Appendix B. Data Appendix
This section describes the U.S. annual data used for model evaluation and estimation. The period covered is 1949 to 2013. The raw data were taken from a variety of sources, which, unless stated otherwise, are the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA), Bureau of Labour Statistics (BLS), Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED), and Energy Information Administration (EIA). We note that all data are seasonally adjusted, in constant prices, per capita terms, and logged, except when stated otherwise. The model and the estimating framework both necessitate compiling a dataset on aggregate measures for the single final output, consumption, investment, labour hours, oil use, exports, and imports. Further, we require observed time-series on the real exchange rate, wages, and interest rates. Besides, we need empirical counterparts for sectoral capital stocks and capital utilisation rates. We note that, as in the model, aggregates of output, investment, labour hours, and oil use are obtained as the sum of their respective sectoral values.
In general, we define data for the energy-intensive sector as containing the following industries: agriculture, mining, utilities, construction, manufacturing, and transportation. Wholesale and retail trade, information, finance, professional and business services, educational services, arts, and other non-government services make up the non-energy-intensive sector. Practical issues faced in constructing the variables on the above-defined grounds imply the need to comment on some of our data definitions. To begin with, in measuring sectoral output, we split the output of the public sector into two due to the lack of sufficient disaggregation of government output and added half each to the summed value-added of the relevant industries for each of energy- and non-energy-intensive sectors.
For the investment series, we combined investment in private fixed assets, equipment, structures, and intellectual property products with the series for consumer durables (both of which are classified by type of product). Then, starting with the consumption of durable goods, we assign into investments that are non-energy-intensive furnishings and durable household equipment, recreational goods and vehicles, and other durable goods. Investment in energy-intensive durable goods is given as the residual. Further, investment in energy-intensive goods is given by the sum of equipment and structures less residential equipment and improvements. We define investment in non-energy-intensive-type goods as the sum of residential equipment, improvements, and intellectual property products.
Hours worked is obtained by following the procedure of Herrendorf et al. [
43], which involves combining GDP-by-Industry data reported using the North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) classification with the Income-and-Employment-by-Industry data reported with three different classifications over the sample period (the Standard Industrial Classification (SIC) from 1949 to 2000 (SIC72 for pre-1987 and SIC87 between 1987 and 2000) and NAICS since 2001). In particular, the former data representations follow the classification we would prefer, while the latter provides the industry-level information we require for assignment into energy- and non-energy-intensive sectors.
Formally, the sectoral labour hours are computed using:
where
HE = number of hours employed,
NE = number of employees,
ft = full-time,
se = self-employed, and
ftpt = full-time part-time.
We take the total energy consumption in the economy to be the aggregate consumption of primary energy. That is, the consumption of fossil fuels comprising petroleum, coal, and natural gas (measured in trillions of British thermal units (BTUs)) in the private sector, excluding the electric power sector. We collectively refer to these fossil fuels as oil. We do not, however, include the consumption of renewables (geothermal, solar/PV, and biomass) and electricity for both theory and data reasons. On the data, if one chooses to use, for instance, total primary energy consumption data, there are no data for biomass consumption until 1981. Moreover, we excluded the electric-power-generating sector, which would have been classed as a highly energy-intensive sector, given that close to 70% of all primary energy is used or lost as this sector provides electricity to the final consumers. We have, however, not included it because we have not modelled an energy-producing sector, which would have to be the case if we had incorporated electricity into our total for energy consumption.
Hence, aggregate energy consumption in the U.S. is formally given by the dollar value of total primary energy use:
where
represents the conversion factor for relating BTUs to barrels of oil.
Oil consumption is provided for four end-use sectors: namely, the industrial, transportation, residential, and commercial sectors. Given a lack of further disaggregation, we use the primary energy consumption in both the industrial and transportation sectors as a proxy for energy use in the energy-intensive sector, and primary energy consumption in both the residential and commercial sectors as a proxy for energy use in the non-energy-intensive sector. Prices of energy- and non-energy-intensive goods are derived based on chain-type price indexes for value-added by industry. For the price of energy-intensive goods, we use the weighted average from agriculture, mining, utilities, construction, manufacturing, and transportation. We utilise the weighted average from wholesale and retail trade, information, finance, professional and business services, educational services, arts, and other non-government services for the price of non-energy-intensive goods.
Following the constructions of energy-intensive and non-energy-intensive investment goods above, we construct the sectoral physical capital stocks. The energy-intensive sector capital stock is the sum of non-residential equipment and structures. The physical capital stock of the non-energy-intensive sector is obtained as the sum of residential equipment and structures, and intellectual property products. Further, non-energy-intensive-type capital stock is taken as the sum of furnishings and durable household equipment, recreational goods and vehicles, and other durable goods, such that capital stock in the energy-intensive-type consumption durable goods is given by motor vehicles and parts. For the energy-intensive sector capital utilisation rate, we use capacity utilisation rate for total manufacturing industry. Meanwhile, capacity utilisation rate for motor vehicles and parts is used to proxy capital utilisation rate in the non-energy-intensive sector.
For wages, we use the real index of hourly compensation. Interest rate is the three-month Treasury bill rate for 1949–1954 ([
41]), where we have converted their quarterly data into annual data by averaging, and we use the federal funds rate for 1955–2013. The real exchange rate is U.S. CPI for all urban consumers relative to ROW CPI. Consumption is measured using personal consumption expenditures, less durable goods.
Appendix C. Calibration
The assessment of the quantitative workings of the model can only begin when we have chosen values for the model parameters, such that we are able to simulate the model. Further, indirect inference estimation that we employ needs starting parameter values. In this section, we discuss how we obtain these values (see
Table A1). We set the Frisch elasticity of labour supply
equal to 5 (A value of zero for
implies perfect labour mobility between sectors. This type of perfect factor mobility is prevalent in the RBC literature especially as it relates to the labour market activities. However, suffice it to say that this is as plausible as, for example, the degree of sector-specific skilled labour that is needed. Hence, as
so does the degree of sector specificity. We are thus inclined to begin the analysis from a more Walrasian context such that we set
closer to 0, fix consumption elasticity
at 2, and preserve the CES form of the production functions by setting the respective sector’s elasticity of substitution between capital services and efficient energy use,
and
, equal to 0.7; Kim and Loungani [
13] (Table 2, p. 180) provide a justification for using this value. They also considered a value of 0.001 suggesting a Cobb–Douglas form and high elasticity of substitution between capital services and energy use. We, however, stick to the parameter value that preserves the general form of specification and leave the optimal choice of parameter value to be decided at the estimation stage later on). Further, we suppose that there is some degree of habit formation h for agents in this model, setting the initial parameter value to 0.7, which is in line with previous estimates in the literature for a developed country such as the U.S. A very small value of 0.001 is chosen for the parameters that relate to the adjustment costs of capital,
and
, following a popular practice in the literature.
Moving on to the component parameters of the two depreciation functions, the steady state implies that
for which we note that only four of their six parameters needed identifying; these are
and
. So, conditional on the values of the discount factor and the real rental rates for capital services in the two sectors, we calibrate the parameters governing the elasticities of marginal depreciations with respect to capital utilisation rates as
. This expression yields 1.463 and 1.694, respectively, for the energy-intensive and non-energy-intensive parameters, which are reasonably located in the range found in the literature (Basu and Kimball [
27] suggested the upper bound of 2 based on a 95% confidence band. Further, to calibrate this parameter, we have gone for the more restricted form of the depreciation function by setting
. Basu and Kimball [
27], though, used the more general form in their empirical work and concluded that there is no statistical evidence in support of the non-zero value for the fixed component of the depreciation function as assumed by many other authors in the literature. See, for example, Greenwood et al. [
44] and Burnside and Eichenbaum [
45]. We observe that our values are not far from those usually employed in the literature. For example, Greenwood et al. used a value of 1.42, while Burnside and Eichenbaum, using their factor-hoarding model and data on output and capital, calibrated μ to be 1.56 (Δ = 0.56). We must note that the specification for time-varying depreciation is less general in these other studies. Statistically, however, both values are not rejected by the data. This is performed noting one of the concerns of Basu and Kimball [
27] that “…our method makes clear that Δ is a parameter that needs to be estimated, and in fact is not pinned down very precisely by the data because it has to be estimated as the reciprocal of a fairly small number. Thus, even the small standard error of the reduced-form parameter necessarily implies that there is large uncertainty about the structural parameter Δ. Consequently, economic modellers should conduct sensitivity analysis of their results using a wide range of values for this parameter.” In addition, “variable depreciation does not seem a significant source of error in the capital stock figures reported by the BEA.” Specifically, they concluded that this issue “strikes us as second-order.” This thus supports our empirical approach because it is essentially aimed at achieving optimal calibration and is also efficient in dealing with errors in the model, irrespective of how they are introduced. So, once we have assessed the performance of the model under this calibration approach, the above arguments make more important our next empirical exercise, which is to estimate the model’s underlying structural parameters). Moreover, with no loss of generality, we fix the values for
at unity, as in Burnside and Eichenbaum [
45], Boileau and Normandin [
46], and Leduc and Sill [
47]. The idea is that
and
are admitted into the model only jointly as
, such that
has a trivial implication that
. Additionally, using household’s optimality conditions with regards to capital utilisation rates conditioned on the values for the respective sector’s rental rate of capital in the steady state, we can show that
. This simplifies to give 0.132 and 0.102 that are reported in
Table A1.
Table A1.
Initial parameter values used to start the simulated annealing algorithm.
Table A1.
Initial parameter values used to start the simulated annealing algorithm.
Parameter | Value | Description |
---|
| 5 | Frisch elasticity of labour supply |
| 2 | Elasticity of substitution in consumption |
| 0.7 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 0.7 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 0.43 | Elasticity of output to labour hours plus 1 in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.28 | Elasticity of output to labour hours plus 1 in the non-energy-intensive sector |
h | 0.7 | Habit formation in consumption |
| 0.132 | Marginal cost of capital utilisation in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.102 | Marginal cost of capital utilisation in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 1.463 | Elasticity of capital utilisation rate in the energy-intensive sector |
| 1.694 | Elasticity of capital utilisation rate in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 0.001 | Adjustment cost parameter for capital in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.001 | Adjustment cost parameter for capital in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 1.5 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 1.5 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 0.44 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 0.44 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 0.9 | Elasticity of substitution between and |
| 0.55 | Bias parameter for energy-intensive goods |
| 0.990 | Weight of capital services in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.996 | Weight of capital services in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 100 | Wald percentile (Y, P, E, C) |
| 40.14 | Transformed Mahalanobis distance (Y, P, E, C) |
Parameters governing the elasticities of labour hours in the energy-intensive and non-energy-intensive sectors,
and
, are 0.43 and 0.28, respectively, being calibrated to match the respective sector’s capital-output ratios. The values chosen for the elasticities of substitution parameters in the aggregator functions are all standard in the trade literature ([
48,
49,
50]) and U.S. data:
,
,
, and
. Then, the parameters governing the weight of capital services in both sectors
are implicitly estimated throughout. First, based on calibrated values and later using estimated values, given the fixed parameters obtained from target steady state ratios of the model. In practice, we use the expression:
where the values change mainly with the parameter
.
The values of all the remaining structural model parameters are fixed throughout the empirical investigation (see
Table A2). As an example, these include the discount factor,
, which we set at 0.96, indicating that the annual real rate of interest is 4% (a value found to be consistent with the average post-WWII interest rate in the U.S.). All the other parameters capture the long-run average data values over the sample period.
Table A2.
Fixed structural parameter and steady state ratios.
Table A2.
Fixed structural parameter and steady state ratios.
Parameter | Value | Description |
---|
β | 0.96 | Discount factor |
δ | 0.09 | Marginal cost of capital utilisation in the energy-intensive sector |
δ | 0.06 | Marginal cost of capital utilisation in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 1 | Price of crude oil |
| 0.011 | Energy-capital ratio in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.014 | Energy-capital ratio in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 0.08 | Investment-capital ratio in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.17 | Investment-capital ratio in the non-energy-intensive sector |
| 0.7 | Share of investment in the energy-intensive sector to aggregate investment |
| 0.3 | Share of investment in the non-energy-intensive sector to aggregate investment |
| 0.4 | Share of labour hours in the energy-intensive sector to aggregate labour hours |
| 0.6 | Share of labour hours in the non-energy-intensive sector to aggregate labour hours |
| 0.78 | Share of oil use in the energy-intensive sector to aggregate oil use |
| 0.22 | Share of oil use in the non-energy-intensive sector to aggregate oil use |
| 0.41 | Ratio of energy-intensive output to total output |
| 0.59 | Ratio of non-energy-intensive output to total output |
g/d | 0.21 | Share of government consumption spending in domestic absorption |
i/d | 0.3 | Share of investment in domestic absorption |
c/d | 0.49 | Share of consumption in domestic absorption |
| 1.385 | Ratio of domestic absorption to output in the energy-intensive sector |
| 0.1573 | Ratio of exports to output in energy-intensive sector |
| 0.205 | Ratio of imports to output in energy-intensive sector |
| 0.37 | Ratio of absorption of energy-intensive goods to total domestic absorption |
i/y | 0.308 | Share of investment to total output |
g/y | 0.215 | Share of government consumption spending in total output |
o/y | 0.037 | Share of energy use in total output |
x/y | 0.08 | Share of exports in total output |
m/y | 0.092 | Share of imports in total output |
c/y | 0.268 | Share of private consumption in total output |
| 1 | Price of imported goods |
r | 0.04 | Interest rate |
w | 1 | Wages |
In addition, there are 12 autocorrelation parameters and 12 standard deviations of innovations that make up the model’s structural shock processes. To calibrate these parameters, we assume that the twelve exogenous processes follow AR(1) stationary processes in logarithm. Further, we assume that the innovations are serially uncorrelated, such that the 24 parameters are calculated based on twelve derived series. More specifically, the eight behavioural errors (preference shock, labour supply shock, two sectoral productivity shocks, two investment technology shocks, and two sectoral energy efficiency shocks) and the four exogenous processes (government spending shock, oil price shock, world demand shock, and imported energy-intensive goods price shock) are calculated part-sequentially as using model equations and actual data:
Nine of the above equations are without expectations such that the structural errors are backed out directly as residuals. For Equations (A74) and (A75) that are with expectations, the residuals are derived using the instrumental variable method recommended by McCallum [
33] and Wickens [
34], where the instruments are the lagged values of the endogenous variables. We then fit a univariate AR(1) model to each of the constructed series for the shocks. We have thus followed Blankenau et al. [
24] (p. 874) in using “the observable endogenous variables and the orthogonality conditions implied by the Euler equations to recover the exogenous shocks…” This allows us to use the model equivalent of the four observed exogenous variables, such that we have maintained one of the early open economy model assumptions in the lineage of Fleming [
51] and Mundell [
52] that treat current account transactions mainly as residuals. In Meenagh et al. [
9], we relax this manner of deriving the parameters of the observed shock processes, making use of their corresponding actual observations. This other approach follows the literature that interprets changes in the current account as emerging from planned behaviour of agents (see, for example, Sachs [
53], Aizenman [
54], Frenkel and Razin [
55], Razin [
56], and Dornbusch [
57] for earlier accounts).
Table A3 documents the results.
Table A3.
Starting values of the shock processes.
Table A3.
Starting values of the shock processes.
Parameter | Value | Parameter | Value | Description |
---|
| 0.58 | | 1.20 | Preference shock |
| 0.49 | | 0.12 | Labour supply shock |
| 0.30 | | 0.07 | Investment technology in the energy-intensive sector shock |
| 0.30 | | 0.07 | Investment technology in the non-energy-intensive sector shock |
| 0.54 | | 0.31 | Oil price shock |
| 0.49 | | 0.02 | Total factor productivity in the energy-intensive sector shock |
| 0.26 | | 0.03 | Total factor productivity in the non-energy-intensive sector shock |
| 0.59 | | 0.52 | Energy efficiency in the energy-intensive sector shock |
| 0.59 | | 0.55 | Energy efficiency in the non-energy-intensive sector shock |
| 0.41 | | 0.06 | Government spending shock |
| 0.56 | | 0.04 | Imported energy-intensive goods price shock |
| 0.61 | | 0.20 | World demand shock |