP, whereas the public debts only decreased by 0.36 in France and 0.29 percentage points of the GDP in Italy (rule for the variation).
4.3. Expenditure Rules and Economic Activity
This section analyzes, according to empirical observations, whether expenditure rules are harmful to sustaining a high level of economic activity. Mainly, what is the relative efficiency of fiscal rules in terms of the variation or level of public expenditure to sustain economic activity?
According to our database, economic activity growth is higher by about 0.84 percentage points in countries with an expenditure rule in comparison with average OECD values. However,
Figure 3 shows that a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure could increase economic activity by 1.52 percentage points, whereas a rule in terms of the variation could only increase economic activity by 0.71 percentage points. This can be explained by the fact that preserving fiscal margins by sound fiscal policies when economic activity is sufficiently high can allow automatic stabilizers to be afterward more efficient in sustaining economic activity in a recessionary framework. However, having both kinds of expenditure rules could be detrimental, as economic activity would then be weaker by 0.28 percentage points. Indeed, strongly constraining public consumption has always recessionary consequences because of the fiscal multiplier, even if the latter is weaker in open economies.
Therefore, an expenditure rule, in particular in terms of the level of public expenditure, could improve economic activity. Additionally, empirically, we find that a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure is more appropriate to sustain economic activity, especially when the share of public expenditure in GDP is weak (see
Appendix C). Indeed, when the public expenditure-to-GDP ratio is weak, this rule would allow economic activity to increase by 2.31 percentage points in comparison with other OECD countries. On the contrary, economic activity would only increase by 1.54 percentage points with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure, whereas the relation is not significant with both types of expenditure rules. In the same way, when the public expenditure-to-GDP ratio is high, a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure would increase economic activity by 1.23 percentage points in comparison with other OECD countries. On the contrary, economic activity would decrease by 0.5 percentage points with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure, and even by 0.94 percentage points when both types of expenditure rules are present (see
Appendix C).
For example, in 2019, the average economic growth was 1.7% in OECD countries, whereas economic growth rates were 3% in Botswana and even 5.8% in Tanzania and 7.4% in Vietnam, where the public expenditure-to-GDP ratio was weak and with a rule in terms of the level of public expenditure. In countries with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure and a weak public expenditure-to-GDP ratio, economic growth was high in Estonia (3.7%), Romania (3.9%), Lithuania (4.7%), Ireland (5.3%) and Mongolia (5.6%), but was weak in Argentina (−2%), Paraguay (−0.4%), Australia, and Mexico (−0.3%). Finally, economic growth was weak in countries with a high share of public expenditure in GDP, and with a rule in terms of the variation of public expenditure such as Italy (0.5%), or with both types of public expenditure rules such as Denmark (1.5%) or Finland (1.2%).
For all countries, whether they have fiscal rules or not, empirical data show a decreasing relation between the share of public expenditure in GDP and real economic activity (see
Figure 4). For example, the share of public expenditure in GDP is particularly high (already above 50% of the GDP in 2019) in Belgium, Finland or France, whereas economic growth is mainly weaker than in other countries. On the contrary, the share of public expenditure in GDP is particularly weak (below 30% of the GDP) in Ireland, India, Paraguay or Peru, whereas economic growth is usually higher than in other countries.
Moreover, we can study whether this influence of the share of public expenditure in GDP on economic activity is also influenced by the existence and the nature of a potential fiscal rule. Then, the empirical data show that the share of public expenditure in GDP is detrimental to economic growth whatever the existing public expenditure rule. However, it would be less detrimental for countries with limits on the level of public expenditure, and much more detrimental for countries with both types of fiscal rules in terms of the level and also of variation of public expenditure (see
Figure A7 in
Appendix C).