Private Property Rights, Dynamic Efficiency and Economic Development: An Austrian Reply to Neo-Marxist Scholars Nieto and Mateo on Cyber-Communism and Market Process
Abstract
:1. Introduction
2. Theoretical Framework and Methodology
2.1. Entrepreneurship: The Driving Force of the Market Economy
2.2. The Theory of Dynamic Efficiency
2.3. Private Property Rights
2.4. Economic Calculation and Socialism’s Impossibility
2.5. The Austrian Theory of Economic Development
3. Review, Assessment, and Discussion
3.1. The Case of Cyber-Communism
3.2. The Impossibility of Cyber-Communism: A Property Rights Approach
4. Challenge Key Points
5. Conclusions
Author Contributions
Funding
Institutional Review Board Statement
Informed Consent Statement
Data Availability Statement
Acknowledgments
Conflicts of Interest
1. | Following Cockshott and Cottrell (1997), any complex social system with a developed division of labor needs to compute what it costs to produce the material conditions in terms of the key resource available to individuals: labor time. In capitalist economies, accounting occurs spontaneously through money, voluntary exchanges, and competitive market price formation. In contrast, communism replaces the calculation of market prices with labor time: (i) labor as a measure of costs, and (ii) a remuneration system in job bonds (as certificates that indicate the hours of labor that a worker has contributed to the communist production system) to replace the capitalist wage system. In communism, the cost of the different goods must be calculated according to the amount of labor time (vertically integrated labor) required in each case. A part of the total produced by a worker would go to a community fund, and the rest would be a job bond to exchange for consumer goods. It requires an advanced information technology system and an input-output table that solves matrix algebra problems in real-time. |
2. | The fundamental difference between human action and the entities of nature is the category of purpose. Following Menger’s ([1871] 1976) subjective theory of value: If individual judges a good as useful to achieve his end, there must be a human need, an object that satisfies it, and the subjective knowledge that this object exists or could exist. The same physical good can be useful one moment and useless another. Therefore, utility and scarcity are subjective elements depending on the action plans. |
3. | The law of price of productive factors explains the inconsistency of the Marxist theory of labor exploitation (Boettke and Candela 2017). First, there is no exploitation in a private property-based society because individual relationships are contractual. Second, the entrepreneur cannot pay the undiscounted value of marginal productivity today because the production outcomes will be prolonged in the future (for example, at the close of the accounting year). Third, suppose workers do not want to work for someone else. In that case, they provide services to another person, company or institution in exchange for a salary or remuneration—and are paid in advance the value discounted by the market interest rate, they can choose to work for their account (self-employed entrepreneurs), or through cooperatives (worker associations). The opposite occurs in a no-private property-based society, where the governing body coercively imposes the determination of prices, wages, and occupations. |
4. | Whoever questions the existence of the economy denies that the well-being of individuals is affected by scarcity. A world without scarcity implies that individuals could enjoy the absolute satisfaction of all their desires. This assertion corresponds to the myth of perfect abundance proclaimed by Marxist and Keynesian doctrines, where abundance will be inevitable and it will be feasible to give “to each according to his needs” (Caldwell 1997). However, the doctrines are alien to elementary empirical evidence. Human beings act because they are not omniscient, omnipotent, or omnipresent: they do not have the power to make conditions completely satisfactory. |
References
- Acemoglu, Daron, and James A. Robinson. 2019. Rents and Economic Development: The Perspective of Why Nations Fail. Public Choice 181: 13–28. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Acemoglu, Daron, Suresh Naidu, Pascual Restrepo, and James A. Robinson. 2019. Democracy does cause growth. Journal of Political Economy 127: 47–100. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Adaman, Fikret, and Pat Devine. 1996. The Economics Calculation Debate: Lessons for Socialists. Cambridge Journal of Economics 20: 523–37. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Adaman, Fikret, and Pat Devine. 2002. A Reconsideration of the Theory of Entrepreneurship: A Participatory Approach. Review of Political Economy 14: 329–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Arnaert, Brecht L. 2018. Talking to Walls: The Socialist Calculation Debate that Never Really was One. Procesos de Mercado 15: 339–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Baumol, William J. 1990. Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive. Journal of Political Economy 98: 893–921. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Boettke, Peter J. 2000. Socialism and the Market: The Socialist Calculation Debate Revisited. London and New York: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
- Boettke, Peter J. 2019. How Misesian Was the Hayekian Research Program? Procesos de Mercado 16: 251–57. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boettke, Peter J. 2020. Property, Predation and Socialist Reality. Journal of Institutional Economics 16: 185–97. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Boettke, Peter J., and Rosolino A. Candela. 2014. Development and Property Rights. In Encyclopedia on Law and Economics. Edited by Alain Marciano and Giovanni B. Ramello. New York: Springer, pp. 1–9. [Google Scholar]
- Boettke, Peter J., and Rosolino A. Candela. 2017. Price Theory as Prophylactic Against Popular Fallacies. Journal of Institutional Economics 13: 725–52. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bylund, Per L., and G. P. Manish. 2017. Private Property and Economic Calculation: A Reply to Andy Denis. Review of Political Economy 29: 414–31. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Bylund, Per L., and Mark D. Packard. 2021. Subjective value in entrepreneurship. Small Business Economics, 1–18. [Google Scholar]
- Caldwell, Bruce J. 1997. Hayek and Socialism. Journal of Economic Literature 35: 1856–90. [Google Scholar]
- Cockshott, W. Paul. 2017. Big Data and Supercomputers: Foundations of Cyber Communism. Glasgow: University of Glasgow. [Google Scholar]
- Cockshott, W. Paul, and Allin F. Cottrell. 1997. Labour Time versus Alternative Value Bases: A Research Note. Cambridge Journal of Economics 21: 545–49. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cockshott, W. Paul, and Maxi Nieto. 2017. Ciber-Comunismo: Planificación Económica, Computadoras y Democracia. Trotta: Madrid. [Google Scholar]
- Cottrell, Allin, and W. Paul Cockshott. 1993. Calculation, Complexity and Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Once Again. Review of Political Economy 5: 73–112. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Cottrell, Allin, and W. Paul Cockshott. 2008. Computadores y Democracia Económica. Revista de Economía Institucional 10: 161–205. [Google Scholar]
- Ebeling, Richard M. 2015. F. A. Hayek and Why Government can’t Manage Society. Procesos de Mercado 12: 343–59. [Google Scholar]
- Endres, Anthony M., and David A. Harper. 2020. Economic Development and Complexity: The Role of Recombinant Capital. Cambridge Journal of Economics 44: 157–80. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Espinosa, Victor I. 2020. Epistemological Problems of Development Economics. Procesos de Mercado 17: 55–93. [Google Scholar]
- Espinosa, Victor I. 2021a. Salvador Allende’s Development Policy: Lessons after 50 Years. Economic Affairs 41: 96–110. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Espinosa, Víctor I. 2021b. Ciberplanificación, Propiedad Privada y Cálculo Económico. Revista de Economía Institucional 23: 163–84. [Google Scholar]
- Espinosa, Victor I. 2022. Principios Modernos de Economía del Desarrollo: Teoría y Práctica. Madrid: Unión Editorial, in press. [Google Scholar]
- Espinosa, Victor I., and Óscar R. Carreiro. 2021. Old and New Development Economics: A Reassessment of Objectives. Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 24: 254–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Espinosa, Victor I., William H. Wang, and Haijiu Zhu. 2020. Israel Kirzner on Dynamic Efficiency and Economic Development. Procesos de Mercado 17: 283–310. [Google Scholar]
- Espinosa, Victor I., José Antonio Peña-Ramos, and Fátima Recuero-López. 2021a. The Political Economy of Rent-seeking: Evidence from Spain’s Support Policies for Renewable Energy. Energies 14: 4197. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Espinosa, Victor I., Miguel A. Alonso Neira, and Jesús Huerta de Soto. 2021b. Principles of Sustainable Economic Growth and Development: A Call to Action in a Post-COVID-19 World. Sustainability. in press. [Google Scholar]
- Foss, Nicolai J., and Peter G. Klein. 2012. Organizing Entrepreneurial Judgment: A New Approach to the Firm. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Hayek, Friedrich A. 1935. Collectivist Economic Planning. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. [Google Scholar]
- Hayek, Friedrich A. 1944. The Road to Serfdom. London and New York: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
- Hayek, Friedrich A. 1945. The Use of Knowledge in Society. American Economic Review 35: 519–30. [Google Scholar]
- Hayek, Friedrich A. 1988. The Fatal Conceit: The Errors of Socialism. In The Collected Works of Friedrich August Hayek. Edited by W. W. Bartley II. London and New York: Routledge, vol. I. [Google Scholar]
- Holcombe, Randall G. 2021. Entrepreneurial Economies. Economies 9: 123. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Hoppe, Hans-Hermann. 1989. A Theory of Capitalism and Socialism. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. [Google Scholar]
- Hoppe, Hans-Hermann. 1993. Economics and Ethics of Private Property. Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. [Google Scholar]
- Hoppe, Hans-Hermann. 1995. Economic Science and the Austrian Method. Auburn: The Mises Institute Press. [Google Scholar]
- Huerta de Soto, Jesús. 2009. The Theory of Dynamic Efficiency. London and New York: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
- Huerta de Soto, Jesús. 2010. Socialism, Economic Calculation and Entrepreneurship. Cheltenham and Northampton: Edward Elgar. [Google Scholar]
- Ikeda, Sanford. 2015. Dynamics of Interventionism. In Oxford Handbook of Austrian Economics. Edited by Peter J. Boettke and Christopher J. Coyne. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 393–416. [Google Scholar]
- Kirzner, Israel M. 2000. The Driving Force of the Market: Essays in Austrian Economics. London and New York: Routledge. [Google Scholar]
- Kirzner, Israel M. 2017. The Entrepreneurial Market Process: An Exposition. Southern Economic Journal 83: 855–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Klein, Peter G. 2010. The Capitalist & the Entrepreneur. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute. [Google Scholar]
- Lange, Oskar. 1965. Problems of Political Economy of Socialism. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House. [Google Scholar]
- Lavoie, Don. 1985. Rivalry and Central Planning: The Socialist Calculation Debate Reconsidered. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Lewin, Peter, and Nicolas Cachanosky. 2018. Value and Capital: Austrian Capital Theory, Retrospect and Prospect. Review of Austrian Economics 31: 1–26. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Machlup, Fritz. 1980. Knowledge: Its Creation, Distribution, and Economic Significance, Volume I: Knowledge and Knowledge Production. Princeton: Princeton University Press. [Google Scholar]
- Marx, Karl, and Friedrich Engels. 1976. Manifesto of the Communist Party. In Marx-Engels Collected Works. New York: International Publishers, vol. 6, pp. 477–519. First published 1848. [Google Scholar]
- Menger, C. 1976. Principles of Economics. New York: New York University Press. First published 1871. [Google Scholar]
- Miller, Terry, Anthony B. Kim, and James M. Roberts. 2020. Index of Economic Freedom. Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation. [Google Scholar]
- Mises, Ludwig. 1935. Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth. In Collectivist Economic Planning. Edited by Friedrich August Hayek. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, pp. 87–130. First published 1920. [Google Scholar]
- Mises, Ludwig. 1951. Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. New Haven: Yale University Press. First published 1922. [Google Scholar]
- Mises, Ludwig. 1998. Human Action. A Treatise on Economics. Auburn: Mises Institute. First published 1949. [Google Scholar]
- Mises, Ludwig. 1962. Profit and Loss. In Planning for Freedom and Other Essays and Addresses, 2nd ed. Edited by Ludwig von Mises. South Holland: Libertarian Press, pp. 108–50. [Google Scholar]
- Nieto, Maxi. 2020. Is Economic Calculation Impossible in Socialism? Criticism of the New Austrian Reading. Revista de Economía Institucional 22: 127–51. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Nieto, Maxi, and Juan P. Mateo. 2020. Dynamic Efficiency in a Planned Economy: Innovation and Entrepreneurship without Markets. Science & Society 84: 42–66. [Google Scholar]
- O’Neill, John. 1996. Who Won the Socialist Calculation Debate? History of Political Thought 17: 431–42. [Google Scholar]
- Phillips, Leigh, and Michal Rozworski. 2019. The People’s Republic of Wal-Mart: How the World’s Biggest Corporations Are Laying the Foundation for Socialism. Verso: New York. [Google Scholar]
- Piano, Ennio E., and Louis Rouanet. 2020. Economic Calculation and the Organization of Markets. Review of Austrian Economics 33: 331–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Redford, Audrey. 2020. Property Rights, Entrepreneurship, and Economic Development. Review of Austrian Economics 33: 139–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Rothbard, Murray N. 1951. Praxeology: Reply to Mr. Schuller. American Economic Review 41: 943–46. [Google Scholar]
- Rothbard, Murray N. 1977. Power and Market: Government and the Economy. Kansas City: Sheed Andrews and McMeel. First published 1970. [Google Scholar]
- Rothbard, Murray N. 2002. For a New Liberty: The Libertarian Manifesto. Auburn: The Mises Institute Press. First published 1973. [Google Scholar]
- Rothbard, Murray N. 1991. The End of Socialism and the Calculation Debate Revisited. Review of Austrian Economics 5: 51–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- Selgin, George A. 1988. Praxeology and Understanding: An Analysis of the Controversy in Austrian Economics. Review of Austrian Economics 2: 19–58. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
- Transparency International. 2020. Corruption Perceptions Index. Berlin: Transparency International Group. [Google Scholar]
- Wang, William Hongsong. 2017. Jesús Huerta de Soto: The Synthesizer of the Austrian School. Procesos de Mercado 14: 173–202. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
- World Bank. 2020. Doing Business 2020. Washington: World Bank Group. [Google Scholar]
Key Points | Cyber-Communist Criteria | Austrian Criteria |
---|---|---|
Circular reasoning in the Austrian theory of socialism | The Austrians say that “dynamic efficiency requires the free exercise of the entrepreneurship and the market, given that said efficiency is defined as that same entrepreneurship and market” (Nieto and Mateo 2020, p. 42). | “The dynamic efficiency theory, based on methodological individualism, is not circular reasoning. It is a construction of verbal chains of logic, from the essence—entrepreneurship as the innate ability of individuals to identify and solve human problems—to institutional analysis: a theory of voluntary (market) or coercive (socialism) exchanges. For this reason, Nieto and Mateo’s criticism about circular reasoning only makes sense in Marxist holism, disregarding the logical and deductive analysis of a priori theoretical knowledge: the category of human action as the pivotal element of all economic science” (Espinosa 2021b, p. 175). |
The feasibility of economic development in labor time through modern computing | Without private property rights, the economic calculation would be in labor time “through mathematical optimization for efficient allocation, based on modern information and communication... One fundamental instrument to this end would be the construction of an input-output super-matrix that brings together all sectoral and business interdependencies in the national economy” (Nieto and Mateo 2020, p. 52). | “The Marxist theory of labor value suggests that the value of things arises from their labor time. However, the modern theory of value explains that what human beings consider valuable is subjective, that is, they value goods depending on how they satisfy their subjective preferences according to their action plans. Regardless of modern computing, once the inherently subjective and speculative nature of all resource allocation is recognized, private property in the means of production emerges as the necessary institutional prerequisite to facilitate economic calculation. Without it, there can be no speculation tempered by the threat of suffering losses. […] Such a socialist economy does not support a discovery process for identifying how best to satisfy consumers, and thus the prices cannot approximate the social opportunity cost involved in resource allocation—they are arbitrary” (Bylund and Manish 2017, pp. 416, 428). |
The feasibility of cyber-communist entrepreneurship | “In socialism, ownership and management are separate: the community is the principal and, represented by a planning authority, it provides the resources that companies must manage efficiently through democratically elected management personnel” (Nieto and Mateo 2020, p. 57). | “[The socialist governing body] may employ workers, managers, technicians, inventors, and the like, but it cannot, by definition, employ entrepreneurs, because there are no money profits and losses. Entrepreneurship, and not labor or management or technological expertise, is the crucial element of the market economy. As Mises puts it: Managers of socialist enterprises may be allowed to “play market”, to act as if they were managers of private firms with their own interests at stake, but entrepreneurs cannot be asked to “play speculation and investment”. In the absence of entrepreneurship, a complex dynamic economy cannot allocate resources to their highest valued use” (Foss and Klein 2012, p. 41). |
Publisher’s Note: MDPI stays neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. |
© 2021 by the authors. Licensee MDPI, Basel, Switzerland. This article is an open access article distributed under the terms and conditions of the Creative Commons Attribution (CC BY) license (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).
Share and Cite
Wang, W.H.; Espinosa, V.I.; Peña-Ramos, J.A. Private Property Rights, Dynamic Efficiency and Economic Development: An Austrian Reply to Neo-Marxist Scholars Nieto and Mateo on Cyber-Communism and Market Process. Economies 2021, 9, 165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9040165
Wang WH, Espinosa VI, Peña-Ramos JA. Private Property Rights, Dynamic Efficiency and Economic Development: An Austrian Reply to Neo-Marxist Scholars Nieto and Mateo on Cyber-Communism and Market Process. Economies. 2021; 9(4):165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9040165
Chicago/Turabian StyleWang, William Hongsong, Victor I. Espinosa, and José Antonio Peña-Ramos. 2021. "Private Property Rights, Dynamic Efficiency and Economic Development: An Austrian Reply to Neo-Marxist Scholars Nieto and Mateo on Cyber-Communism and Market Process" Economies 9, no. 4: 165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9040165
APA StyleWang, W. H., Espinosa, V. I., & Peña-Ramos, J. A. (2021). Private Property Rights, Dynamic Efficiency and Economic Development: An Austrian Reply to Neo-Marxist Scholars Nieto and Mateo on Cyber-Communism and Market Process. Economies, 9(4), 165. https://doi.org/10.3390/economies9040165